SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 97
Go Global !
Managerial Economics :
Monopoly
By
Stephen Ong
Visiting Fellow, Birmingham City University
Visiting Professor, College of Management,
Shenzhen University
May 2013
Agenda
1. Market Power
2. Antitrust
3. Price Discrimination
Learning Objectives
To understand market power,
monopoly and monopsony
To explain how the MR=MC rule
helps a monopoly to determine its
optimum
To discuss government regulation
and antitrust laws
To understand price discrimination
in monopoly markets
Overview
Market power
Characteristics of monopoly
and monopsony markets
Pricing and output decisions
in monopoly markets
Implications for managerial
decisions
1
Market Power
Firms With Market Power
The ability of a firm to
influence the prices of its
products and develop
other competitive
strategies that enable it
to earn large profits over
longer periods of time.
The Monopoly Model
A market structure
characterized by a single
firm producing a product
with no close substitutes.
Monopoly Model - Graphical
P
Q
PM
ATCM
QM
D
MR
MC
ATCP
Q
PM
QM
ATCM
D
MR
MC
ATC
PROFIT
LOSS
Comparing Monopoly and Perfect
Competition
 The Perfectly
Competitive Firm
 At QPC :
 MR = MC
 P = ATC
 P = MC
 Minimum Point of
ATC Curve
 Price-Taker
 Firm Has Supply
Curve
 The Monopoly Firm
 At QM :
 MR = MC
 P > ATC
 P > MC
 Not at Minimum
Point of ATC
 Price-Searcher
 Firm Has No Supply
Curve
Comparing Monopoly and Perfect
Competition - Graphical
P
Q
PM
QM
D
MR
MC
ATC
D = P = MRPC
QC
ATC
MC
Another Look at Monopoly
vs. Perfect Competition
PM
PC
QCQM
AC=MC
D
MR
$
Q
Sources of Market Power
Economies of scale
Barriers created by
government
Input barriers
Brand loyalties
Consumer lock-in and
switching costs
Network externalities
Economies of Scale
Economies of scale can
act as a barrier to entry
in different industries
because only large-scale
firms can achieve the
cost-reduction benefits
of these economies.
Barriers Created by
Government
Licenses
Patents and Copyrights
Input Barriers
Other barriers to entry
include control over raw
materials or other key
inputs in a production
process and barriers in
financial capital markets.
Brand Loyalties
The creation of brand
loyalties through
advertising and other
marketing efforts is a
strategy that many
managers use to create
and maintain market
power.
Consumer Lock-In and
Switching Costs
Barriers to entry can also
result if consumers
become locked into
certain types or brands
of products and would
incur substantial
switching costs if they
changed.
Network Externalities
Network externalities act
as a barrier to entry
because the value of a
product to consumers
depends on the number
of customers using the
product.
Examples of Shifting
Market Power
Shifting Demand
for Kleenex
Home Depot and
Customer
Service
Borders
Bookstores’
Online Strategy
Monopoly
Market with only one seller.
Monopsony
Market with only one buyer.
Market power
Ability of a seller or buyer to affect
the price of a good.
Monopoly
Average Revenue and Marginal Revenue
Marginal revenue : Change in revenue resulting from a one-unit
increase in output.
TABLE 1 TOTAL, MARGINAL, AND AVERAGE REVENUE
PRICE
(P)
QUANTITY
(Q)
TOTAL
REVENUE
(R)
MARGINAL
REVENUE
(MR)
AVERAGE
REVENUE
(AR)
$6 0 $0 — —
5 1 5 $5 $5
4 2 8 3 4
3 3 9 1 3
2 4 8 1 2
1 5 5 3 1
Consider a firm facing the following demand curve: P = 6  Q
Average and
marginal
revenue are
shown for
the demand
curve
P = 6 − Q.
AVERAGE AND MARGINAL REVENUE
PROFIT IS MAXIMIZED WHEN
MARGINAL REVENUE
EQUALS MARGINAL COST
The Monopolist’s Output Decision
Q* is the output level at which
MR = MC.
If the firm produces a smaller
output—say, Q1—it sacrifices
some profit because the extra
revenue that could be earned
from producing and selling
the units between Q1 and Q*
exceeds the cost of producing
them.
Similarly, expanding output
from Q* to Q2 would reduce
profit because the additional
cost would exceed the
additional revenue.
We can also see algebraically that Q* maximizes
profit. Profit π is the difference between revenue
and cost, both of which depend on Q:
As Q is increased from zero, profit will increase until it
reaches a maximum and then begin to decrease. Thus
the profit-maximizing Q is such that the incremental
profit resulting from a small increase in Q is just zero
(i.e., Δπ /ΔQ = 0). Then
But ΔR/ΔQ is marginal revenue and ΔC/ΔQ is
marginal cost. Thus the profit-maximizing
condition is that
EXAMPLE OF PROFIT
MAXIMIZATION
Part (a) shows total revenue R, total cost C,
and profit, the difference between the two.
Part (b) shows average and marginal
revenue and average and marginal cost.
Marginal revenue is the slope of the total
revenue curve, and marginal cost is the
slope of the total cost curve.
The profit-maximizing output is Q* = 10, the
point where marginal revenue equals
marginal cost.
At this output level, the slope of the profit
curve is zero, and the slopes of the total
revenue and total cost curves are equal.
The profit per unit is $15, the difference
between average revenue and average
cost. Because 10 units are produced, total
profit is $150.
A Rule of Thumb for Pricing
Note that the extra revenue from an incremental unit of quantity,
Δ(PQ)/ΔQ, has two components:
1. Producing one extra unit and selling it at price P brings in revenue
(1)(P) = P.
2. But because the firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve,
producing and selling this extra unit also results in a small drop in
price ΔP/ΔQ, which reduces the revenue from all units sold (i.e., a
change in revenue Q[ΔP/ΔQ]).Thus,
With limited knowledge of average and marginal revenue, we can
derive a rule of thump that can be more easily applied in practice.
First, write the expression for marginal revenue:
(Q/P)(ΔP/ΔQ) is the reciprocal of the elasticity of
demand, 1/Ed, measured at the profit-maximizing
output, and
Now, because the firm’s objective is to maximize profit,
we can set marginal revenue equal to marginal cost:
which can be rearranged to give us
Equivalently, we can rearrange this equation to express
price directly as a markup over marginal cost:
ASTRA-MERCK PRICES PRILOSEC
In 1995, Prilosec, represented a new generation of anti-
ulcer medication. Prilosec was based on a very different
biochemical mechanism and was much more effective
than earlier drugs.
By 1996, it had become the best-selling drug in the world
and faced no major competitor.
Astra-Merck was pricing Prilosec at about $3.50 per daily
dose. The marginal cost of producing and packaging
Prilosec is only about 30 to 40 cents per daily dose. The
price elasticity of demand, ED, should be in the range of
roughly −1.0 to −1.2.
Setting the price at a markup exceeding 400 percent
over marginal cost is consistent with our rule of thumb for
pricing.
Shifts in Demand
A monopolistic market has no supply curve. In other
words, there is no one-to-one relationship between price
and the quantity produced.
The reason is that the monopolist’s output decision depends
not only on marginal cost but also on the shape of the
demand curve.
As a result, shifts in demand do not trace out the series of
prices and quantities that correspond to a competitive
supply curve. Instead, shifts in demand can lead to changes
in price with no change in output, changes in output with no
change in price, or changes in both price and output.
Shifts in demand usually cause changes in both price and
quantity. A competitive industry supplies a specific quantity
at every price. No such relationship exists for a monopolist,
which, depending on how demand shifts, might supply
several different quantities at the same price, or
the same quantity at different prices.
SHIFTS IN DEMAND
Shifting the demand curve
shows that a monopolistic
market has no supply curve—
i.e., there is no one-to-one
relationship between price and
quantity produced. In (a), the
demand curve D1 shifts to new
demand curve D2. But the new
marginal revenue curve MR2
intersects marginal cost at the
same point as the old marginal
revenue curve MR1. The profit-
maximizing output therefore
remains the same, although
price falls from P1 to P2. In (b),
the new marginal revenue
curve MR2 intersects marginal
cost at a higher output level
Q2. But because demand is
now more elastic, price
remains the same.
THE DEMAND FOR TOOTHBRUSHES
Monopoly Power
Part (a) shows the market
demand for toothbrushes.
Part (b) shows the demand
for toothbrushes as seen by
Firm A.
At a market price of $1.50,
elasticity of market demand
is −1.5.
Firm A, however, sees a
much more elastic demand
curve DA because of
competition from other
firms. At a price of $1.50,
Firm A’s demand elasticity is
−6. Still, Firm A has some
monopoly power: Its profit-
maximizing price is $1.50,
which exceeds marginal
cost.
ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND FOR SOFT DRINKS
Soft drinks provide a good example of the difference between a
market elasticity of demand and a firm’s elasticity of demand.
In addition, soft drinks are important because their consumption
has been linked to childhood obesity; there could be health
benefits from taxing them.
A recent review of several statistical studies found that the
market elasticity of demand for soft drinks is between −0.8 and
−1.0.6 That means that if all soft drink producers increased the
prices of all of their brands by 1 percent, the quantity of soft
drinks demanded would fall by 0.8 to 1.0 percent.
The demand for any individual soft drink, however, will be much
more elastic, because consumers can readily substitute one
drink for another. Although elasticities will differ across different
brands, studies have shown that the elasticity of demand for,
say, Coca Cola is around −5.7 In other words, if the price of Coke
were increased by 1 percent but the prices of all other soft
drinks remained unchanged, the quantity of Coke demanded
would fall by about 5 percent. Students—and business people—
sometimes confuse the market elasticity of demand with the firm
(or brand) elasticity of demand.
ELASTICITY OF DEMAND AND PRICE MARKUP
The Rule of Thumb for Pricing
The markup (P − MC)/P is equal to minus the inverse of the elasticity of
demand. If the firm’s demand is elastic, as in (a), the markup is small and the
firm has little monopoly power.
The opposite is true if demand is relatively inelastic, as in (b).
MARKUP PRICING: SUPERMARKETS TO
DESIGNER JEANS
Although the elasticity of market demand for food is small
(about −1), no single supermarket can raise its prices very
much without losing customers to other stores.
The elasticity of demand for any one supermarket is often as large as
−10. We find P = MC/(1 − 0.1) =MC/(0.9) = (1.11)MC.
The manager of a typical supermarket should set prices about 11
percent above marginal cost.
Small convenience stores typically charge higher prices
because its customers are generally less price sensitive.
Because the elasticity of demand for a convenience store is about −5,
the markup equation implies that its prices should be about 25 percent
above marginal cost.
With designer jeans, demand elasticities in the range of −2
to −3 are typical. This means that price should be 50 to
100 percent higher than marginal cost.
THE PRICING OF VIDEOS
When the market for videos was young, producers had no good
estimates of the elasticity of demand. As the market matured,
however, sales data and market research studies put pricing
decisions on firmer ground. By the 1990s, most producers had
lowered prices across the board.
TABLE 2 RETAIL PRICES OF VIDEOS IN 1985 AND 2011
1985 2011
TITLE
RETAIL PRICE
($) TITLE
RETAIL PRICE
($)
VHS DVD
Purple Rain $29.98 Tangled $20.60
Raiders of the Lost Ark $24.95
Harry Potter and the
Deathly Hallows, Part 1 $20.58
Jane Fonda Workout $59.95 Megamind $18.74
The Empire Strikes Back $79.98 Despicable Me $14.99
An Officer and a
Gentleman $24.95 Red $27.14
Star Trek: The Motion
Picture $24.95 The King’s Speech $14.99
Star Wars $39.98 Secretariat $20.60
VIDEO SALES
Between 1990 and 1998, lower prices induced consumers to buy
many more videos. By 2001, sales of DVDs overtook sales of VHS
videocassettes. High-definition DVDs were introduced in 2006,
and are expected to displace sales of conventional DVDs. All
DVDs, however, are now being displaced by streaming video.
THE PRICING OF VIDEOS
Sources of Monopoly Power
The less elastic its demand curve, the more
monopoly power a firm has. The ultimate
determinant of monopoly power is therefore
the firm’s elasticity of demand.
Three factors determine a firm’s elasticity of demand.
1. The elasticity of market demand. Because the
firm’s own demand will be at least as elastic as market
demand, the elasticity of market demand limits the
potential for monopoly power.
2. The number of firms in the market. If there are many
firms, it is unlikely that any one firm will be able to
affect price significantly.
3. The interaction among firms. Even if only two or three
firms are in the market, each firm will be unable to
profitably raise price very much if the rivalry among
them is aggressive, with each firm trying to capture as
much of the market as it can.
If there is only one firm—a pure monopolist—its demand curve
is the market demand curve. In this case, the firm’s degree of
monopoly power depends completely on the elasticity of market
demand.
When several firms compete with one another, the elasticity of
market demand sets a lower limit on the magnitude of the
elasticity of demand for each firm.
A particular firm’s elasticity depends on how the firms compete
with one another, and the elasticity of market demand limits the
potential monopoly power of individual producers.
Because the demand for oil is fairly inelastic (at least
in the short run), OPEC could raise oil prices far above marginal
production cost during the 1970s and early 1980s. Because the
demands for such commodities as coffee, cocoa, tin, and copper
are much more elastic, attempts by producers to cartelize these
markets and raise prices have largely failed. In each case, the
elasticity of market demand limits the potential monopoly power
of individual producers.
1. The Elasticity of Market Demand
2.The Number of Firms
Other things being equal, the monopoly power of
each firm will fall as the number of firms
increases. When only a few firms account for
most of the sales in a market, we say that the
market is highly concentrated.
Barrier to entry
Condition that impedes entry by new competitors.
1. Sometimes there are natural barriers to entry.
2. Patents, copyrights, and licenses
3. Economies of scale may make it too costly for
more than a few firms to supply the entire
market. In some cases, economies of scale may
be so large that it is most efficient for a single
firm—a natural monopoly—to supply the entire
market.
3.The Interaction Among Firms
Firms might compete aggressively, undercutting one
another’s prices to capture more market share, or they
might not compete much. They might even collude (in
violation of the antitrust laws), agreeing to limit
output and raise prices.
Other things being equal, monopoly power is smaller when
firms compete aggressively and is larger when they
cooperate. Because raising prices in concert rather than
individually is more likely to be profitable, collusion can
generate substantial monopoly power.
Remember that a firm’s monopoly power often changes
over time, as its operating conditions (market demand and
cost), its behaviour, and the behaviour of its competitors
change. Monopoly power must therefore be thought of in a
dynamic context. Furthermore, real or potential monopoly
power in the short run can make an industry more
competitive in the long run: Large short-run profits can
induce new firms to enter an industry, thereby reducing
monopoly power over the longer term.
The Social Costs of Monopoly Power
DEADWEIGHT LOSS FROM
MONOPOLY POWER
The shaded rectangle and
triangles show changes in
consumer and producer surplus
when moving from competitive
price and quantity, Pc and Qc,
to a monopolist’s price and
quantity, Pm and Qm.
Because of the higher price,
consumers lose A + B
and producer gains A − C. The
deadweight loss is B + C.
Rent Seeking
Spending money in socially unproductive efforts to acquire, maintain, or
exercise monopoly.
We would expect the economic incentive to incur rent-
seeking costs to bear a direct relation to the gains from
monopoly power (i.e., rectangle A minus triangle C.)
REGULATING THE PRICE OF
A NATURAL MONOPOLY
A firm is a natural monopoly
because it has economies of
scale (declining average and
marginal costs) over its entire
output range.
If price were regulated to be Pc the
firm would lose money and go out
of business.
Setting the price at Pr yields the
largest possible output consistent
with the firm’s remaining in
business; excess profit is zero.
Natural Monopoly
Firm that can produce the entire output of the market at a
cost lower than what it would be if there were several
firms.
Monopsony
Oligopsony Market with only a few buyers.
Monopsony power
Buyer’s ability to affect the price of a good.
Marginal value
Additional benefit derived from purchasing one more
unit of a good.
Marginal expenditure
Additional cost of buying one more unit of a good.
Average expenditure
Price paid per unit of a good.
COMPETITIVE BUYER COMPARED TO COMPETITIVE SELLER
In (a), the competitive buyer takes market price P* as given. Therefore,
marginal expenditure and average expenditure are constant and equal;
quantity purchased is found by equating price to marginal value
(demand). In (b), the competitive seller also takes price as given.
Marginal revenue and average revenue are constant and equal;
quantity sold is found by equating price to marginal cost.
MONOPSONIST BUYER
The market supply curve is
monopsonist’s average
expenditure curve AE.
Because average expenditure is
rising, marginal expenditure lies
above it.
The monopsonist purchases
quantity Q*m, where marginal
expenditure and marginal value
(demand) intersect.
The price paid per unit P*m is then
found from the average
expenditure (supply) curve.
In a competitive market, price and
quantity, Pc and Qc, are both
higher.
They are found at the point where
average expenditure (supply) and
marginal value (demand) intersect.
These diagrams show the close analogy between monopoly and monopsony.
(a) The monopolist produces where marginal revenue intersects marginal cost.
Average revenue exceeds marginal revenue, so that price exceeds marginal
cost.
(b) The monopsonist purchases up to the point where marginal expenditure
intersects marginal value.
Marginal expenditure exceeds average expenditure, so that marginal value
exceeds price.
Monopsony and Monopoly Compared
MONOPSONY POWER: ELASTIC VERSUS INELASTIC SUPPLY
Monopsony power depends on the elasticity of supply.
When supply is elastic, as in (a), marginal expenditure and average expenditure
do not differ by much, so price is close to what it would be in a competitive
market.
The opposite is true when supply is inelastic, as in (b).
Monopsony Power
Sources of Monopsony Power
ELASTICITY OF MARKET SUPPLY
If only one buyer is in the market—a pure monopsonist—its
monopsony power is completely determined by the elasticity of
market supply. If supply is highly elastic, monopsony power is
small and there is little gain in being the only buyer.
NUMBER OF BUYERS
When the number of buyers is very large, no single buyer can
have much influence over price. Thus each buyer faces an
extremely elastic supply curve, so that the market is almost
completely competitive.
INTERACTION AMONG BUYERS
If four buyers in a market compete aggressively, they will bid up the
price close to their marginal value of the product, and will thus have
little monopsony power. On the other hand, if those buyers compete
less aggressively, or even collude, prices will not be bid up very
much, and the buyers’ degree of monopsony power might be nearly
as high as if there were only one buyer.
DEADWEIGHT LOSS FROM
MONOPSONY POWER
The Social Costs of Monopsony Power
The shaded rectangle and
triangles show changes in
buyer and seller surplus
when moving from
competitive price and
quantity, Pc and Qc, to the
monopsonist’s price and
quantity, Pm and Qm.
Because both price and
quantity are lower, there is
an increase in buyer
(consumer) surplus given
by A − B.
Producer surplus falls by
A + C, so there is a
deadweight loss given by
triangles B and C.
Bilateral Monopoly
Market with only one seller and one buyer.
It is difficult to predict the price and quantity in a bilateral
monopoly. Both the buyer and the seller are in a bargaining
situation.
Bilateral monopoly is rare. Although bargaining may still be
involved, we can apply a rough principle here: Monopsony
power and monopoly power will tend to counteract each
other. In other words, the monopsony power of buyers will
reduce the effective monopoly power of sellers, and vice
versa.
This tendency does not mean that the market will end up
looking perfectly competitive, but in general,
monopsony power will push price closer to
marginal cost, and monopoly power will
push price closer to marginal value.
MONOPSONY POWER IN U.S. MANUFACTURING
The role of monopsony power was investigated to determine the
extent to which variations in price-cost margins could be attributed
to variations in monopsony power. The study found that buyers’
monopsony power had an important effect on the price-cost margins
of sellers.
In industries where only four or five buyers account for all or nearly
all sales, the price-cost margins of sellers would on
average be as much as 10 percentage points lower than in
comparable industries with hundreds of buyers accounting for sales.
Each major car producer in the United States typically buys an individual
part from at least three, and often as many as a dozen, suppliers.
For a specialized part, a single auto company may be the
only buyer.
As a result, the automobile companies have considerable
monopsony power. Not surprisingly, producers of parts
and components usually have little or no monopoly
power.
2
Antitrust
Measures of Market Power
Lerner Index
Cross Price Elasticity of
Demand
Concentration Ratios
The Herfindahl-Hirschman
Index
Measuring Monopoly Power :
Lerner Index
Remember the important distinction between a
perfectly competitive firm and a firm with
monopoly power: For the competitive firm,
price equals marginal cost; for the firm with
monopoly power, price exceeds marginal cost.
Lerner Index of Monopoly Power
Measure of monopoly power calculated as excess of price over
marginal cost as a fraction of price.
Mathematically:
This index of monopoly power can also be expressed in terms of
the elasticity of demand facing the firm.
The regulation of a monopoly is sometimes based on the rate of return
that it earns on its capital. The regulatory agency determines an allowed
price, so that this rate of return is in some sense “competitive” or “fair.”
Although it is a key element in determining the firm’s rate of return, a
firm’s capital stock is difficult to value. While a “fair” rate of return must
be based on the firm’s actual cost of capital, that cost depends in turn
on the behaviour of the regulatory agency. Regulatory lag is a term
associated with delays in changing regulated prices.
Another approach to regulation is setting price caps based on the
firm’s variable costs. A price cap can allow for more flexibility than rate-
of-return regulation. Under price cap regulation, for example, a firm
would typically be allowed to raise its prices each year (without having
to get approval from the regulatory agency) by an amount equal to the
actual rate of inflation, minus expected productivity growth.
Regulation in Practice
Rate-of-return regulation
Maximum price allowed by a regulatory agency is based on the
(expected) rate of return that a firm will earn.
The Effect of a Tax
EFFECT OF EXCISE TAX
ON MONOPOLIST
With a tax t per unit, the
firm’s effective
marginal cost is
increased by the
amount t to MC + t.
In this example, the
increase in price ΔP is
larger than the tax t.
Suppose a specific tax of t dollars per unit is levied, so that the
monopolist must remit t dollars to the government for every unit it
sells. If MC was the firm’s original marginal cost, its optimal
production decision is now given by
PRICE
REGULATION
If left alone, a monopolist
produces Qm and charges
Pm.
When the government
imposes a price ceiling of
P1 the firm’s average and
marginal revenue are
constant and equal to P1
for output levels up to Q1.
For larger output levels,
the original average and
marginal revenue curves
apply.
The new marginal
revenue curve is,
therefore, the dark purple
line, which intersects the
marginal cost curve at Q1.
Price Regulation
PRICE REGULATION
When price is
lowered to Pc, at the
point where marginal
cost intersects
average revenue,
output increases to
its maximum Qc. This
is the output that
would be produced
by a competitive
industry.
Lowering price
further, to P3, reduces
output to Q3 and
causes a shortage,
Q’3 − Q3.
Limiting Market Power:
The Antitrust Laws
Antitrust laws
Rules and regulations prohibiting actions that restrain, or are likely to
restrain, competition.
Excessive market power harms potential purchasers and raises
problems of equity and fairness. In addition, market power reduces
output, which leads to a deadweight loss.
In theory, a firm’s excess profits could be taxed away, but redistribution
of the firm’s profits is often impractical.
To limit the market power of a natural monopoly, such as an electric
utility company, direct price regulation is the answer.
It is important to stress that, while there are limitations
(such as colluding with other firms), in general, it is not
illegal to be a monopolist or to have market power. On the
contrary, we have seen that patent and copyright
laws protect the monopoly positions of firms that
developed unique innovations.
Restricting what Firms can do
Parallel conduct
Form of implicit collusion in which one
firm consistently follows actions of
another.
Predatory pricing
Practice of pricing to drive current
competitors out of business and to
discourage new entrants in a market so
that a firm can enjoy higher future
profits.
Antitrust Issues
The Sherman Act of 1890
The Clayton Act of 1914
The Federal Trade
Commission Act of 1914
The antitrust laws are enforced in three
ways in USA :
1. Through the Antitrust Division of the
Department of Justice.
2. Through the administrative
procedures of the Federal Trade
Commission.
3. Through private proceedings.
Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws
Antitrust in Europe
 At first glance, the antitrust laws of the European Union
are quite similar to those of the United States. Article
101 of the Treaty of the European Community concerns
restraints of trade, much like Section 1 of the Sherman
Act.
 Article 102, which focuses on abuses of market power
by dominant firms, is similar in many ways to Section 2
of the Sherman Act.
 Finally, with respect to mergers, the European Merger
Control Act is similar in spirit to Section 7 of the Clayton
Act.
 Nevertheless, there remain a number of procedural and
substantive differences between antitrust laws in
Europe and the United States. Merger evaluations
typically are conducted more quickly in Europe.
 Antitrust enforcement has grown rapidly through the
world in the past decade.
A PHONE CALL ABOUT PRICES
Robert Crandall, president and CEO of American, made a phone call
to Howard Putnam, president and chief executive of Braniff. It went
like this:
Crandall: I think it’s dumb as hell for Christ’s sake, all right, to sit here
and pound the @!#$%&! out of each other and neither one of us
making a @!#$%&! dime.
Putnam: Well . . .
Crandall: I mean, you know, @!#$%&!, what the hell is the point of it?
Putnam: But if you’re going to overlay every route of American’s on
top of every route that Braniff has—I just can’t sit here and allow you
to bury us without giving our best effort.
Crandall: Oh sure, but Eastern and Delta do the same thing in Atlanta
and have for years.
Putnam: Do you have a suggestion for me?
A PHONE CALL ABOUT PRICES
Crandall: Yes, I have a suggestion for you. Raise your @!#$%&! fares
20 percent. I’ll raise mine the next morning.
Putnam: Robert, we. . .
Crandall: You’ll make more money and I will, too.
Putnam: We can’t talk about pricing!
Crandall: Oh @!#$%&!, Howard. We can talk about any @!#$%&! thing
we want to talk about.
Crandall was wrong. Talking about prices and agreeing to fix
them is a clear violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act.
However, proposing to fix prices is not enough to violate Section 1 of
the Sherman Act: For the law to be violated, the two parties must agree
to collude.
Therefore, because Putnam had rejected Crandall’s proposal, Section
1 was not violated.
GO DIRECTLY TO JAIL. DON’T PASS GO
If you become a successful business executive, think
twice before picking up the phone. And if your
company happens to be located in Europe or Asia,
don’t think that will keep you out of a U.S. jail.
For example:
In 1996 Archer Daniels Midland (ADM) and two other
producers of lysine (an animal feed additive) pled guilty to
charges of price fixing. In 1999 three ADM executives were
sentenced to prison terms of two to three years.
In 1999 four of the world’s largest drug and chemical
companies—Hoffman-La Roche of Switzerland,
BASF of Germany, Rhone Poulenc of France, and
Takeda of Japan—pled guilty to fixing the prices of
vitamins sold in the U.S. and Europe. The companies paid
about $1.5 billion in penalties to the U.S. Department of
Justice (DOJ), $1 billion to the European Commission, and
over $4 billion to settle civil suits. Executives from each of
the companies did prison time in the U.S.
GO DIRECTLY TO JAIL. DON’T PASS GO
During 2002 to 2009, Horizon Lines engaged in
price fixing with Sea Star Lines (Puerto Rico-based
shipping companies). Five executives got prison
terms ranging from one to four years.
Eight companies, mostly in Korea and Japan, fixed
DRAM (memory chip) prices from 1998 to 2002. In
2007, 18 executives from these companies were
sentenced to prison terms in the United States.
In 2009, five companies pled guilty to fixing prices
of LCD displays during 2001-2006. 22 executives
received prison sentences in the United States (on
top of $1 billion in fines).
In 2011, two companies were convicted of fixing
prices and rigging bids for ready-mix concrete in
Iowa. One executive was sentenced to one year in
prison, another to four years.
THE UNITED STATES AND THE EUROPEAN
UNION VERSUS MICROSOFT
Over the past two decades Microsoft has grown to become the
largest computer software company in the world, and has
dominated the office productivity market. Under the antitrust laws
of the United States and the European Union, efforts by firms to
restrain trade or to engage in activities that inappropriately
maintain monopolies are illegal. Did Microsoft engage in
anticompetitive, illegal practices?
In 1998, the U.S. government said yes; Microsoft disagreed.
The Antitrust Division of the U.S. DOJ filed suit, claiming that
Microsoft had illegally bundled its Internet browser, Internet
Explorer, with its operating system for the purpose of maintaining
its dominant operating system monopoly. Following an eight-
month trial that was hard-fought on a range of economic issues,
the District Court found that Microsoft did have monopoly power in
the market for PC operating systems, which it had maintained
illegally in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
The U.S. case was ultimately settled in 2004, with (among other
things) Microsoft agreeing to give computer manufacturers
(1) the ability to offer an operating system without Internet
Explorer and (2) the option of loading competing browser
Programs on the PCs that they sell.
THE UNITED STATES AND THE EUROPEAN
UNION VERSUS MICROSOFT
Microsoft’s problems did not end with the U.S. settlement,
however. In 2004, the European Commission ordered
Microsoft to pay $794 million in fines for its anti-
competitive practices, to produce a version of Windows
without the Windows Media Player to be sold alongside its
standard editions.
In 2008, the European Commission levied an additional
fine of $1.44 billion, claiming that Microsoft had not
complied with the earlier decision. Even more recently, in
response to a concern relating to the bundling of browsers,
Microsoft agreed to offer customers a choice of browsers
when first booting up their new operating system.
As of 2011, the European case against Microsoft remains
on appeal. There is strong evidence that the European-
imposed remedies have had little impact on the market for
media players or browsers. However, Microsoft is facing an
even stronger threat than U.S. or E.U. enforcement, such
as competition from the powerful Google search engine
and social media sites such as Facebook.
3
Price Discrimination
Pricing and output decisions
in monopoly markets
 A monopoly market consists of one firm
(the firm is the market)
• firm has the power to set any price it wants
• however, the firm’s ability to set price is
limited by the demand curve for its product,
and in particular, the price elasticity of
demand
Pricing and output decisions in
monopoly markets
Assume demand
is linear: it is
downward sloping
because the firm is
a price setter
Assume MC is
constant
 choose output
where MR=MC,
set price at P*
Pricing and output decisions in
monopoly markets
Demand is the
same as before, as
is MR
MC is upward
sloping, which
shows diminishing
returns
 set output where
MR=MC
Implications of monopoly
for decision making
 Monopoly market
 most important lesson is not to be
arrogant and assume their ability to
earn economic profit can never be
diminished
 changes in economics of a business
eventually break down a dominating
company’s monopolistic power
Capturing Consumer Surplus
CAPTURING CONSUMER SURPLUS
Price discrimination
Practice of charging different prices to
different consumers for similar goods.
If a firm can charge only one price
for all its customers, that price will
be P* and the quantity produced will
be Q*.
Ideally, the firm would like to charge
a higher price to consumers willing
to pay more than P*, thereby
capturing some of the consumer
surplus under region A of the
demand curve.
The firm would also like to sell to
consumers willing to pay prices
lower than P*, but only if doing so
does not entail lowering the price to
other consumers.
In that way, the firm could also
capture some of the surplus under
region B of the demand curve.
First degree price discrimination
Practice of charging each customer her reservation price.
First-Degree Price Discrimination
Variable profit
Sum of profits on each incremental unit produced by a
firm; i.e., profit ignoring fixed costs.
Reservation price
Maximum price that a customer is willing to pay for a
good.
Price Discrimination
ADDITIONAL PROFIT FROM PERFECT FIRST-
DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION
Because the firm charges
each consumer her
reservation price, it is
profitable to expand output
to Q**.
When only a single price,
P*, is charged, the firm’s
variable profit is the area
between the marginal
revenue and marginal cost
curves.
With perfect price
discrimination, this profit
expands to the area
between the demand curve
and the marginal cost
curve.
FIRST-DEGREE PRICE
DISCRIMINATION IN PRACTICE
PERFECT PRICE DISCRIMINATION
The additional profit from producing and selling
an incremental unit is the difference between
demand and marginal cost.
IMPERFECT PRICE DISCRIMINATION
Firms usually don’t know the
reservation price of every consumer,
but sometimes reservation prices can
be roughly identified.
Here, six different prices are charged.
The firm earns higher profits, but some
consumers may also benefit.
With a single price P4, there are fewer
consumers.
The consumers who now pay P5 or P6
enjoy a surplus.
SECOND-DEGREE PRICE
DISCRIMINATION
Second-Degree Price Discrimination
Practice of charging different prices per unit for different
quantities of the same good or service.
Block pricing : Practice of charging different prices for
different quantities or “blocks” of a good.
Different prices are charged for
different quantities, or “blocks,” of
the same good. Here, there are
three blocks, with corresponding
prices P1, P2, and P3.
There are also economies of scale,
and average and marginal costs
are declining. Second-degree
price discrimination can then make
consumers better off by expanding
output and lowering cost.
Third-Degree Price Discrimination
Practice of dividing consumers into two or more
groups with separate demand curves and charging
different prices to each group.
CREATING CONSUMER GROUPS
If third-degree price discrimination is feasible, how
should the firm decide what price to charge each group
of consumers?
1. We know that however much is produced, total
output should be divided between the groups of
customers so that marginal revenues for each
group are equal.
2. We know that total output must be such that the
marginal revenue for each group of consumers is
equal to the marginal cost of production.
DETERMINING RELATIVE PRICES
Let P1 be the price charged to the first group of consumers,
P2 the price charged to the second group, and C(QT) the
total cost of producing output QT = Q1 + Q2. Total profit is
then
THIRD-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION
Consumers are divided into two
groups, with separate demand
curves for each group. The
optimal prices and quantities
are such that the marginal
revenue from each group is the
same and equal to marginal
cost.
Here group 1, with demand
curve D1, is charged P1,
and group 2, with the more
elastic demand curve D2, is
charged the lower price P2.
Marginal cost depends on the
total quantity produced QT.
Note that Q1 and Q2 are chosen
so that MR1 = MR2 = MC.
NO SALES TO SMALLER MARKETS
Even if third-degree price
discrimination is feasible,
it may not pay to sell to
both groups of consumers
if marginal cost is rising.
Here the first group of
consumers, with demand
D1, are not willing to pay
much for the product.
It is unprofitable to sell to
them because the price
would have to be too low
to compensate for the
resulting increase in
marginal cost.
THE ECONOMICS OF COUPONS AND
REBATES
Coupons provide a means of price discrimination.
TABLE 1 PRICE ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND FOR
USERS VERSUS NONUSERS OF COUPONS
PRICE ELASTICITY
PRODUCT NONUSERS USERS
Toilet tissue – 0.60 –0.66
Stuffing/dressing –0.71 –0.96
Shampoo –0.84 –1.04
Cooking/salad oil –1.22 –1.32
Dry mix dinners –0.88 –1.09
Cake mix –0.21 –0.43
Cat food –0.49 –1.13
Frozen entrees –0.60 –0.95
Gelatin –0.97 –1.25
Spaghetti sauce –1.65 –1.81
Crème
rinse/conditioner
–0.82 –1.12
Soups –1.05 –1.22
Hot dogs –0.59 –0.77
AIRLINE FARES
TABLE 2 ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND FOR AIR TRAVEL
FARE CATEGORY
ELASTICITY
FIRST
CLASS
UNRESTRICTED
COACH DISCOUNTED
Price –0.3 –0.4 –0.9
Income 1.2 1.2 1.8
Travelers are often amazed at the variety of fares available for round-
trip flights from New York to Los Angeles.
Recently, for example, the first-class fare was above $2000; the regular
(unrestricted) economy fare was about $1000, and special discount
fares (often requiring the purchase of a ticket two weeks in advance
and/or a Saturday night stayover) could be bought for as little as $200.
These fares provide a profitable form of price discrimination.
The gains from discriminating are large because different types of
customers, with very different elasticities of demand, purchase these
different types of tickets.
Airline price discrimination has become increasingly sophisticated. A
wide variety of fares is available.
Intertemporal Price Discrimination
and Peak-Load Pricing
INTERTEMPORAL PRICE
DISCRIMINATION
Intertemporal price
discrimination
Spending money in socially
unproductive efforts to acquire,
maintain, or exercise monopoly.
Peak-load pricing
Spending money in socially
unproductive efforts to
acquire, maintain, or
exercise monopoly.
Consumers are divided into
groups by changing the price
over time.
Initially, the price is high. The
firm captures surplus from
consumers who have a high
demand for the good and who
are unwilling to wait to buy it.
Later the price is reduced to
appeal to the mass market.
PEAK-LOAD
PRICING
Peak-Load Pricing
Demands for some goods
and services increase
sharply during particular
times of the day or year.
Charging a higher price P1
during the peak periods is
more profitable for the firm
than charging a single price
at all times.
It is also more efficient
because marginal cost is
higher during peak periods.
HOW TO PRICE A BEST-SELLING NOVEL
Publishing both hardbound and paperback editions of a
book allows publishers to price discriminate.
Some consumers want to buy a new bestseller as soon as
it is released, even if the price is $25. Other consumers,
however, will wait a year until the book is available in
paperback for $10.
The key is to divide consumers into two groups, so that
those who are willing to pay a high price do so and only
those unwilling to pay a high price wait and buy the
paperback.
It is clear, however, that those consumers willing to wait for
the paperback edition have demands that are far more
elastic than those of bibliophiles.
It is not surprising, then, that paperback editions
sell for so much less than hardbacks.
The Two-Part Tariff
TWO-PART TARIFF WITH
A SINGLE CONSUMER
Form of pricing in which consumers are charged both
an entry and a usage fee.
SINGLE CONSUMER
The consumer has
demand curve D.
The firm maximizes profit
by setting usage fee P
equal to marginal cost
and entry fee T* equal to
the entire surplus of the
consumer.
TWO-PART TARIFF WITH
TWO CONSUMERS
TWO CONSUMERS
The profit-maximizing
usage fee P* will exceed
marginal cost.
The entry fee T* is equal
to the surplus of the
consumer with the
smaller demand.
The resulting profit is
2T* + (P* − MC)(Q1 + Q2).
Note that this profit is
larger than twice the
area of triangle ABC.
TWO-PART TARIFF WITH MANY
DIFFERENT CONSUMERS
MANY CONSUMERS
Total profit π is the sum of the profit
from the entry fee πa and the profit
from sales πs. Both πa and πs depend on
T, the entry fee.
Therefore
π = πa + πs = n(T)T + (P − MC)Q(n)
where n is the number of entrants,
which depends on the entry fee T, and
Q is the rate of sales, which is greater
the larger is n.
Here T* is the profit-maximizing entry
fee, given P. To calculate optimum
values for P and T, we can start with a
number for P, find the optimum T, and
then estimate the resulting profit. P is
then changed and the corresponding T
recalculated, along with the new profit
level.
PRICING CELLULAR PHONE SERVICE
Most telephone service is priced using a two-part tariff: a
monthly access fee, which may include some free minutes,
plus a per-minute charge for additional minutes. This is also
true for cellular phone service, which has grown explosively,
both in the United States and around the world. In the case
of cellular service, providers have taken the two-part tariff
and turned it into an art form. In most parts of the United
States, consumers can choose among four national network
providers—Verizon, T-Mobile, AT&T, and Sprint. These
providers compete among themselves for customers, but
each has some market power. Market power arises in part
from oligopolistic pricing and output Decisions, but also
because consumers face switching costs: Most service
providers impose a penalty upwards of $200 for early
termination. Because providers have market power, they
must think carefully about profit-maximizing pricing
strategies. The two-part tariff provides an ideal means by
which cellular providers can capture consumer surplus and
turn it into profit. The two-part tariff works best when
consumers have identical or very similar demands.
PRICING CELLULAR PHONE SERVICE
TABLE 3 CELLULAR RATE PLANS (2011)
ANYTIME
MINUNTE
S
MONTHLY
ACCESS
CHARGES
NIGHT &
WEEKEND
MINUTES
PER-MINUTE
RATE AFTER
ALLOWANCE
A. VERIZON: AMERICA’S CHOICE BASIC
450 $39.99 Unlimited $0.45
900 $59.99 Unlimited $0.40
Unlimited $69.99 Unlimited Included
B. SPRINT: BASIC TALK PLANS
200 $29.99 Unlimited $0.45
450 $39.99 Unlimited $0.45
900 $59.99 Unlimited $0.40
C. AT&T INDIVIDUAL PLANS
450 $39.99 5000 $0.45
900 $59.99 Unlimited $0.40
Unlimited $69.99 Unlimited Included
PRICING CELLULAR PHONE SERVICE
TABLE 3 CELLULAR RATE PLANS (2011) (continued)
ANYTIME
MINUNTES
MONTHLY ACCESS
CHARGES
NIGHT & WEEKEND
MINUTES
PER-MINUTE RATE
AFTER ALLOWANCE
D. ORANGE (UK)
100 £10.00 None 2.5 pence
200 £15.00 None 2.5 pence
300 £20.00 None 2.5 pence
E. ORANGE (ISRAEL)
None 28.00 NIS None 0.59 NIS
100 38.00 NIS None 0.59 NIS
400 61.90 NIS None 0.59 NIS
F. CHINA MOBILE
150 58 RMB None 0.40 RMB
450 158 RMB None 0.35 RMB
800 258 RMB None 0.32 RMB
1200 358 RMB None 0.30 RMB
1800 458 RMB None 0.25 RMB
To convert the international prices to U.S. dollars (as of August 2011),
use the following conversion factors: 1£ = $1.60, 1 NIS = $0.30, and 1
RMB = $0.13.
Conclusion
“Monopoly : The earnings of many in
the hands of one.”
Eugene Debs
Core Reading
• Keat, Paul G. and Young, Philip KY (2009)
Managerial Economics, 6th edition, Pearson
• Samuelson, William F. and Marks, Stephen
G.(2010) Managerial Economics, 6th edition, John
Wiley
• Pindyck, Robert S. and Rubinfeld, Daniel L.(2013)
Microeconomics, 8th edition, Pearson
• Samuelson, P.A. and Nordhaus, W. D.
(2010)“Economics” Irwin/McGraw-Hill, 19th
Edition
• Porter, Michael E. (2004)“Competitive Strategy –
Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors”
Free Press
Questions?

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Was ist angesagt?

Some Key Diagrams for Year 1 Micro
Some Key Diagrams for Year 1 MicroSome Key Diagrams for Year 1 Micro
Some Key Diagrams for Year 1 Microtutor2u
 
Market structure and pricing practices
Market structure and pricing practicesMarket structure and pricing practices
Market structure and pricing practicesvtu
 
Price ditermination
Price diterminationPrice ditermination
Price diterminationMudit Mishra
 
Market structure
Market structureMarket structure
Market structureOnline
 
Pricing decisions under different market structures
Pricing decisions under different market structuresPricing decisions under different market structures
Pricing decisions under different market structuresdvy92010
 
Key Diagrams for A2 Business Microeconomics
Key Diagrams for A2 Business MicroeconomicsKey Diagrams for A2 Business Microeconomics
Key Diagrams for A2 Business Microeconomicstutor2u
 
Price & Output Determination under Monopoly
Price & Output Determination under MonopolyPrice & Output Determination under Monopoly
Price & Output Determination under MonopolyStephin Abraham Sabu
 
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in MonopolyPricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopolynazirali423
 
Unit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And Oligopoly
Unit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And OligopolyUnit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And Oligopoly
Unit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And OligopolyCorey Topf
 
Oligopoly & Duopoly
Oligopoly & DuopolyOligopoly & Duopoly
Oligopoly & DuopolyBikash Kumar
 
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic CompetitionMonopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competitiontutor2u
 
Basics of the Economics of Monopoly
Basics of the Economics of MonopolyBasics of the Economics of Monopoly
Basics of the Economics of Monopolytutor2u
 

Was ist angesagt? (20)

Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 
Some Key Diagrams for Year 1 Micro
Some Key Diagrams for Year 1 MicroSome Key Diagrams for Year 1 Micro
Some Key Diagrams for Year 1 Micro
 
Market structure and pricing practices
Market structure and pricing practicesMarket structure and pricing practices
Market structure and pricing practices
 
Monoply
Monoply Monoply
Monoply
 
Price ditermination
Price diterminationPrice ditermination
Price ditermination
 
Market structure
Market structureMarket structure
Market structure
 
Bilateral monopoly
Bilateral monopolyBilateral monopoly
Bilateral monopoly
 
Managerial economics
Managerial economicsManagerial economics
Managerial economics
 
Pricing decisions under different market structures
Pricing decisions under different market structuresPricing decisions under different market structures
Pricing decisions under different market structures
 
Key Diagrams for A2 Business Microeconomics
Key Diagrams for A2 Business MicroeconomicsKey Diagrams for A2 Business Microeconomics
Key Diagrams for A2 Business Microeconomics
 
Duopoly
DuopolyDuopoly
Duopoly
 
6 monopolistic competition
6 monopolistic competition6 monopolistic competition
6 monopolistic competition
 
Price & Output Determination under Monopoly
Price & Output Determination under MonopolyPrice & Output Determination under Monopoly
Price & Output Determination under Monopoly
 
Micro economics
Micro economicsMicro economics
Micro economics
 
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in MonopolyPricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
Pricing and Output Decisions in Monopoly
 
Unit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And Oligopoly
Unit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And OligopolyUnit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And Oligopoly
Unit 2 3 4 And 2 3 5 Mc And Oligopoly
 
Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 
Oligopoly & Duopoly
Oligopoly & DuopolyOligopoly & Duopoly
Oligopoly & Duopoly
 
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic CompetitionMonopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition
 
Basics of the Economics of Monopoly
Basics of the Economics of MonopolyBasics of the Economics of Monopoly
Basics of the Economics of Monopoly
 

Andere mochten auch

Mba1014 production and costs 110513
Mba1014 production and costs 110513Mba1014 production and costs 110513
Mba1014 production and costs 110513Stephen Ong
 
Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513
Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513
Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513Stephen Ong
 
Mba1014 perfect competition 180513
Mba1014 perfect competition 180513Mba1014 perfect competition 180513
Mba1014 perfect competition 180513Stephen Ong
 
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413Stephen Ong
 
Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413
Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413
Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413Stephen Ong
 
Mba1014 supply and demand 010513
Mba1014 supply and demand 010513Mba1014 supply and demand 010513
Mba1014 supply and demand 010513Stephen Ong
 

Andere mochten auch (6)

Mba1014 production and costs 110513
Mba1014 production and costs 110513Mba1014 production and costs 110513
Mba1014 production and costs 110513
 
Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513
Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513
Mba1014 consumers markets elasticity 040513
 
Mba1014 perfect competition 180513
Mba1014 perfect competition 180513Mba1014 perfect competition 180513
Mba1014 perfect competition 180513
 
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
Mba1014 global economic environment 200413
 
Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413
Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413
Mba1014 macro economic environment 200413
 
Mba1014 supply and demand 010513
Mba1014 supply and demand 010513Mba1014 supply and demand 010513
Mba1014 supply and demand 010513
 

Ähnlich wie Mba1014 monopoly 220513

Microeconomics Monopoly
Microeconomics MonopolyMicroeconomics Monopoly
Microeconomics MonopolyRakesh Mehta
 
Price and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdf
Price and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdfPrice and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdf
Price and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdfPiyush773215
 
12 monopoly kusom slides.
12 monopoly kusom slides.12 monopoly kusom slides.
12 monopoly kusom slides.gannibhai
 
10. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp01
10. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp0110. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp01
10. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp01malikjameel1986
 
Chap. 7. Market Structure.pptx
Chap. 7. Market Structure.pptxChap. 7. Market Structure.pptx
Chap. 7. Market Structure.pptxRAMOSERLYNP
 
MARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.ppt
MARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.pptMARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.ppt
MARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.pptAroutselvamChanemoug1
 
consumer and producer surplus
consumer and producer surplusconsumer and producer surplus
consumer and producer surplussehrish628
 
Business economics market structures
Business economics   market structuresBusiness economics   market structures
Business economics market structuresRachit Walia
 
microeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.ppt
microeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.pptmicroeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.ppt
microeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.pptPhamThanhVinh1
 
Lecture 5 27.02.13
Lecture 5 27.02.13Lecture 5 27.02.13
Lecture 5 27.02.13Dan Curtis
 
Chapter 2 detailed on market structures.ppt
Chapter 2 detailed on market structures.pptChapter 2 detailed on market structures.ppt
Chapter 2 detailed on market structures.pptnatan82253
 
Perfect+competetion+1.pptx
Perfect+competetion+1.pptxPerfect+competetion+1.pptx
Perfect+competetion+1.pptxJayvee64
 

Ähnlich wie Mba1014 monopoly 220513 (20)

Microeconomics Monopoly
Microeconomics MonopolyMicroeconomics Monopoly
Microeconomics Monopoly
 
Oligopoly,duopoly
Oligopoly,duopolyOligopoly,duopoly
Oligopoly,duopoly
 
Pricing in Economics
Pricing in Economics Pricing in Economics
Pricing in Economics
 
Price and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdf
Price and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdfPrice and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdf
Price and Output Determination in Monopolistic Competition.pdf
 
Micro
MicroMicro
Micro
 
Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 
12 monopoly kusom slides.
12 monopoly kusom slides.12 monopoly kusom slides.
12 monopoly kusom slides.
 
Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 
10. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp01
10. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp0110. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp01
10. market structure and pricing practices 130119101444-phpapp01
 
Role of microeconomics in pricing a product
Role of microeconomics in pricing a productRole of microeconomics in pricing a product
Role of microeconomics in pricing a product
 
Chap. 7. Market Structure.pptx
Chap. 7. Market Structure.pptxChap. 7. Market Structure.pptx
Chap. 7. Market Structure.pptx
 
Chap6
Chap6Chap6
Chap6
 
Chap6
Chap6Chap6
Chap6
 
MARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.ppt
MARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.pptMARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.ppt
MARKET POWER The Monopoly and monopsony.ppt
 
consumer and producer surplus
consumer and producer surplusconsumer and producer surplus
consumer and producer surplus
 
Business economics market structures
Business economics   market structuresBusiness economics   market structures
Business economics market structures
 
microeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.ppt
microeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.pptmicroeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.ppt
microeconomics - princ-ch15-presentation.ppt
 
Lecture 5 27.02.13
Lecture 5 27.02.13Lecture 5 27.02.13
Lecture 5 27.02.13
 
Chapter 2 detailed on market structures.ppt
Chapter 2 detailed on market structures.pptChapter 2 detailed on market structures.ppt
Chapter 2 detailed on market structures.ppt
 
Perfect+competetion+1.pptx
Perfect+competetion+1.pptxPerfect+competetion+1.pptx
Perfect+competetion+1.pptx
 

Mehr von Stephen Ong

Tcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessmentTcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessmentStephen Ong
 
Tcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysisTcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysisStephen Ong
 
Tcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysisTcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysisStephen Ong
 
Tcm Workshop 1 Technology analysis
Tcm Workshop 1 Technology analysisTcm Workshop 1 Technology analysis
Tcm Workshop 1 Technology analysisStephen Ong
 
Tcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessmentTcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessmentStephen Ong
 
Tcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysisTcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysisStephen Ong
 
Tcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysisTcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysisStephen Ong
 
Tcm concept discovery stage introduction
Tcm concept discovery stage introductionTcm concept discovery stage introduction
Tcm concept discovery stage introductionStephen Ong
 
Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415
Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415
Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415Stephen Ong
 
Tbs910 linear programming
Tbs910 linear programmingTbs910 linear programming
Tbs910 linear programmingStephen Ong
 
Mod001093 family businesses 050415
Mod001093 family businesses 050415Mod001093 family businesses 050415
Mod001093 family businesses 050415Stephen Ong
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415
Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415
Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415Stephen Ong
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315
Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315
Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315Stephen Ong
 
Tbs910 regression models
Tbs910 regression modelsTbs910 regression models
Tbs910 regression modelsStephen Ong
 
Tbs910 sampling hypothesis regression
Tbs910 sampling hypothesis regressionTbs910 sampling hypothesis regression
Tbs910 sampling hypothesis regressionStephen Ong
 
Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315
Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315
Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315Stephen Ong
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii 160315
Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii  160315Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii  160315
Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii 160315Stephen Ong
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i 140315
Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i  140315Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i  140315
Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i 140315Stephen Ong
 
Mod001093 context of sme 220315
Mod001093 context of sme 220315Mod001093 context of sme 220315
Mod001093 context of sme 220315Stephen Ong
 
Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315
Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315
Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315Stephen Ong
 

Mehr von Stephen Ong (20)

Tcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessmentTcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessment
 
Tcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysisTcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysis
 
Tcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysisTcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysis
 
Tcm Workshop 1 Technology analysis
Tcm Workshop 1 Technology analysisTcm Workshop 1 Technology analysis
Tcm Workshop 1 Technology analysis
 
Tcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessmentTcm step 3 venture assessment
Tcm step 3 venture assessment
 
Tcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysisTcm step 2 market needs analysis
Tcm step 2 market needs analysis
 
Tcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysisTcm step 1 technology analysis
Tcm step 1 technology analysis
 
Tcm concept discovery stage introduction
Tcm concept discovery stage introductionTcm concept discovery stage introduction
Tcm concept discovery stage introduction
 
Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415
Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415
Mod001093 german sme hidden champions 120415
 
Tbs910 linear programming
Tbs910 linear programmingTbs910 linear programming
Tbs910 linear programming
 
Mod001093 family businesses 050415
Mod001093 family businesses 050415Mod001093 family businesses 050415
Mod001093 family businesses 050415
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415
Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415
Gs503 vcf lecture 8 innovation finance ii 060415
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315
Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315
Gs503 vcf lecture 7 innovation finance i 300315
 
Tbs910 regression models
Tbs910 regression modelsTbs910 regression models
Tbs910 regression models
 
Tbs910 sampling hypothesis regression
Tbs910 sampling hypothesis regressionTbs910 sampling hypothesis regression
Tbs910 sampling hypothesis regression
 
Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315
Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315
Mod001093 intrapreneurship 290315
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii 160315
Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii  160315Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii  160315
Gs503 vcf lecture 6 partial valuation ii 160315
 
Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i 140315
Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i  140315Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i  140315
Gs503 vcf lecture 5 partial valuation i 140315
 
Mod001093 context of sme 220315
Mod001093 context of sme 220315Mod001093 context of sme 220315
Mod001093 context of sme 220315
 
Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315
Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315
Mod001093 from innovation business model to startup 140315
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen

Organizational Transformation Lead with Culture
Organizational Transformation Lead with CultureOrganizational Transformation Lead with Culture
Organizational Transformation Lead with CultureSeta Wicaksana
 
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023Neil Kimberley
 
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...daisycvs
 
Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...
Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...
Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...allensay1
 
Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...
Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...
Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...Anamikakaur10
 
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Dave Litwiller
 
Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...
Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...
Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...amitlee9823
 
Call Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service AvailableCall Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service AvailableSeo
 
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service NoidaCall Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noidadlhescort
 
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptxCracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptxWorkforce Group
 
Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...
Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...
Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...amitlee9823
 
👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...
👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...
👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...rajveerescorts2022
 
BAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRL
BAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRLBAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRL
BAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRLkapoorjyoti4444
 
FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756
FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756
FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756dollysharma2066
 
B.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptx
B.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptxB.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptx
B.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptxpriyanshujha201
 
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesMysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesDipal Arora
 
Value Proposition canvas- Customer needs and pains
Value Proposition canvas- Customer needs and painsValue Proposition canvas- Customer needs and pains
Value Proposition canvas- Customer needs and painsP&CO
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen (20)

Organizational Transformation Lead with Culture
Organizational Transformation Lead with CultureOrganizational Transformation Lead with Culture
Organizational Transformation Lead with Culture
 
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
Mondelez State of Snacking and Future Trends 2023
 
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
 
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
Quick Doctor In Kuwait +2773`7758`557 Kuwait Doha Qatar Dubai Abu Dhabi Sharj...
 
Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...
Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...
Call Girls Service In Old Town Dubai ((0551707352)) Old Town Dubai Call Girl ...
 
Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...
Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...
Call Now ☎️🔝 9332606886🔝 Call Girls ❤ Service In Bhilwara Female Escorts Serv...
 
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
Enhancing and Restoring Safety & Quality Cultures - Dave Litwiller - May 2024...
 
Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...
Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...
Call Girls Electronic City Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Servi...
 
unwanted pregnancy Kit [+918133066128] Abortion Pills IN Dubai UAE Abudhabi
unwanted pregnancy Kit [+918133066128] Abortion Pills IN Dubai UAE Abudhabiunwanted pregnancy Kit [+918133066128] Abortion Pills IN Dubai UAE Abudhabi
unwanted pregnancy Kit [+918133066128] Abortion Pills IN Dubai UAE Abudhabi
 
Call Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service AvailableCall Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Ludhiana Just Call 98765-12871 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
 
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service NoidaCall Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
Call Girls In Noida 959961⊹3876 Independent Escort Service Noida
 
Falcon Invoice Discounting platform in india
Falcon Invoice Discounting platform in indiaFalcon Invoice Discounting platform in india
Falcon Invoice Discounting platform in india
 
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptxCracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
Cracking the Cultural Competence Code.pptx
 
Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...
Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...
Call Girls Kengeri Satellite Town Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Gir...
 
👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...
👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...
👉Chandigarh Call Girls 👉9878799926👉Just Call👉Chandigarh Call Girl In Chandiga...
 
BAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRL
BAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRLBAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRL
BAGALUR CALL GIRL IN 98274*61493 ❤CALL GIRLS IN ESCORT SERVICE❤CALL GIRL
 
FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756
FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756
FULL ENJOY Call Girls In Majnu Ka Tilla, Delhi Contact Us 8377877756
 
B.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptx
B.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptxB.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptx
B.COM Unit – 4 ( CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY ( CSR ).pptx
 
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesMysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
 
Value Proposition canvas- Customer needs and pains
Value Proposition canvas- Customer needs and painsValue Proposition canvas- Customer needs and pains
Value Proposition canvas- Customer needs and pains
 

Mba1014 monopoly 220513

  • 1. Go Global ! Managerial Economics : Monopoly By Stephen Ong Visiting Fellow, Birmingham City University Visiting Professor, College of Management, Shenzhen University May 2013
  • 2. Agenda 1. Market Power 2. Antitrust 3. Price Discrimination
  • 3. Learning Objectives To understand market power, monopoly and monopsony To explain how the MR=MC rule helps a monopoly to determine its optimum To discuss government regulation and antitrust laws To understand price discrimination in monopoly markets
  • 4. Overview Market power Characteristics of monopoly and monopsony markets Pricing and output decisions in monopoly markets Implications for managerial decisions
  • 6. Firms With Market Power The ability of a firm to influence the prices of its products and develop other competitive strategies that enable it to earn large profits over longer periods of time.
  • 7. The Monopoly Model A market structure characterized by a single firm producing a product with no close substitutes.
  • 8. Monopoly Model - Graphical P Q PM ATCM QM D MR MC ATCP Q PM QM ATCM D MR MC ATC PROFIT LOSS
  • 9. Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition  The Perfectly Competitive Firm  At QPC :  MR = MC  P = ATC  P = MC  Minimum Point of ATC Curve  Price-Taker  Firm Has Supply Curve  The Monopoly Firm  At QM :  MR = MC  P > ATC  P > MC  Not at Minimum Point of ATC  Price-Searcher  Firm Has No Supply Curve
  • 10. Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition - Graphical P Q PM QM D MR MC ATC D = P = MRPC QC ATC MC
  • 11. Another Look at Monopoly vs. Perfect Competition PM PC QCQM AC=MC D MR $ Q
  • 12. Sources of Market Power Economies of scale Barriers created by government Input barriers Brand loyalties Consumer lock-in and switching costs Network externalities
  • 13. Economies of Scale Economies of scale can act as a barrier to entry in different industries because only large-scale firms can achieve the cost-reduction benefits of these economies.
  • 15. Input Barriers Other barriers to entry include control over raw materials or other key inputs in a production process and barriers in financial capital markets.
  • 16. Brand Loyalties The creation of brand loyalties through advertising and other marketing efforts is a strategy that many managers use to create and maintain market power.
  • 17. Consumer Lock-In and Switching Costs Barriers to entry can also result if consumers become locked into certain types or brands of products and would incur substantial switching costs if they changed.
  • 18. Network Externalities Network externalities act as a barrier to entry because the value of a product to consumers depends on the number of customers using the product.
  • 19. Examples of Shifting Market Power Shifting Demand for Kleenex Home Depot and Customer Service Borders Bookstores’ Online Strategy
  • 20. Monopoly Market with only one seller. Monopsony Market with only one buyer. Market power Ability of a seller or buyer to affect the price of a good.
  • 21. Monopoly Average Revenue and Marginal Revenue Marginal revenue : Change in revenue resulting from a one-unit increase in output. TABLE 1 TOTAL, MARGINAL, AND AVERAGE REVENUE PRICE (P) QUANTITY (Q) TOTAL REVENUE (R) MARGINAL REVENUE (MR) AVERAGE REVENUE (AR) $6 0 $0 — — 5 1 5 $5 $5 4 2 8 3 4 3 3 9 1 3 2 4 8 1 2 1 5 5 3 1 Consider a firm facing the following demand curve: P = 6  Q
  • 22. Average and marginal revenue are shown for the demand curve P = 6 − Q. AVERAGE AND MARGINAL REVENUE
  • 23. PROFIT IS MAXIMIZED WHEN MARGINAL REVENUE EQUALS MARGINAL COST The Monopolist’s Output Decision Q* is the output level at which MR = MC. If the firm produces a smaller output—say, Q1—it sacrifices some profit because the extra revenue that could be earned from producing and selling the units between Q1 and Q* exceeds the cost of producing them. Similarly, expanding output from Q* to Q2 would reduce profit because the additional cost would exceed the additional revenue.
  • 24. We can also see algebraically that Q* maximizes profit. Profit π is the difference between revenue and cost, both of which depend on Q: As Q is increased from zero, profit will increase until it reaches a maximum and then begin to decrease. Thus the profit-maximizing Q is such that the incremental profit resulting from a small increase in Q is just zero (i.e., Δπ /ΔQ = 0). Then But ΔR/ΔQ is marginal revenue and ΔC/ΔQ is marginal cost. Thus the profit-maximizing condition is that
  • 25. EXAMPLE OF PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Part (a) shows total revenue R, total cost C, and profit, the difference between the two. Part (b) shows average and marginal revenue and average and marginal cost. Marginal revenue is the slope of the total revenue curve, and marginal cost is the slope of the total cost curve. The profit-maximizing output is Q* = 10, the point where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. At this output level, the slope of the profit curve is zero, and the slopes of the total revenue and total cost curves are equal. The profit per unit is $15, the difference between average revenue and average cost. Because 10 units are produced, total profit is $150.
  • 26. A Rule of Thumb for Pricing Note that the extra revenue from an incremental unit of quantity, Δ(PQ)/ΔQ, has two components: 1. Producing one extra unit and selling it at price P brings in revenue (1)(P) = P. 2. But because the firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, producing and selling this extra unit also results in a small drop in price ΔP/ΔQ, which reduces the revenue from all units sold (i.e., a change in revenue Q[ΔP/ΔQ]).Thus, With limited knowledge of average and marginal revenue, we can derive a rule of thump that can be more easily applied in practice. First, write the expression for marginal revenue:
  • 27. (Q/P)(ΔP/ΔQ) is the reciprocal of the elasticity of demand, 1/Ed, measured at the profit-maximizing output, and Now, because the firm’s objective is to maximize profit, we can set marginal revenue equal to marginal cost: which can be rearranged to give us Equivalently, we can rearrange this equation to express price directly as a markup over marginal cost:
  • 28. ASTRA-MERCK PRICES PRILOSEC In 1995, Prilosec, represented a new generation of anti- ulcer medication. Prilosec was based on a very different biochemical mechanism and was much more effective than earlier drugs. By 1996, it had become the best-selling drug in the world and faced no major competitor. Astra-Merck was pricing Prilosec at about $3.50 per daily dose. The marginal cost of producing and packaging Prilosec is only about 30 to 40 cents per daily dose. The price elasticity of demand, ED, should be in the range of roughly −1.0 to −1.2. Setting the price at a markup exceeding 400 percent over marginal cost is consistent with our rule of thumb for pricing.
  • 29. Shifts in Demand A monopolistic market has no supply curve. In other words, there is no one-to-one relationship between price and the quantity produced. The reason is that the monopolist’s output decision depends not only on marginal cost but also on the shape of the demand curve. As a result, shifts in demand do not trace out the series of prices and quantities that correspond to a competitive supply curve. Instead, shifts in demand can lead to changes in price with no change in output, changes in output with no change in price, or changes in both price and output. Shifts in demand usually cause changes in both price and quantity. A competitive industry supplies a specific quantity at every price. No such relationship exists for a monopolist, which, depending on how demand shifts, might supply several different quantities at the same price, or the same quantity at different prices.
  • 30. SHIFTS IN DEMAND Shifting the demand curve shows that a monopolistic market has no supply curve— i.e., there is no one-to-one relationship between price and quantity produced. In (a), the demand curve D1 shifts to new demand curve D2. But the new marginal revenue curve MR2 intersects marginal cost at the same point as the old marginal revenue curve MR1. The profit- maximizing output therefore remains the same, although price falls from P1 to P2. In (b), the new marginal revenue curve MR2 intersects marginal cost at a higher output level Q2. But because demand is now more elastic, price remains the same.
  • 31. THE DEMAND FOR TOOTHBRUSHES Monopoly Power Part (a) shows the market demand for toothbrushes. Part (b) shows the demand for toothbrushes as seen by Firm A. At a market price of $1.50, elasticity of market demand is −1.5. Firm A, however, sees a much more elastic demand curve DA because of competition from other firms. At a price of $1.50, Firm A’s demand elasticity is −6. Still, Firm A has some monopoly power: Its profit- maximizing price is $1.50, which exceeds marginal cost.
  • 32. ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND FOR SOFT DRINKS Soft drinks provide a good example of the difference between a market elasticity of demand and a firm’s elasticity of demand. In addition, soft drinks are important because their consumption has been linked to childhood obesity; there could be health benefits from taxing them. A recent review of several statistical studies found that the market elasticity of demand for soft drinks is between −0.8 and −1.0.6 That means that if all soft drink producers increased the prices of all of their brands by 1 percent, the quantity of soft drinks demanded would fall by 0.8 to 1.0 percent. The demand for any individual soft drink, however, will be much more elastic, because consumers can readily substitute one drink for another. Although elasticities will differ across different brands, studies have shown that the elasticity of demand for, say, Coca Cola is around −5.7 In other words, if the price of Coke were increased by 1 percent but the prices of all other soft drinks remained unchanged, the quantity of Coke demanded would fall by about 5 percent. Students—and business people— sometimes confuse the market elasticity of demand with the firm (or brand) elasticity of demand.
  • 33. ELASTICITY OF DEMAND AND PRICE MARKUP The Rule of Thumb for Pricing The markup (P − MC)/P is equal to minus the inverse of the elasticity of demand. If the firm’s demand is elastic, as in (a), the markup is small and the firm has little monopoly power. The opposite is true if demand is relatively inelastic, as in (b).
  • 34. MARKUP PRICING: SUPERMARKETS TO DESIGNER JEANS Although the elasticity of market demand for food is small (about −1), no single supermarket can raise its prices very much without losing customers to other stores. The elasticity of demand for any one supermarket is often as large as −10. We find P = MC/(1 − 0.1) =MC/(0.9) = (1.11)MC. The manager of a typical supermarket should set prices about 11 percent above marginal cost. Small convenience stores typically charge higher prices because its customers are generally less price sensitive. Because the elasticity of demand for a convenience store is about −5, the markup equation implies that its prices should be about 25 percent above marginal cost. With designer jeans, demand elasticities in the range of −2 to −3 are typical. This means that price should be 50 to 100 percent higher than marginal cost.
  • 35. THE PRICING OF VIDEOS When the market for videos was young, producers had no good estimates of the elasticity of demand. As the market matured, however, sales data and market research studies put pricing decisions on firmer ground. By the 1990s, most producers had lowered prices across the board. TABLE 2 RETAIL PRICES OF VIDEOS IN 1985 AND 2011 1985 2011 TITLE RETAIL PRICE ($) TITLE RETAIL PRICE ($) VHS DVD Purple Rain $29.98 Tangled $20.60 Raiders of the Lost Ark $24.95 Harry Potter and the Deathly Hallows, Part 1 $20.58 Jane Fonda Workout $59.95 Megamind $18.74 The Empire Strikes Back $79.98 Despicable Me $14.99 An Officer and a Gentleman $24.95 Red $27.14 Star Trek: The Motion Picture $24.95 The King’s Speech $14.99 Star Wars $39.98 Secretariat $20.60
  • 36. VIDEO SALES Between 1990 and 1998, lower prices induced consumers to buy many more videos. By 2001, sales of DVDs overtook sales of VHS videocassettes. High-definition DVDs were introduced in 2006, and are expected to displace sales of conventional DVDs. All DVDs, however, are now being displaced by streaming video. THE PRICING OF VIDEOS
  • 37. Sources of Monopoly Power The less elastic its demand curve, the more monopoly power a firm has. The ultimate determinant of monopoly power is therefore the firm’s elasticity of demand. Three factors determine a firm’s elasticity of demand. 1. The elasticity of market demand. Because the firm’s own demand will be at least as elastic as market demand, the elasticity of market demand limits the potential for monopoly power. 2. The number of firms in the market. If there are many firms, it is unlikely that any one firm will be able to affect price significantly. 3. The interaction among firms. Even if only two or three firms are in the market, each firm will be unable to profitably raise price very much if the rivalry among them is aggressive, with each firm trying to capture as much of the market as it can.
  • 38. If there is only one firm—a pure monopolist—its demand curve is the market demand curve. In this case, the firm’s degree of monopoly power depends completely on the elasticity of market demand. When several firms compete with one another, the elasticity of market demand sets a lower limit on the magnitude of the elasticity of demand for each firm. A particular firm’s elasticity depends on how the firms compete with one another, and the elasticity of market demand limits the potential monopoly power of individual producers. Because the demand for oil is fairly inelastic (at least in the short run), OPEC could raise oil prices far above marginal production cost during the 1970s and early 1980s. Because the demands for such commodities as coffee, cocoa, tin, and copper are much more elastic, attempts by producers to cartelize these markets and raise prices have largely failed. In each case, the elasticity of market demand limits the potential monopoly power of individual producers. 1. The Elasticity of Market Demand
  • 39. 2.The Number of Firms Other things being equal, the monopoly power of each firm will fall as the number of firms increases. When only a few firms account for most of the sales in a market, we say that the market is highly concentrated. Barrier to entry Condition that impedes entry by new competitors. 1. Sometimes there are natural barriers to entry. 2. Patents, copyrights, and licenses 3. Economies of scale may make it too costly for more than a few firms to supply the entire market. In some cases, economies of scale may be so large that it is most efficient for a single firm—a natural monopoly—to supply the entire market.
  • 40. 3.The Interaction Among Firms Firms might compete aggressively, undercutting one another’s prices to capture more market share, or they might not compete much. They might even collude (in violation of the antitrust laws), agreeing to limit output and raise prices. Other things being equal, monopoly power is smaller when firms compete aggressively and is larger when they cooperate. Because raising prices in concert rather than individually is more likely to be profitable, collusion can generate substantial monopoly power. Remember that a firm’s monopoly power often changes over time, as its operating conditions (market demand and cost), its behaviour, and the behaviour of its competitors change. Monopoly power must therefore be thought of in a dynamic context. Furthermore, real or potential monopoly power in the short run can make an industry more competitive in the long run: Large short-run profits can induce new firms to enter an industry, thereby reducing monopoly power over the longer term.
  • 41. The Social Costs of Monopoly Power DEADWEIGHT LOSS FROM MONOPOLY POWER The shaded rectangle and triangles show changes in consumer and producer surplus when moving from competitive price and quantity, Pc and Qc, to a monopolist’s price and quantity, Pm and Qm. Because of the higher price, consumers lose A + B and producer gains A − C. The deadweight loss is B + C. Rent Seeking Spending money in socially unproductive efforts to acquire, maintain, or exercise monopoly. We would expect the economic incentive to incur rent- seeking costs to bear a direct relation to the gains from monopoly power (i.e., rectangle A minus triangle C.)
  • 42. REGULATING THE PRICE OF A NATURAL MONOPOLY A firm is a natural monopoly because it has economies of scale (declining average and marginal costs) over its entire output range. If price were regulated to be Pc the firm would lose money and go out of business. Setting the price at Pr yields the largest possible output consistent with the firm’s remaining in business; excess profit is zero. Natural Monopoly Firm that can produce the entire output of the market at a cost lower than what it would be if there were several firms.
  • 43. Monopsony Oligopsony Market with only a few buyers. Monopsony power Buyer’s ability to affect the price of a good. Marginal value Additional benefit derived from purchasing one more unit of a good. Marginal expenditure Additional cost of buying one more unit of a good. Average expenditure Price paid per unit of a good.
  • 44. COMPETITIVE BUYER COMPARED TO COMPETITIVE SELLER In (a), the competitive buyer takes market price P* as given. Therefore, marginal expenditure and average expenditure are constant and equal; quantity purchased is found by equating price to marginal value (demand). In (b), the competitive seller also takes price as given. Marginal revenue and average revenue are constant and equal; quantity sold is found by equating price to marginal cost.
  • 45. MONOPSONIST BUYER The market supply curve is monopsonist’s average expenditure curve AE. Because average expenditure is rising, marginal expenditure lies above it. The monopsonist purchases quantity Q*m, where marginal expenditure and marginal value (demand) intersect. The price paid per unit P*m is then found from the average expenditure (supply) curve. In a competitive market, price and quantity, Pc and Qc, are both higher. They are found at the point where average expenditure (supply) and marginal value (demand) intersect.
  • 46. These diagrams show the close analogy between monopoly and monopsony. (a) The monopolist produces where marginal revenue intersects marginal cost. Average revenue exceeds marginal revenue, so that price exceeds marginal cost. (b) The monopsonist purchases up to the point where marginal expenditure intersects marginal value. Marginal expenditure exceeds average expenditure, so that marginal value exceeds price. Monopsony and Monopoly Compared
  • 47. MONOPSONY POWER: ELASTIC VERSUS INELASTIC SUPPLY Monopsony power depends on the elasticity of supply. When supply is elastic, as in (a), marginal expenditure and average expenditure do not differ by much, so price is close to what it would be in a competitive market. The opposite is true when supply is inelastic, as in (b). Monopsony Power
  • 48. Sources of Monopsony Power ELASTICITY OF MARKET SUPPLY If only one buyer is in the market—a pure monopsonist—its monopsony power is completely determined by the elasticity of market supply. If supply is highly elastic, monopsony power is small and there is little gain in being the only buyer. NUMBER OF BUYERS When the number of buyers is very large, no single buyer can have much influence over price. Thus each buyer faces an extremely elastic supply curve, so that the market is almost completely competitive. INTERACTION AMONG BUYERS If four buyers in a market compete aggressively, they will bid up the price close to their marginal value of the product, and will thus have little monopsony power. On the other hand, if those buyers compete less aggressively, or even collude, prices will not be bid up very much, and the buyers’ degree of monopsony power might be nearly as high as if there were only one buyer.
  • 49. DEADWEIGHT LOSS FROM MONOPSONY POWER The Social Costs of Monopsony Power The shaded rectangle and triangles show changes in buyer and seller surplus when moving from competitive price and quantity, Pc and Qc, to the monopsonist’s price and quantity, Pm and Qm. Because both price and quantity are lower, there is an increase in buyer (consumer) surplus given by A − B. Producer surplus falls by A + C, so there is a deadweight loss given by triangles B and C.
  • 50. Bilateral Monopoly Market with only one seller and one buyer. It is difficult to predict the price and quantity in a bilateral monopoly. Both the buyer and the seller are in a bargaining situation. Bilateral monopoly is rare. Although bargaining may still be involved, we can apply a rough principle here: Monopsony power and monopoly power will tend to counteract each other. In other words, the monopsony power of buyers will reduce the effective monopoly power of sellers, and vice versa. This tendency does not mean that the market will end up looking perfectly competitive, but in general, monopsony power will push price closer to marginal cost, and monopoly power will push price closer to marginal value.
  • 51. MONOPSONY POWER IN U.S. MANUFACTURING The role of monopsony power was investigated to determine the extent to which variations in price-cost margins could be attributed to variations in monopsony power. The study found that buyers’ monopsony power had an important effect on the price-cost margins of sellers. In industries where only four or five buyers account for all or nearly all sales, the price-cost margins of sellers would on average be as much as 10 percentage points lower than in comparable industries with hundreds of buyers accounting for sales. Each major car producer in the United States typically buys an individual part from at least three, and often as many as a dozen, suppliers. For a specialized part, a single auto company may be the only buyer. As a result, the automobile companies have considerable monopsony power. Not surprisingly, producers of parts and components usually have little or no monopoly power.
  • 53. Measures of Market Power Lerner Index Cross Price Elasticity of Demand Concentration Ratios The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
  • 54. Measuring Monopoly Power : Lerner Index Remember the important distinction between a perfectly competitive firm and a firm with monopoly power: For the competitive firm, price equals marginal cost; for the firm with monopoly power, price exceeds marginal cost. Lerner Index of Monopoly Power Measure of monopoly power calculated as excess of price over marginal cost as a fraction of price. Mathematically: This index of monopoly power can also be expressed in terms of the elasticity of demand facing the firm.
  • 55. The regulation of a monopoly is sometimes based on the rate of return that it earns on its capital. The regulatory agency determines an allowed price, so that this rate of return is in some sense “competitive” or “fair.” Although it is a key element in determining the firm’s rate of return, a firm’s capital stock is difficult to value. While a “fair” rate of return must be based on the firm’s actual cost of capital, that cost depends in turn on the behaviour of the regulatory agency. Regulatory lag is a term associated with delays in changing regulated prices. Another approach to regulation is setting price caps based on the firm’s variable costs. A price cap can allow for more flexibility than rate- of-return regulation. Under price cap regulation, for example, a firm would typically be allowed to raise its prices each year (without having to get approval from the regulatory agency) by an amount equal to the actual rate of inflation, minus expected productivity growth. Regulation in Practice Rate-of-return regulation Maximum price allowed by a regulatory agency is based on the (expected) rate of return that a firm will earn.
  • 56. The Effect of a Tax EFFECT OF EXCISE TAX ON MONOPOLIST With a tax t per unit, the firm’s effective marginal cost is increased by the amount t to MC + t. In this example, the increase in price ΔP is larger than the tax t. Suppose a specific tax of t dollars per unit is levied, so that the monopolist must remit t dollars to the government for every unit it sells. If MC was the firm’s original marginal cost, its optimal production decision is now given by
  • 57. PRICE REGULATION If left alone, a monopolist produces Qm and charges Pm. When the government imposes a price ceiling of P1 the firm’s average and marginal revenue are constant and equal to P1 for output levels up to Q1. For larger output levels, the original average and marginal revenue curves apply. The new marginal revenue curve is, therefore, the dark purple line, which intersects the marginal cost curve at Q1. Price Regulation
  • 58. PRICE REGULATION When price is lowered to Pc, at the point where marginal cost intersects average revenue, output increases to its maximum Qc. This is the output that would be produced by a competitive industry. Lowering price further, to P3, reduces output to Q3 and causes a shortage, Q’3 − Q3.
  • 59. Limiting Market Power: The Antitrust Laws Antitrust laws Rules and regulations prohibiting actions that restrain, or are likely to restrain, competition. Excessive market power harms potential purchasers and raises problems of equity and fairness. In addition, market power reduces output, which leads to a deadweight loss. In theory, a firm’s excess profits could be taxed away, but redistribution of the firm’s profits is often impractical. To limit the market power of a natural monopoly, such as an electric utility company, direct price regulation is the answer. It is important to stress that, while there are limitations (such as colluding with other firms), in general, it is not illegal to be a monopolist or to have market power. On the contrary, we have seen that patent and copyright laws protect the monopoly positions of firms that developed unique innovations.
  • 60. Restricting what Firms can do Parallel conduct Form of implicit collusion in which one firm consistently follows actions of another. Predatory pricing Practice of pricing to drive current competitors out of business and to discourage new entrants in a market so that a firm can enjoy higher future profits.
  • 61. Antitrust Issues The Sherman Act of 1890 The Clayton Act of 1914 The Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914
  • 62. The antitrust laws are enforced in three ways in USA : 1. Through the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice. 2. Through the administrative procedures of the Federal Trade Commission. 3. Through private proceedings. Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws
  • 63. Antitrust in Europe  At first glance, the antitrust laws of the European Union are quite similar to those of the United States. Article 101 of the Treaty of the European Community concerns restraints of trade, much like Section 1 of the Sherman Act.  Article 102, which focuses on abuses of market power by dominant firms, is similar in many ways to Section 2 of the Sherman Act.  Finally, with respect to mergers, the European Merger Control Act is similar in spirit to Section 7 of the Clayton Act.  Nevertheless, there remain a number of procedural and substantive differences between antitrust laws in Europe and the United States. Merger evaluations typically are conducted more quickly in Europe.  Antitrust enforcement has grown rapidly through the world in the past decade.
  • 64. A PHONE CALL ABOUT PRICES Robert Crandall, president and CEO of American, made a phone call to Howard Putnam, president and chief executive of Braniff. It went like this: Crandall: I think it’s dumb as hell for Christ’s sake, all right, to sit here and pound the @!#$%&! out of each other and neither one of us making a @!#$%&! dime. Putnam: Well . . . Crandall: I mean, you know, @!#$%&!, what the hell is the point of it? Putnam: But if you’re going to overlay every route of American’s on top of every route that Braniff has—I just can’t sit here and allow you to bury us without giving our best effort. Crandall: Oh sure, but Eastern and Delta do the same thing in Atlanta and have for years. Putnam: Do you have a suggestion for me?
  • 65. A PHONE CALL ABOUT PRICES Crandall: Yes, I have a suggestion for you. Raise your @!#$%&! fares 20 percent. I’ll raise mine the next morning. Putnam: Robert, we. . . Crandall: You’ll make more money and I will, too. Putnam: We can’t talk about pricing! Crandall: Oh @!#$%&!, Howard. We can talk about any @!#$%&! thing we want to talk about. Crandall was wrong. Talking about prices and agreeing to fix them is a clear violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act. However, proposing to fix prices is not enough to violate Section 1 of the Sherman Act: For the law to be violated, the two parties must agree to collude. Therefore, because Putnam had rejected Crandall’s proposal, Section 1 was not violated.
  • 66. GO DIRECTLY TO JAIL. DON’T PASS GO If you become a successful business executive, think twice before picking up the phone. And if your company happens to be located in Europe or Asia, don’t think that will keep you out of a U.S. jail. For example: In 1996 Archer Daniels Midland (ADM) and two other producers of lysine (an animal feed additive) pled guilty to charges of price fixing. In 1999 three ADM executives were sentenced to prison terms of two to three years. In 1999 four of the world’s largest drug and chemical companies—Hoffman-La Roche of Switzerland, BASF of Germany, Rhone Poulenc of France, and Takeda of Japan—pled guilty to fixing the prices of vitamins sold in the U.S. and Europe. The companies paid about $1.5 billion in penalties to the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ), $1 billion to the European Commission, and over $4 billion to settle civil suits. Executives from each of the companies did prison time in the U.S.
  • 67. GO DIRECTLY TO JAIL. DON’T PASS GO During 2002 to 2009, Horizon Lines engaged in price fixing with Sea Star Lines (Puerto Rico-based shipping companies). Five executives got prison terms ranging from one to four years. Eight companies, mostly in Korea and Japan, fixed DRAM (memory chip) prices from 1998 to 2002. In 2007, 18 executives from these companies were sentenced to prison terms in the United States. In 2009, five companies pled guilty to fixing prices of LCD displays during 2001-2006. 22 executives received prison sentences in the United States (on top of $1 billion in fines). In 2011, two companies were convicted of fixing prices and rigging bids for ready-mix concrete in Iowa. One executive was sentenced to one year in prison, another to four years.
  • 68. THE UNITED STATES AND THE EUROPEAN UNION VERSUS MICROSOFT Over the past two decades Microsoft has grown to become the largest computer software company in the world, and has dominated the office productivity market. Under the antitrust laws of the United States and the European Union, efforts by firms to restrain trade or to engage in activities that inappropriately maintain monopolies are illegal. Did Microsoft engage in anticompetitive, illegal practices? In 1998, the U.S. government said yes; Microsoft disagreed. The Antitrust Division of the U.S. DOJ filed suit, claiming that Microsoft had illegally bundled its Internet browser, Internet Explorer, with its operating system for the purpose of maintaining its dominant operating system monopoly. Following an eight- month trial that was hard-fought on a range of economic issues, the District Court found that Microsoft did have monopoly power in the market for PC operating systems, which it had maintained illegally in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. The U.S. case was ultimately settled in 2004, with (among other things) Microsoft agreeing to give computer manufacturers (1) the ability to offer an operating system without Internet Explorer and (2) the option of loading competing browser Programs on the PCs that they sell.
  • 69. THE UNITED STATES AND THE EUROPEAN UNION VERSUS MICROSOFT Microsoft’s problems did not end with the U.S. settlement, however. In 2004, the European Commission ordered Microsoft to pay $794 million in fines for its anti- competitive practices, to produce a version of Windows without the Windows Media Player to be sold alongside its standard editions. In 2008, the European Commission levied an additional fine of $1.44 billion, claiming that Microsoft had not complied with the earlier decision. Even more recently, in response to a concern relating to the bundling of browsers, Microsoft agreed to offer customers a choice of browsers when first booting up their new operating system. As of 2011, the European case against Microsoft remains on appeal. There is strong evidence that the European- imposed remedies have had little impact on the market for media players or browsers. However, Microsoft is facing an even stronger threat than U.S. or E.U. enforcement, such as competition from the powerful Google search engine and social media sites such as Facebook.
  • 71. Pricing and output decisions in monopoly markets  A monopoly market consists of one firm (the firm is the market) • firm has the power to set any price it wants • however, the firm’s ability to set price is limited by the demand curve for its product, and in particular, the price elasticity of demand
  • 72. Pricing and output decisions in monopoly markets Assume demand is linear: it is downward sloping because the firm is a price setter Assume MC is constant  choose output where MR=MC, set price at P*
  • 73. Pricing and output decisions in monopoly markets Demand is the same as before, as is MR MC is upward sloping, which shows diminishing returns  set output where MR=MC
  • 74. Implications of monopoly for decision making  Monopoly market  most important lesson is not to be arrogant and assume their ability to earn economic profit can never be diminished  changes in economics of a business eventually break down a dominating company’s monopolistic power
  • 75. Capturing Consumer Surplus CAPTURING CONSUMER SURPLUS Price discrimination Practice of charging different prices to different consumers for similar goods. If a firm can charge only one price for all its customers, that price will be P* and the quantity produced will be Q*. Ideally, the firm would like to charge a higher price to consumers willing to pay more than P*, thereby capturing some of the consumer surplus under region A of the demand curve. The firm would also like to sell to consumers willing to pay prices lower than P*, but only if doing so does not entail lowering the price to other consumers. In that way, the firm could also capture some of the surplus under region B of the demand curve.
  • 76. First degree price discrimination Practice of charging each customer her reservation price. First-Degree Price Discrimination Variable profit Sum of profits on each incremental unit produced by a firm; i.e., profit ignoring fixed costs. Reservation price Maximum price that a customer is willing to pay for a good. Price Discrimination
  • 77. ADDITIONAL PROFIT FROM PERFECT FIRST- DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION Because the firm charges each consumer her reservation price, it is profitable to expand output to Q**. When only a single price, P*, is charged, the firm’s variable profit is the area between the marginal revenue and marginal cost curves. With perfect price discrimination, this profit expands to the area between the demand curve and the marginal cost curve.
  • 78. FIRST-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN PRACTICE PERFECT PRICE DISCRIMINATION The additional profit from producing and selling an incremental unit is the difference between demand and marginal cost. IMPERFECT PRICE DISCRIMINATION Firms usually don’t know the reservation price of every consumer, but sometimes reservation prices can be roughly identified. Here, six different prices are charged. The firm earns higher profits, but some consumers may also benefit. With a single price P4, there are fewer consumers. The consumers who now pay P5 or P6 enjoy a surplus.
  • 79. SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION Second-Degree Price Discrimination Practice of charging different prices per unit for different quantities of the same good or service. Block pricing : Practice of charging different prices for different quantities or “blocks” of a good. Different prices are charged for different quantities, or “blocks,” of the same good. Here, there are three blocks, with corresponding prices P1, P2, and P3. There are also economies of scale, and average and marginal costs are declining. Second-degree price discrimination can then make consumers better off by expanding output and lowering cost.
  • 80. Third-Degree Price Discrimination Practice of dividing consumers into two or more groups with separate demand curves and charging different prices to each group. CREATING CONSUMER GROUPS If third-degree price discrimination is feasible, how should the firm decide what price to charge each group of consumers? 1. We know that however much is produced, total output should be divided between the groups of customers so that marginal revenues for each group are equal. 2. We know that total output must be such that the marginal revenue for each group of consumers is equal to the marginal cost of production.
  • 81. DETERMINING RELATIVE PRICES Let P1 be the price charged to the first group of consumers, P2 the price charged to the second group, and C(QT) the total cost of producing output QT = Q1 + Q2. Total profit is then
  • 82. THIRD-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION Consumers are divided into two groups, with separate demand curves for each group. The optimal prices and quantities are such that the marginal revenue from each group is the same and equal to marginal cost. Here group 1, with demand curve D1, is charged P1, and group 2, with the more elastic demand curve D2, is charged the lower price P2. Marginal cost depends on the total quantity produced QT. Note that Q1 and Q2 are chosen so that MR1 = MR2 = MC.
  • 83. NO SALES TO SMALLER MARKETS Even if third-degree price discrimination is feasible, it may not pay to sell to both groups of consumers if marginal cost is rising. Here the first group of consumers, with demand D1, are not willing to pay much for the product. It is unprofitable to sell to them because the price would have to be too low to compensate for the resulting increase in marginal cost.
  • 84. THE ECONOMICS OF COUPONS AND REBATES Coupons provide a means of price discrimination. TABLE 1 PRICE ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND FOR USERS VERSUS NONUSERS OF COUPONS PRICE ELASTICITY PRODUCT NONUSERS USERS Toilet tissue – 0.60 –0.66 Stuffing/dressing –0.71 –0.96 Shampoo –0.84 –1.04 Cooking/salad oil –1.22 –1.32 Dry mix dinners –0.88 –1.09 Cake mix –0.21 –0.43 Cat food –0.49 –1.13 Frozen entrees –0.60 –0.95 Gelatin –0.97 –1.25 Spaghetti sauce –1.65 –1.81 Crème rinse/conditioner –0.82 –1.12 Soups –1.05 –1.22 Hot dogs –0.59 –0.77
  • 85. AIRLINE FARES TABLE 2 ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND FOR AIR TRAVEL FARE CATEGORY ELASTICITY FIRST CLASS UNRESTRICTED COACH DISCOUNTED Price –0.3 –0.4 –0.9 Income 1.2 1.2 1.8 Travelers are often amazed at the variety of fares available for round- trip flights from New York to Los Angeles. Recently, for example, the first-class fare was above $2000; the regular (unrestricted) economy fare was about $1000, and special discount fares (often requiring the purchase of a ticket two weeks in advance and/or a Saturday night stayover) could be bought for as little as $200. These fares provide a profitable form of price discrimination. The gains from discriminating are large because different types of customers, with very different elasticities of demand, purchase these different types of tickets. Airline price discrimination has become increasingly sophisticated. A wide variety of fares is available.
  • 86. Intertemporal Price Discrimination and Peak-Load Pricing INTERTEMPORAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION Intertemporal price discrimination Spending money in socially unproductive efforts to acquire, maintain, or exercise monopoly. Peak-load pricing Spending money in socially unproductive efforts to acquire, maintain, or exercise monopoly. Consumers are divided into groups by changing the price over time. Initially, the price is high. The firm captures surplus from consumers who have a high demand for the good and who are unwilling to wait to buy it. Later the price is reduced to appeal to the mass market.
  • 87. PEAK-LOAD PRICING Peak-Load Pricing Demands for some goods and services increase sharply during particular times of the day or year. Charging a higher price P1 during the peak periods is more profitable for the firm than charging a single price at all times. It is also more efficient because marginal cost is higher during peak periods.
  • 88. HOW TO PRICE A BEST-SELLING NOVEL Publishing both hardbound and paperback editions of a book allows publishers to price discriminate. Some consumers want to buy a new bestseller as soon as it is released, even if the price is $25. Other consumers, however, will wait a year until the book is available in paperback for $10. The key is to divide consumers into two groups, so that those who are willing to pay a high price do so and only those unwilling to pay a high price wait and buy the paperback. It is clear, however, that those consumers willing to wait for the paperback edition have demands that are far more elastic than those of bibliophiles. It is not surprising, then, that paperback editions sell for so much less than hardbacks.
  • 89. The Two-Part Tariff TWO-PART TARIFF WITH A SINGLE CONSUMER Form of pricing in which consumers are charged both an entry and a usage fee. SINGLE CONSUMER The consumer has demand curve D. The firm maximizes profit by setting usage fee P equal to marginal cost and entry fee T* equal to the entire surplus of the consumer.
  • 90. TWO-PART TARIFF WITH TWO CONSUMERS TWO CONSUMERS The profit-maximizing usage fee P* will exceed marginal cost. The entry fee T* is equal to the surplus of the consumer with the smaller demand. The resulting profit is 2T* + (P* − MC)(Q1 + Q2). Note that this profit is larger than twice the area of triangle ABC.
  • 91. TWO-PART TARIFF WITH MANY DIFFERENT CONSUMERS MANY CONSUMERS Total profit π is the sum of the profit from the entry fee πa and the profit from sales πs. Both πa and πs depend on T, the entry fee. Therefore π = πa + πs = n(T)T + (P − MC)Q(n) where n is the number of entrants, which depends on the entry fee T, and Q is the rate of sales, which is greater the larger is n. Here T* is the profit-maximizing entry fee, given P. To calculate optimum values for P and T, we can start with a number for P, find the optimum T, and then estimate the resulting profit. P is then changed and the corresponding T recalculated, along with the new profit level.
  • 92. PRICING CELLULAR PHONE SERVICE Most telephone service is priced using a two-part tariff: a monthly access fee, which may include some free minutes, plus a per-minute charge for additional minutes. This is also true for cellular phone service, which has grown explosively, both in the United States and around the world. In the case of cellular service, providers have taken the two-part tariff and turned it into an art form. In most parts of the United States, consumers can choose among four national network providers—Verizon, T-Mobile, AT&T, and Sprint. These providers compete among themselves for customers, but each has some market power. Market power arises in part from oligopolistic pricing and output Decisions, but also because consumers face switching costs: Most service providers impose a penalty upwards of $200 for early termination. Because providers have market power, they must think carefully about profit-maximizing pricing strategies. The two-part tariff provides an ideal means by which cellular providers can capture consumer surplus and turn it into profit. The two-part tariff works best when consumers have identical or very similar demands.
  • 93. PRICING CELLULAR PHONE SERVICE TABLE 3 CELLULAR RATE PLANS (2011) ANYTIME MINUNTE S MONTHLY ACCESS CHARGES NIGHT & WEEKEND MINUTES PER-MINUTE RATE AFTER ALLOWANCE A. VERIZON: AMERICA’S CHOICE BASIC 450 $39.99 Unlimited $0.45 900 $59.99 Unlimited $0.40 Unlimited $69.99 Unlimited Included B. SPRINT: BASIC TALK PLANS 200 $29.99 Unlimited $0.45 450 $39.99 Unlimited $0.45 900 $59.99 Unlimited $0.40 C. AT&T INDIVIDUAL PLANS 450 $39.99 5000 $0.45 900 $59.99 Unlimited $0.40 Unlimited $69.99 Unlimited Included
  • 94. PRICING CELLULAR PHONE SERVICE TABLE 3 CELLULAR RATE PLANS (2011) (continued) ANYTIME MINUNTES MONTHLY ACCESS CHARGES NIGHT & WEEKEND MINUTES PER-MINUTE RATE AFTER ALLOWANCE D. ORANGE (UK) 100 £10.00 None 2.5 pence 200 £15.00 None 2.5 pence 300 £20.00 None 2.5 pence E. ORANGE (ISRAEL) None 28.00 NIS None 0.59 NIS 100 38.00 NIS None 0.59 NIS 400 61.90 NIS None 0.59 NIS F. CHINA MOBILE 150 58 RMB None 0.40 RMB 450 158 RMB None 0.35 RMB 800 258 RMB None 0.32 RMB 1200 358 RMB None 0.30 RMB 1800 458 RMB None 0.25 RMB To convert the international prices to U.S. dollars (as of August 2011), use the following conversion factors: 1£ = $1.60, 1 NIS = $0.30, and 1 RMB = $0.13.
  • 95. Conclusion “Monopoly : The earnings of many in the hands of one.” Eugene Debs
  • 96. Core Reading • Keat, Paul G. and Young, Philip KY (2009) Managerial Economics, 6th edition, Pearson • Samuelson, William F. and Marks, Stephen G.(2010) Managerial Economics, 6th edition, John Wiley • Pindyck, Robert S. and Rubinfeld, Daniel L.(2013) Microeconomics, 8th edition, Pearson • Samuelson, P.A. and Nordhaus, W. D. (2010)“Economics” Irwin/McGraw-Hill, 19th Edition • Porter, Michael E. (2004)“Competitive Strategy – Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors” Free Press