SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 42
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3181607
Investor Psychology and Security Market Under-
and Overreactions
Journal of Finance, December 1998.
Kent Daniel
David Hirshleifer
Avanidhar Subrahmanyam
Fin 9310 – Behavioral Finance Seminar
- April 4, 2018 -
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3181607
Outline
1. Challenges to Behavioral Finance
2. This Paper’s Goals
3. Regularities in Anomalous Price Patterns
4. The Overconfidence Theory
• Psychological Evidence on Overconfidence and on Biased
Self-Attribution
• Model Setup
5. Model Implications
• Reaction to Public and Private Information
• Event Study Implications
• Price Scaled Variables
– Aggregate and Cross-Sectional Forecastability
• Short and Long Horizon Autocorrelations
• Short and Long Horizon Correlations with Information
Releases
• Corporate Finance Implications
6. Relation to Existing Theories
7. Conclusion
2
Challenges: Financial Market Anomalies
• There is now evidence of strong return predictability
• This evidence is largely responsible for the growth in interest
in behavioral finance.
• However, the over-reaction/under-reaction interpretations of-
ten given to this evidence appear contradictory:
[In the behavioral literature] ...[a]pparent anomalies
are viewed one at a time, and the same authors, ex-
amining different events, seem content with over-reaction
or under-reaction, and willing to infer that both war-
rant dropping market efficiency. (Fama 1998)
• The apparent inconsistency makes the behavioral stories ap-
pear no better than the market efficiency hypothesis:
The market efficiency hypothesis, of course, offers a
simple answer to this question – chance. Specifically,
the expected value of abnormal returns is zero, but
chance generates apparent anomalies that split ran-
domly between apparent over-reaction and apparent
under-reaction. (Fama 1998)
3
The Goal
• What do we need for a convincing behavioral theory?
• Fama (1998):
The alternative has a daunting task. It must spec-
ify what it is about investor psychology that causes
simultaneous under-reaction to some types of events
and over-reaction to others. The alternative must
also explain the range of observed results better
than the simple market efficiency story; that is,
[that] the expected value of abnormal returns is
zero, but chance generates deviations from zero
(anomalies) in both directions.
• Also, to answer Fama and others, we need to
– establish that there are consistent patterns in the data
– develop as-yet untested implications of the theory.
4
The Evidence Against Market Efficiency
Why not stick with efficient markets?
• These anomalies are sufficiently strong and regular that they
cause one to seriously question the efficient-markets paradigm:
– High Sharpe ratios are achievable with size, value, mo-
mentum and market timing strategies
(MacKinlay 1995, Campbell and Cochrane 1999).
– Apparent lack of correlation between returns of these strate-
gies and investors’ marginal utilities
(Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny 1994).
– Out-of-sample (in time and location) have strongly es-
tablished these as regularities. (Davis, Fama, and French
2000, Fama and French 1998)
• Theories have analyzed why a small group of “optimizing,”
investors may not eliminate these patterns.
– But, we have not established what sort of behavioral bi-
ases might be at the root of these patterns
5
The Goals of This Paper
Based on this we have two goals in this paper:
• Catalog regularities among the empirical anomalies.
• Develop a behavioral model that:
– is based upon plausible micro-foundations.
– is parsimonious
– has implications consistent with the empirical regular-
ities.
– has as-yet untested empirical implications.
6
Regularities: Return Autocorrelations
• Return auto-correlations & covariances, empirically, look like:
1 2 33’
Favorable Private Signal
Unfavorable Private Signal
Price
Time
• Positive short-lag return autocorrelations (‘mo-
mentum’):
– Cross-Sectional: Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)
– Aggregate: Lo and MacKinlay (1988).
• Negative long-lag autocorrelations (long-run ‘over-
reaction’):
– Cross-Sectional: DeBondt and Thaler (1985, 1987), Chopra,
Lakonishok, and Ritter (1992)
– Aggregate: Fama and French (1988b), Poterba and Sum-
mers (1988); also Kim, Nelson, and Startz (1988), Daniel
(2001)
7
• implying an impulse-response function of the form:
1 2 33’
Favorable Private Signal
Unfavorable Private Signal
Full Information Value
Full Information Value
• This is consistent with the evidence presented in Jegadeesh
and Titman (2001).
8
Regularities: Underreaction to Public News
Public-event-date average security returns are typically of the
same sign as subsequent average long-run abnormal performance
(‘underreaction’)
• Seasoned Offerings: Loughran and Ritter (1995) and
Spiess and Affleck-Graves (1995); see, however, Brav and
Gompers (1997).
• Repurchase Announcements: Ikenberry, Lakonishok,
and Vermaelen (1995).
• Insider Trading: Seyhun (1986), Seyhun (1988). Rozeff
and Zaman (1988). Public trading strategy does not beat
bid-ask and transactions costs.
• Analysts’ Buy and Sell Recommendations: Wom-
ack (1996), Michaely and Womack (1999), Desai and Jain
(1995).
• Stock Splits: Grinblatt, Masulis, and Titman (1984),
Desai and Jain (1997).
• Dividend Initiations and Omissions: Michaely,
Thaler, and Womack (1995).
• Merger Announcements: Agrawal, Jaffe, and Mandelker
(1992), Agrawal, Jaffe, and Mandelker (1996), and Rau and
Vermaelen (1998).
• Venture Capital Distributions: Gompers and Lerner
(1998)
9
Regularities: Earnings/Return Correlations
• Short Horizon – Earnings surprises are positively correlated
with future returns
– Earnings Announcements: Bernard and Thomas
(1989, 1990), Brown and Pope (1996)
– Earnings Forecasts: Abarbanell and Bernard (1991,
1992), Mendenhall (1991).
• Long Horizon – High past growth negatively correlated with
future long horizon return.
– Past Accounting Growth Rates: Lakonishok, Shleifer,
and Vishny (1994)
10
Regularities: Price-Scaled Variables
Price-Scaled Variables are postively correlated with future re-
turns:
• Cross-Sectionally:
– E/P Ratio: Basu (1983), Jaffe, Keim, and Westerfield
(1989),
– B/P Ratio: Graham and Dodd (1934), Stattman (1980),
Rosenberg, Reid, and Lanstein (1985), DeBondt and Thaler
(1987), Fama and French (1992);
• Aggregate:
– D/P Ratio: Dow (1920), Ball (1978), Campbell and
Shiller (1988) and Fama and French (1988a)
– E/P Ratio: Fama and French (1988a)
– B/P Ratio: Kothari and Shanken (1997)
11
Behavioral Basis for the Model
• We retain expected utility theory; all investors are Bayesian
• However, informed investors
1. are overconfident about the value/precision of their pri-
vate information, and
2. update their estimate of the precision of their private in-
formation in a biased fashion (Self-Attribution Bias).
– Confidence rises more when trades are confirmed than
it falls when beliefs are disconfirmed.
• We make no assumptions about whether investors under- or
over-react, follow trends, etc.
– all of these effects are an implication of overconfi-
dence, rather than an assumption of the model
12
Evidence of Overconfidence
13
Evidence of Overconfidence
“...perhaps the most robust finding in the psychology of
judgement is that people are overconfident.”
—DeBondt/Thaler (1995)
Overconfidence of Professionals in their Judgments:
• Psychologists: Oskamp (1965)
• Physicians
& Nurses:
Christensen-Szalanski and Bushyhead
(1981), Baumann, Deber, and Thompson
(1991)
• Engineers: Kidd (1970)
• Attorneys: Wagenaar and Keren (1986)
• Negotiators: Neale and Bazerman (1990)
• Entrepeneurs: Cooper, Woo, and Dunkelberg (1988)
• Managers: Russo and Schoemaker (1992)
• Investment
Bankers:
Stael von Holstein (1972)
• Security Analysts
& Economic
Forecasters:
Ahlers and Lakonishok (1983), Elton,
Gruber, and Gultekin (1984), Froot and
Frankel (1989), DeBondt and Thaler
(1990), DeBondt (1991).
14
Evidence of Overconfidence
“...perhaps the most robust finding in the psychology of
judgment is that people are overconfident.”
-DeBondt/Thaler (1995)
• There is pervasive evidence of the overconfidence of profes-
sionals in their judgments
• People perceive themselves as:
– More able than they actually are.
– More able than average.
– More favorably than they are viewed by others.
• Individuals underestimate their prediction error variance in
experimental settings:
• In our model, investors are overconfident in their ability to
generate generate private information
– Gathering new private information through interviews with
firm management, etc.,
– Processing publicly available information
– Note that we do not specify how investors process infor-
mation, just that they are overconfident about the results
of this processing!
• In our model, informed agents’ overconfidence is manifested
in their overestimation of the precision of their information.
15
Self-Attribution Bias
• Individuals do not know their ability/precision; they must
estimate it.
• Behavioral evidence suggests that agents update estimates of
their precision in a biased fashion:
– People discount unfavorable information and magnify fa-
vorable information in updating beliefs about their own
abilities.
• Fischoff (1982), Langer and Roth (1975), Miller and Ross
(1975), Taylor and Brown (1988).
• Consistent with evidence of cognitive dissonance.
• In our model, their estimate of the precision (1/σ2
) of their
signals increases more with confirming information than it
decreases with dis-confirming information.
16
The Overconfidence Model
• “Idealized” setting is a continuum of risk-averse agents, some
of which receive information and are overconfident about it.
– For tractability, we have two continuous masses of agents:
1. Risk neutral overconfident informed traders (I’s)
2. Risk averse fully rational uninformed traders (U’s),
with exponential utility.
– This should yield the same qualitative results as the ide-
alized setting.
∗ In Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (2001), we
explore the ramifications of making both agents risk-
averse, and of having a full set of risky assets.
• Further, we assume that all informed receive the same signal.
s1 = θ +
where θ is the true firm value.
– The same qualitative results would obtain with a contin-
uum of ex-ante identical individuals who receive and are
overconfident about information signals of the form
s1,i = θ + + δi,
where δi is independent across risk averse individuals.
• We have two versions of the model
– a simplified static confidence version
– a full dynamic confidence version
17
The Static Overconfidence Model
Four dates:
0 1 2 3time
Private Signal Public Signal Realization
θ ∼ N(¯θ, σ2
θ) s1 = θ + s2 = θ + η. θ
1. Date 0: identical prior beliefs, equilibrium allocations.
2. Date 1: I’s receive a common noisy private signal about un-
derlying security value and trade with U’s.
• I’s underestimate σ2
(as σ2
C < σ2
)
3. Date 2: Noisy public signal arrives, re-trade.
4. Date 3: Conclusive public information arrives, liquidate, con-
sume.
• Because σ2
C is too small, stock prices:
– overreact to private information arrival
– underreact to public information arrival.
• Expected future price movement is proportional to −E[ ]
18
The Full (Dynamic) Confidence Model
time
Private Signal Public Signal Public Signal Public Signal
1 2 3 4
sI φ2 φ3 φ4
...
0
• Again, there is a single private signal at time 1
˜sI = ˜θ + ˜ ˜ ∼ N(0, σ2
)
• Now, at date 2 through T, a public signal ˜φt is released
˜φt = ˜θ + ˜ηt
where
– ˜ηt ∼ i.i.d. N(0, σ2
η).
– σ2
η is common knowledge.
• Φt is the average of all public signals through time t
Φt =
1
(t − 1)
t
τ=2
˜φτ
– Φt is a sufficient statistic for the set of all past φ’s
• The ad hoc variance updating rule I’s use is;
– If sign(sI − Φt−1) = sign(φt − Φt−1)
and |sI − Φt−1| < 2σΦ,t then vC,t = (1 + k)vC,t−1
– Otherwise vC,t = (1 − k)vC,t−1
• (1 + k)/(1 − k) is an index of the investor’s attribution bias
19
Equilibrium
• At each date, all individuals maximize expected utility as a
function of terminal wealth with respect to their beliefs.
• Prices are set such that the aggregate demands for the risky
and numeraire securities at each date equal aggregate supply.
• At each date individuals can trade at the market price to
modify their bundles of risky and numeraire securities.
• Individuals make decisions at each date based on their avail-
able information, including the market price, and I’s overcon-
fident beliefs about precision.
• It is common knowledge that I’s believe with certainty that
the noise variance of s1 is σ2
C and that U’s believe with cer-
tainty it is less than σ2
C.
20
Model Implications
• We determine the implications of the overconfidence model
for the documented equity-market anomalies:
1. Return Autocorrelations
2. Price-Scaled Variables
3. Event studies
– Selective and Non-selective events
4. Earnings/returns correlations at varying horizons
21
Model Implications: Return
Autocorrelations
• The response of prices to private information:
1 2 33’
Favorable Private Signal
Unfavorable Private Signal
Price
Time
• There are distinct Overreaction and Correction Phases.
• Overreaction occurs because of overconfidence in the initial
signal.
• Continuing overreaction occurs because arrival of public in-
formation on average causes the confidence of the informed
to grow.
– Thus, our theory suggests that the apparent short-term
underreaction suggested by momentum can be a result
of continuing overreaction.
∗ See Jegadeesh and Titman (2001).
– Price, on average, is pushed even further in the direction
of trader’s initial private information.
• In the correction phase price converges to the true value of
the security.
22
Price Movements with Static Confidence
• With just overconfidence, and no self-attribution bias, the
price response to a positive private signal is:
0 20 40 60 80 100 120
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
0.35
0.4
0.45
0.5
period
Av.Price
• This plot assumes a constant information arrival rate, expo-
nential decay.
• With this AR(1) price impulse response function , returns
are ARMA(1, 1), and autocorrelations are proportional to
−(1 − φ)φτ
, where φ is the rate of decay in the price plot
above.
• Negative autocorrelations at all lags and all horizons.
• Thus, static overconfidence is consistent with long-run rever-
sals, but not with short-run momentum.
23
Equilibrium of the Dynamic Model
• In equilibrium, the security price is:
˜Pt = EC[˜θ|sI, Φt].
– For tractability, we assume that at each t, I revalues the
security using Bayesian updating as if he knew the preci-
sion of his signal to be σC,t with certainty.
• Hard to solve analytically, so we simulate this.
• We perform 50,000 iterations, each time drawing ˜θ, ˜sI and
the set of φt’s from appropriate distributions.
• The simulation parameters for the results presented here are:
k = 0.75 k = 0.1
σ2
θ = 1 σ2
= 1
σ2
η = 7.5 T = 120
σ2
C,1 = 1
• Model not calibrated.
24
Simulation Results
• The (price) impulse response function for sI = 1
with Attribution Bias
without Attribution Bias
0 20 40 60 80 100 120
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
period
AveragePrice
• The price-change autocorrelogram for full simulation is:
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110
0.02
0
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.1
lag
Autocorrelation
• This is consistent with the empirical evidence.
25
• The Long-Horizon Regression Coefficient for a regression of
price changes on price changes:
R(t, t + τ) = α + βR(t − τ, t) +
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
−1
−0.8
−0.6
−0.4
−0.2
0
0.2
0.4
horizon
correlation
26
Model Implications: Event Studies
• Basic implication of overconfidence model is (1) Overreaction
to Private Information, and (2) Underreaction to Public.
• The model does imply that a security’s return on a public-
information release date is negatively correlated with the fu-
ture return.
• However, counter-intuitively, the static confidence model does
not imply that the correlation of the future return with the
public signal is itself negative.
– Static Confidence Model ⇒ cov(P3 − P2, s2) = 0
• Intuition:
– Assume σθ = σ1 = σ2
Prior s1 s2
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0 0
-1 -1
-2 -2
• Suppose s2 = 2, then E[θ|s2] = 1, S1 = 0 or 2 equally likely.
• Bias equally likely to be up or down.
• Even though underreaction, knowing s2 does not help predict
sign of future returns.
27
• If event is selective (based on mispricing or E[ |P1, s2]), it
will forecast future returns.
• Model is consistent with:
Dividend Initiations
Splits
SEO’s (IPO’s)
Repurchases
Div. Omissions
Event-Date
28
Implications: Selective Events
• Suppose managers act to correct pricing errors:
– issue shares when stock overvalued
– repurchase when stock undervalued
– signal (split, dividend increase, forecast earnings favor-
ably, boost accruals or cash flows) when undervalued
• However, market revalues stubbornly ⇒
– average abnormal post-event return has same sign as event-
date reaction.
• Consistent with any prior runup or rundown
• Informed outsider may also exploit misvaluations:
– Analyst buy/sell recommendations
– Toehold purchases, takeover bids?
• Implications:
– For good news events, the post-event abnormal re-
turns will be larger when B/M high or pre-event perfor-
mance poor (more negative initial valuation error).
∗ Ikenberry, Lakonishok, and Vermaelen (1995): B/M
and repurchase
– For bad news events, the post-event abnormal returns
more negative when B/M low or pre-event performance
good (more positive initial valuation error).
∗ Ikenberry, Rankine, and Stice (1996): prior perfor-
mance and splits
29
Implications: Earnings Growth and Future
Returns
• Many PEAD studies use non-selective measures – We need
full dynamic model to account for this reaction.
• In simulation, we define a public-information/“earnings” change
as:
∆et = ˜φt − Φt−1 = ˜φt − E[˜φt|φs, s = 2, . . . , t − 1]
• ∆et is therefore the deviation of φt from its expected value
based on all past public signals.
• Simulation: average correlation between information changes
and future prices changes looks like:
20 40 60 80 100 120
−3
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
x 10
−3
lag
Cross−correlation
• Broadly consistent with both post-earnings announcement
drift, and long-run post-earnings reversals.
– Magnitude of the effects depends on the intensity of the
attribution bias relative to the variance of the public sig-
nals.
30
Implications: Price Scaled Variables
• High price-scaled measures of fundamentals (e.g., E/P, D/P,
B/M, 1/M) imply high future returns.
• Favorable private signal ⇒ M ↑, B/M ↓.
– Overreaction ⇒ long run M ↓
• Adverse private signal ⇒ M ↓, B/M ↑.
– Overreaction ⇒ long run M ↑
• Therefore, high B/M ⇒ high long run future returns.
• Aggregate price-scaled measures will forecast future market
returns
– if overconfidence about economy-wide information.
• Price-scaled measures will forecast cross sectional patterns
– if overconfidence about firm-specific information.
• Price-scaled variables can dominate standard risk-measures if
investors are sufficiently overconfident.
• Standard fundamental ratio anomalies support overreaction
theories, refute underreaction theories.
31
Implications: Managerial Actions
• Raise capital when fundamental ratios are low (stock overval-
ued)
• Issue shares after firm’s stock price has recently increased
(consistent with Lucas and McDonald (1990).)
• If overconfidence about common factors, issue after firm’s in-
dustry or stock market has risen or B/M low
(consistent with IPO evidence of Pagano, Panetta, and Zin-
gales (1998)).
• When book/market low, favor public over rights issues.
• When book/market low, favor equity over debt issues.
• When book/market low or after firm’s stock has risen, favor
repurchase over dividend.
Should managers disclose as much as possible prior to issuance?
• Can exploit overconfidence by not disclosing.
• But sometimes public disclosure can intensify an overreaction.
32
Relation to Existing Theories
Overconfidence:
• Kyle and Wang (1997): being overconfident as a commitment
to trade aggressively.
• Wang (1998): Overconfidence → info-based trading without
noise traders.
• Odean (1998): Overconfidence with private but not a public
signal, determinants of volatility, volume, and market depth.
Overconfidence increases volatility, overreaction to private
signals,
• Caball´e and S´akovics (1996): Beliefs about beliefs about...
• Benos (1996): Kyle (1985) model with overconfidence.
Positive Feedback Strategies
• DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990): Security
autocorrelation patterns based on mechanistic positive feed-
back investment strategies.
Berk (1995): Recognizes that market value reflects discounting of
risk.
33
Noise Trader Approach
• Prices are moved by trading that seems unrelated to the ar-
rival of information.
• Also important: investor mistakes involving misinterpretation
of genuine new information.
• Noise traders can be viewed as overconfident traders taking
the limit, holding constant the individual’s perceived preci-
sion, as his signal becomes very noisy.
Do overconfident traders go broke?
• Not if overconfidence helps them intimidate others, or encour-
ages high-return risks.
34
Further Empirical Implications
• Firms should prefer debt over equity when B/M is high or
following stock-price rundown.
• Firms should prefer repurchases over dividends when B/M is
low.
• Positive correlation between initial event reaction and post-
event performance.
• Less under-reaction to non-selective corporate events.
• Positive abnormal returns after toehold disclosures
• Post-event performance better for good-news events when
B/M high or pre-event performance poor.
• Post-event performance worse for bad news events when B/M
low or pre-event performance good.
35
Other Comments on Overconfidence
The over-weening conceit which the greater part of men have of
their own abilities, is an ancient evil remarked by the philosophers
and moralists of all ages.
...
The distant prospect of hazards, from which we can hope to ex-
tricate ourselves by courage and address, is not disagreeable to
us, and does not raise the wages of labour in any employment.
—The Wealth of Nations, p. 107, 110
• Smith: overconconfidence affects market prices in enterprises
where outcome depends on ability.
• Does the ‘overweening conceit’ of mankind affect stock market
prices?
36
Conclusions
• Approach to anomalies:
– Parsimonious
– Based on strong psychological evidence
– Explains wide range of phenomena plus new evidence
• Possible further avenues:
– Empirical testing
– Institutions versus individuals
37
References
Abarbanell, Jeffery S., 1991, Do analysts’ earnings forecasts incorporate information in
prior stock price changes?, Journal of Accounting and Economics 14, 147–165.
, and Victor Bernard, 1992, Analysts’ overreaction / underreaction to earnings
information as an explanation for anomalous stock price behavior, Journal of Finance
47, 1181–1207.
Agrawal, Anup, Jeffery F. Jaffe, and Gershon Mandelker, 1992, The post-merger per-
formance of acquiring firms in acquisitions: A re-examination of an anomaly, Journal
of Finance 47, 1605–1621.
, 1996, The pre-acquisition performance of target firms: A re-examination of the
inefficient management hypothesis, Working paper, Wharton School.
Ahlers, David, and Josef Lakonishok, 1983, A study of economists’ consensus forecasts,
Management Science 29, 1113–1125.
Ball, Ray, 1978, Anomalies in relationships between securities’ yields and yield-
surrogates, Journal of Financial Economics 6, 103–126.
Basu, S., 1983, The relationship between earnings yield, market value, and return for
NYSE common stocks: Further evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 12, 126–
156.
Baumann, Andrea O., Raisa B. Deber, and Gail G. Thompson, 1991, Overconfidence
among physicians and nurses: The micro-certainty, macro-uncertainty phenomenon,
Social Science & Medicine 32, 167–174.
Berk, Jonathan, 1995, A critique of size related anomalies, Review of Financial Studies
8, 275–286.
Bernard, Victor L., and Jacob K. Thomas, 1989, Post-earnings-announcement drift:
Delayed price response or risk premium?, Journal of Accounting Research, Supplement
27, 1–48.
, 1990, Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current
earnings for future earnings, Journal of Accounting and Economics 13, 305–340.
Brav, Alon, and Paul A. Gompers, 1997, Myth or reality? The long-run underperfor-
mance of initial public offerings: Evidence from venture and nonventure capital-backed
companies, Journal of Finance 52, 1791–1821.
Brown, Steven J., and Peter F. Pope, 1996, Post-earnings announcement drift?, Working
Paper, New York University.
Caball´e, Jordi, and J´ozsef S´akovics, 1996, Overconfident speculation with imperfect
competition, Working Paper,Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona.
38
Campbell, John Y., and John H. Cochrane, 1999, By force of habit: A consumption-
based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior, Journal of Political Economy
107, 205–251.
Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller, 1988, The dividend-price ratio and expecta-
tions of future dividends and discount factors, Review of Financial Studies 1, 195–228.
Chopra, Navin, Josef Lakonishok, and Jay R. Ritter, 1992, Measuring abnormal perfor-
mance: Do stocks overreact?, Journal of Financial Economics 31, 235–268.
Christensen-Szalanski, Jay J., and James B. Bushyhead, 1981, Physicians’ use of prob-
abilistic information in a real clinical setting, Journal of Experimental Psychology:
Human Perception and Performance 7, 928–935.
Cooper, Arnold C., Carolyn W. Woo, and William C. Dunkelberg, 1988, Entrepeneurs’
perceived chances for success, Journal of Business Venturing 3, 97–108.
Daniel, Kent D., 2001, The power and size of mean reversion tests, Journal of Empirical
Finance 8, 493–535.
, David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 2001, Overconfidence, arbi-
trage, and equilibrium asset pricing, Journal of Finance 56, 921–965.
Davis, James, Eugene F. Fama, and Kenneth R. French, 2000, Characteristics, covari-
ances, and average returns: 1929-1997, Journal of Finance 55, 389–406.
DeBondt, Werner F. M., 1991, What do economists know about the stock market?,
Journal of Portfolio Management 17, 84–91.
, and Richard H. Thaler, 1985, Does the stock market overreact?, Journal of
Finance 40, 793–808.
, 1987, Further evidence on investor overreaction and stock market seasonality,
Journal of Finance 42, 557–581.
, 1990, Do security analysts overreact?, American Economic Review 80, 52–57.
DeLong, J. Bradford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence Summers, and Robert J. Waldmann,
1990, Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation,
Journal of Finance 45, 375–395.
Desai, Hemang, and Prem C. Jain, 1995, An analysis of the recommendations of the
‘superstar’ money managers at Barron’s annual roundtable, Journal of Finance 50,
1257–1274.
, 1997, Long-run common stock returns following stock splits and reverse splits,
Journal of Business 70, 409–434.
Dow, Charles Henry, 1920, Scientific Stock Speculation (Magazine of Wall Street: New
York).
39
Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber, and Mustafa N. Gultekin, 1984, Professional ex-
pectations: Accuracy and diagnosis of errors, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 19, 351–363.
Fama, Eugene F., 1998, Market efficiency, long-term returns and behavioral finance,
Journal of Financial Economics 49, 283–306.
, and Kenneth R. French, 1988a, Dividend yields and expected stock returns,
Journal of Financial Economics 22, 3–25.
, 1988b, Permanent and temporary components of stock prices, Journal of Po-
litical Economy 96, 246–273.
, 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns, Journal of Finance 47, 427–
465.
, 1998, Value versus growth: The international evidence, Journal of Finance 53,
1975–1999.
Fischoff, Baruch, 1982, For those condemned to study the past: Heuristics and biases
in hindsight, in Daniel Kahneman, Paul Slovic, and Amos Tversky, ed.: Judgement
under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases (Cambridge University Press: Cambridge).
Froot, Kenneth, and Jeffery A. Frankel, 1989, Forward discount bias: Is it an exchange
risk premium?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 139–161.
Gompers, Paul, and Josh Lerner, 1998, Venture capital distributions: Short-run and
long-run reactions, Journal of Finance.
Graham, Benjamin, and D. Dodd, 1934, Security Analysis (McGraw Hill: New York,
N.Y.).
Grinblatt, Mark, Ronald W. Masulis, and Sheridan Titman, 1984, The valuation effects
of stock splits and stock dividends, Journal of Financial Economics 13, 97–112.
Ikenberry, David, Josef Lakonishok, and Theo Vermaelen, 1995, Market underreaction
to open market share repurchases, Journal of Financial Economics 39, 181–208.
Ikenberry, David, Graeme Rankine, and Earl K. Stice, 1996, What do stock splits really
signal?, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 357–375.
Jaffe, Jeffrey, Donald B. Keim, and Randolph Westerfield, 1989, Earnings yields, market
values, and stock returns, Journal of Finance 44, 135–148.
Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 1993, Returns to buying winners and
selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency, Journal of Finance 48, 65–91.
, 2001, Profitability of momentum strategies: An evaluation of alternative ex-
planations, Journal of Finance 56, 699–720.
Kidd, John B., 1970, The utilization of subjective probabilities in production planning,
Acta Psychologica 34, 338–347.
40
Kim, Myung-Jig, Charles R. Nelson, and Richard Startz, 1988, Mean reversion in stock
prices? A reappraisal of the empirical evidence, Review of Economic Studies 58,
551–528.
Kothari, S.P., and Jay Shanken, 1997, Book-to-market, dividend yield, and expected
market returns: A time-series analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 44, 169–203.
Kyle, Albert, and F. Albert Wang, 1997, Speculation duopoly with agreement to dis-
agree: Can overconfidence survive the market test?, Journal of Finance 52, 2073–2090.
Lakonishok, Josef, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1994, Contrarian investment,
extrapolation and risk, Journal of Finance 49, 1541–1578.
Langer, Ellen J., and Jane Roth, 1975, Heads I win tails it’s chance: The illusion of
control as a function of the sequence of outcomes in a purely chance task, Journal of
Personality and Social Psychology 32, 951–955.
Lo, Andrew W., and A. Craig MacKinlay, 1988, Stock market prices do not follow
random walks: Evidence from a simple specification test, Review of Financial Studies
1, 41–46.
Loughran, Tim, and Jay R. Ritter, 1995, The new issues puzzle, The Journal of Finance
50, 23–52.
Lucas, Deborah J., and Robert L. McDonald, 1990, Equity issues and stock price dy-
namics, Journal of Finance 45, 1019–1043.
MacKinlay, A. Craig, 1995, Multifactor models do not explain deviations from the
CAPM, Journal of Financial Economics 38, 3–28.
Mendenhall, Richard, 1991, Evidence of possible underweighting of earnings-related in-
formation, Journal of Accounting Research 29, 170–180.
Michaely, Roni, Richard H. Thaler, and Kent L. Womack, 1995, Price reactions to
dividend initiations and omissions: Overreaction or drift?, Journal of Finance 50,
573–608.
Michaely, Roni, and Kent Womack, 1999, Conflict of interest and the credibility of
underwriter analyst recommendations, Review of Financial Studies 12, 573–608.
Miller, Dale T., and Michael Ross, 1975, Self-serving bias in attribution of causality:
Fact or fiction?, Psychological Bulletin 82, 213–225.
Neale, Margaret, and Max Bazerman, 1990, Cognition and Rationality in Negotiation
(The Free Press: New York).
Odean, Terrance, 1998, Volume, volatility, price and profit when all traders are above
average, Journal of Finance 53, 1887–1934.
Oskamp, Stuart, 1965, Overconfidence in case study judgements, Journal of Consulting
Psychology 29, 261–265.
41
Pagano, Marco, Fabio Panetta, and Luigi Zingales, 1998, Why do companies go public?
an empirical analysis, Journal of Finance 53, 27–64.
Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers, 1988, Mean reversion in stock returns:
Evidence and implications, Journal of Financial Economics 22, 27–59.
Rau, Raghavendra P., and Theo Vermaelen, 1998, Glamour, value and the post-
acquisition performance of acquiring firms, Journal of Financial Economics 49.
Rosenberg, Barr, Kenneth Reid, and Ronald Lanstein, 1985, Persuasive evidence of
market inefficiency, Journal of Portfolio Management 11, 9–17.
Rozeff, Michael S., and Mir A. Zaman, 1988, Market efficiency and insider trading: New
evidence, Journal of Business 61, 25–44.
Russo, J. Edward, and Paul J. H. Schoemaker, 1992, Managing overconfidence, Sloan
Management Review 33, 7–17.
Seyhun, H. Nejat, 1986, Insiders’ profits, costs of trading, and market efficiency, Journal
of Financial Economics 61, 189–212.
, 1988, The information content of aggregate insider trading, Journal of Business
61, 1–24.
Spiess, D. Katherine, and John Affleck-Graves, 1995, Underperformance in long-run
stock returns following seasoned equity offerings, Journal of Financial Economics 38,
243–268.
Stael von Holstein, C., 1972, Probabilistic forecasting: An experiment related to the
stock market, Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 8, 139–158.
Stattman, Dennis, 1980, Book values and stock returns, The Chicago MBA: A Journal
of Selected Papers 4, 25–45.
Taylor, Shelley E., and Jonathan D. Brown, 1988, Illusion and well-being: A social
psychological perspective on mental health, Psychological Bulletin 103, 193–210.
Wagenaar, Willem, and Gideoan Keren, 1986, Does the expert know? The reliability of
predictions and confidence ratios of experts, in Erik Hollnagel, Giuseppe Mancini, and
David D. Woods, ed.: Intelligent Decision Support in Process Environment (Springer:
Berlin).
Wang, F. Albert, 1998, Strategic trading, asymmetric information and heterogeneous
prior beliefs, Journal of Financial Markets 1, 321–352.
Womack, Kent L., 1996, Do brokerage analysts’ recommendations have investment
value?, Journal of Finance 51, 137–168.
42

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Was ist angesagt?

Behavioral finance -_an_explanation
Behavioral finance -_an_explanationBehavioral finance -_an_explanation
Behavioral finance -_an_explanation
smritipattnaik
 
Understanding how the mind can help or hinder investment success
Understanding how the mind can help or hinder investment successUnderstanding how the mind can help or hinder investment success
Understanding how the mind can help or hinder investment success
Ravi Abeysuriya
 
Unit 1 behavioural finance to send
Unit 1 behavioural finance to sendUnit 1 behavioural finance to send
Unit 1 behavioural finance to send
Keshav Sharma
 
Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...
Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...
Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...
Rohit Singh
 

Was ist angesagt? (20)

Behavioral finance summary
Behavioral finance summaryBehavioral finance summary
Behavioral finance summary
 
Behavioral finance and investment decision
Behavioral finance and investment decisionBehavioral finance and investment decision
Behavioral finance and investment decision
 
behavioral finance intro
behavioral finance introbehavioral finance intro
behavioral finance intro
 
Behavioral Finance
Behavioral FinanceBehavioral Finance
Behavioral Finance
 
Behavioral finance
Behavioral financeBehavioral finance
Behavioral finance
 
Behavioral finance -_an_explanation
Behavioral finance -_an_explanationBehavioral finance -_an_explanation
Behavioral finance -_an_explanation
 
Behavioural Finance Final Ppt
Behavioural Finance Final PptBehavioural Finance Final Ppt
Behavioural Finance Final Ppt
 
Behavioral Finance
Behavioral FinanceBehavioral Finance
Behavioral Finance
 
Understanding behavioural finance
Understanding behavioural financeUnderstanding behavioural finance
Understanding behavioural finance
 
Behavioral finance
Behavioral financeBehavioral finance
Behavioral finance
 
Behavioral Finance
Behavioral FinanceBehavioral Finance
Behavioral Finance
 
Understanding how the mind can help or hinder investment success
Understanding how the mind can help or hinder investment successUnderstanding how the mind can help or hinder investment success
Understanding how the mind can help or hinder investment success
 
BEHAVIOR FINANCE
BEHAVIOR FINANCEBEHAVIOR FINANCE
BEHAVIOR FINANCE
 
Unit 1 behavioural finance to send
Unit 1 behavioural finance to sendUnit 1 behavioural finance to send
Unit 1 behavioural finance to send
 
Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...
Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...
Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, Regret Aversion & Sel...
 
Behavioural Finance - An Introspection Of Investor Psychology
Behavioural Finance - An Introspection Of Investor PsychologyBehavioural Finance - An Introspection Of Investor Psychology
Behavioural Finance - An Introspection Of Investor Psychology
 
Behavioral financing
Behavioral financingBehavioral financing
Behavioral financing
 
Behavioural corporate finance
Behavioural corporate financeBehavioural corporate finance
Behavioural corporate finance
 
Behavioral Finance
Behavioral Finance Behavioral Finance
Behavioral Finance
 
Impact of Behavioral Biases on Investor's Decision
Impact of Behavioral Biases on Investor's DecisionImpact of Behavioral Biases on Investor's Decision
Impact of Behavioral Biases on Investor's Decision
 

Ähnlich wie Investor psychology and security market under and overreactions, Presentation Slides

momentum slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptx
momentum  slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptxmomentum  slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptx
momentum slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptx
HafizArslan19
 
Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx
 Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx
Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx
ShiraPrater50
 
2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf
2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf
2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf
SwapanRoy16
 
Investor Behavior - Actuarial Research Foundation
Investor Behavior - Actuarial Research FoundationInvestor Behavior - Actuarial Research Foundation
Investor Behavior - Actuarial Research Foundation
Nino Boezio
 
Wang market confidence and momentum
Wang   market confidence and momentumWang   market confidence and momentum
Wang market confidence and momentum
23tino
 
Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26
Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26
Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26
Stephen Ryan
 

Ähnlich wie Investor psychology and security market under and overreactions, Presentation Slides (20)

momentum slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptx
momentum  slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptxmomentum  slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptx
momentum slides U30273_20c92135bbb8667c4e22bc062da68dde.pptx
 
Limited Attention, Information Disclosure, and Financial Reporting
Limited Attention, Information Disclosure, and Financial ReportingLimited Attention, Information Disclosure, and Financial Reporting
Limited Attention, Information Disclosure, and Financial Reporting
 
Fama98.pdf
Fama98.pdfFama98.pdf
Fama98.pdf
 
The X Factor
The X FactorThe X Factor
The X Factor
 
Christopher Gilbert: Financialization and Agricultural Futures Markets
Christopher Gilbert: Financialization and Agricultural Futures MarketsChristopher Gilbert: Financialization and Agricultural Futures Markets
Christopher Gilbert: Financialization and Agricultural Futures Markets
 
Risk Model Methodologies
Risk Model MethodologiesRisk Model Methodologies
Risk Model Methodologies
 
Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx
 Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx
Corresponding author. Tel. 773 702 7282; fax 773 702 9937;.docx
 
Market behavior research @ bec doms
Market behavior research @ bec domsMarket behavior research @ bec doms
Market behavior research @ bec doms
 
Market behavior research @ bec doms
Market behavior research @ bec domsMarket behavior research @ bec doms
Market behavior research @ bec doms
 
Market behavior research @ bec doms
Market behavior research @ bec domsMarket behavior research @ bec doms
Market behavior research @ bec doms
 
2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf
2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf
2behavioralfinance-anoverview-161219191334 (1).pdf
 
Taking on Wall Street: A Comparative Study of Strategies Sourced from "The Pr...
Taking on Wall Street: A Comparative Study of Strategies Sourced from "The Pr...Taking on Wall Street: A Comparative Study of Strategies Sourced from "The Pr...
Taking on Wall Street: A Comparative Study of Strategies Sourced from "The Pr...
 
Application of ML / DL in Finance / Investment
Application of ML / DL in Finance / InvestmentApplication of ML / DL in Finance / Investment
Application of ML / DL in Finance / Investment
 
Application of ML / DL in Finance / Investment
Application of ML / DL in Finance / InvestmentApplication of ML / DL in Finance / Investment
Application of ML / DL in Finance / Investment
 
Behavioral finance summary
Behavioral finance summaryBehavioral finance summary
Behavioral finance summary
 
Investor psychology and asset pricing
Investor psychology and asset pricingInvestor psychology and asset pricing
Investor psychology and asset pricing
 
Investor Behavior - Actuarial Research Foundation
Investor Behavior - Actuarial Research FoundationInvestor Behavior - Actuarial Research Foundation
Investor Behavior - Actuarial Research Foundation
 
Wang market confidence and momentum
Wang   market confidence and momentumWang   market confidence and momentum
Wang market confidence and momentum
 
Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26
Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26
Has anyone seen my neo-cortex by S RYAN AND M RICHARDSON 2015 06 26
 
Can Individual Investors Beat the Market?
Can Individual Investors Beat the Market?Can Individual Investors Beat the Market?
Can Individual Investors Beat the Market?
 

Mehr von David Hirshleifer

Mehr von David Hirshleifer (8)

Are Investors Really Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? The Disposition Effec...
Are Investors Really Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? The Disposition Effec...Are Investors Really Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? The Disposition Effec...
Are Investors Really Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? The Disposition Effec...
 
Conversation, Observational Learning, and Informational Cascades
Conversation, Observational Learning, and Informational CascadesConversation, Observational Learning, and Informational Cascades
Conversation, Observational Learning, and Informational Cascades
 
Opportunism as a firm and managerial trait predicting insider trading profits...
Opportunism as a firm and managerial trait predicting insider trading profits...Opportunism as a firm and managerial trait predicting insider trading profits...
Opportunism as a firm and managerial trait predicting insider trading profits...
 
A theory of costly sequential bidding - Presentation Slides
A theory of costly sequential bidding - Presentation SlidesA theory of costly sequential bidding - Presentation Slides
A theory of costly sequential bidding - Presentation Slides
 
Are Overconfident CEOs Better Innovators?
Are Overconfident CEOs Better Innovators?Are Overconfident CEOs Better Innovators?
Are Overconfident CEOs Better Innovators?
 
Stock market overvaluation, moon shots,and corporate innovation
Stock market overvaluation, moon shots,and corporate innovationStock market overvaluation, moon shots,and corporate innovation
Stock market overvaluation, moon shots,and corporate innovation
 
Innovative efficiency and stock returns
Innovative efficiency and stock returnsInnovative efficiency and stock returns
Innovative efficiency and stock returns
 
Overvalued equity & financing decisions (presentation slides)
Overvalued equity & financing decisions (presentation slides)Overvalued equity & financing decisions (presentation slides)
Overvalued equity & financing decisions (presentation slides)
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen

VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...
VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...
VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
amitlee9823
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen (20)

Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
 
Solution Manual for Principles of Corporate Finance 14th Edition by Richard B...
Solution Manual for Principles of Corporate Finance 14th Edition by Richard B...Solution Manual for Principles of Corporate Finance 14th Edition by Richard B...
Solution Manual for Principles of Corporate Finance 14th Edition by Richard B...
 
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
Mira Road Awesome 100% Independent Call Girls NUmber-9833754194-Dahisar Inter...
 
(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
 
VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...
VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...
VIP Call Girl in Thane 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday With...
 
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
 
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
Vip Call US 📞 7738631006 ✅Call Girls In Sakinaka ( Mumbai )
 
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mumbai 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Lohegaon ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Se...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Lohegaon ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Se...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Lohegaon ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Se...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Lohegaon ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Se...
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Pashan ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Serv...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Pashan ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Serv...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Pashan ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Serv...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Pashan ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Serv...
 
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323 ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323  ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure serviceWhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323  ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323 ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
 
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
(Vedika) Low Rate Call Girls in Pune Call Now 8250077686 Pune Escorts 24x7
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Dighi ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex Servi...
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade  6297143586 Call Hot ...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Talegaon Dabhade 6297143586 Call Hot ...
 
TEST BANK For Corporate Finance, 13th Edition By Stephen Ross, Randolph Weste...
TEST BANK For Corporate Finance, 13th Edition By Stephen Ross, Randolph Weste...TEST BANK For Corporate Finance, 13th Edition By Stephen Ross, Randolph Weste...
TEST BANK For Corporate Finance, 13th Edition By Stephen Ross, Randolph Weste...
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
 
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...
Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...
Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...
 

Investor psychology and security market under and overreactions, Presentation Slides

  • 1. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3181607 Investor Psychology and Security Market Under- and Overreactions Journal of Finance, December 1998. Kent Daniel David Hirshleifer Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Fin 9310 – Behavioral Finance Seminar - April 4, 2018 -
  • 2. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3181607 Outline 1. Challenges to Behavioral Finance 2. This Paper’s Goals 3. Regularities in Anomalous Price Patterns 4. The Overconfidence Theory • Psychological Evidence on Overconfidence and on Biased Self-Attribution • Model Setup 5. Model Implications • Reaction to Public and Private Information • Event Study Implications • Price Scaled Variables – Aggregate and Cross-Sectional Forecastability • Short and Long Horizon Autocorrelations • Short and Long Horizon Correlations with Information Releases • Corporate Finance Implications 6. Relation to Existing Theories 7. Conclusion 2
  • 3. Challenges: Financial Market Anomalies • There is now evidence of strong return predictability • This evidence is largely responsible for the growth in interest in behavioral finance. • However, the over-reaction/under-reaction interpretations of- ten given to this evidence appear contradictory: [In the behavioral literature] ...[a]pparent anomalies are viewed one at a time, and the same authors, ex- amining different events, seem content with over-reaction or under-reaction, and willing to infer that both war- rant dropping market efficiency. (Fama 1998) • The apparent inconsistency makes the behavioral stories ap- pear no better than the market efficiency hypothesis: The market efficiency hypothesis, of course, offers a simple answer to this question – chance. Specifically, the expected value of abnormal returns is zero, but chance generates apparent anomalies that split ran- domly between apparent over-reaction and apparent under-reaction. (Fama 1998) 3
  • 4. The Goal • What do we need for a convincing behavioral theory? • Fama (1998): The alternative has a daunting task. It must spec- ify what it is about investor psychology that causes simultaneous under-reaction to some types of events and over-reaction to others. The alternative must also explain the range of observed results better than the simple market efficiency story; that is, [that] the expected value of abnormal returns is zero, but chance generates deviations from zero (anomalies) in both directions. • Also, to answer Fama and others, we need to – establish that there are consistent patterns in the data – develop as-yet untested implications of the theory. 4
  • 5. The Evidence Against Market Efficiency Why not stick with efficient markets? • These anomalies are sufficiently strong and regular that they cause one to seriously question the efficient-markets paradigm: – High Sharpe ratios are achievable with size, value, mo- mentum and market timing strategies (MacKinlay 1995, Campbell and Cochrane 1999). – Apparent lack of correlation between returns of these strate- gies and investors’ marginal utilities (Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny 1994). – Out-of-sample (in time and location) have strongly es- tablished these as regularities. (Davis, Fama, and French 2000, Fama and French 1998) • Theories have analyzed why a small group of “optimizing,” investors may not eliminate these patterns. – But, we have not established what sort of behavioral bi- ases might be at the root of these patterns 5
  • 6. The Goals of This Paper Based on this we have two goals in this paper: • Catalog regularities among the empirical anomalies. • Develop a behavioral model that: – is based upon plausible micro-foundations. – is parsimonious – has implications consistent with the empirical regular- ities. – has as-yet untested empirical implications. 6
  • 7. Regularities: Return Autocorrelations • Return auto-correlations & covariances, empirically, look like: 1 2 33’ Favorable Private Signal Unfavorable Private Signal Price Time • Positive short-lag return autocorrelations (‘mo- mentum’): – Cross-Sectional: Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) – Aggregate: Lo and MacKinlay (1988). • Negative long-lag autocorrelations (long-run ‘over- reaction’): – Cross-Sectional: DeBondt and Thaler (1985, 1987), Chopra, Lakonishok, and Ritter (1992) – Aggregate: Fama and French (1988b), Poterba and Sum- mers (1988); also Kim, Nelson, and Startz (1988), Daniel (2001) 7
  • 8. • implying an impulse-response function of the form: 1 2 33’ Favorable Private Signal Unfavorable Private Signal Full Information Value Full Information Value • This is consistent with the evidence presented in Jegadeesh and Titman (2001). 8
  • 9. Regularities: Underreaction to Public News Public-event-date average security returns are typically of the same sign as subsequent average long-run abnormal performance (‘underreaction’) • Seasoned Offerings: Loughran and Ritter (1995) and Spiess and Affleck-Graves (1995); see, however, Brav and Gompers (1997). • Repurchase Announcements: Ikenberry, Lakonishok, and Vermaelen (1995). • Insider Trading: Seyhun (1986), Seyhun (1988). Rozeff and Zaman (1988). Public trading strategy does not beat bid-ask and transactions costs. • Analysts’ Buy and Sell Recommendations: Wom- ack (1996), Michaely and Womack (1999), Desai and Jain (1995). • Stock Splits: Grinblatt, Masulis, and Titman (1984), Desai and Jain (1997). • Dividend Initiations and Omissions: Michaely, Thaler, and Womack (1995). • Merger Announcements: Agrawal, Jaffe, and Mandelker (1992), Agrawal, Jaffe, and Mandelker (1996), and Rau and Vermaelen (1998). • Venture Capital Distributions: Gompers and Lerner (1998) 9
  • 10. Regularities: Earnings/Return Correlations • Short Horizon – Earnings surprises are positively correlated with future returns – Earnings Announcements: Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990), Brown and Pope (1996) – Earnings Forecasts: Abarbanell and Bernard (1991, 1992), Mendenhall (1991). • Long Horizon – High past growth negatively correlated with future long horizon return. – Past Accounting Growth Rates: Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1994) 10
  • 11. Regularities: Price-Scaled Variables Price-Scaled Variables are postively correlated with future re- turns: • Cross-Sectionally: – E/P Ratio: Basu (1983), Jaffe, Keim, and Westerfield (1989), – B/P Ratio: Graham and Dodd (1934), Stattman (1980), Rosenberg, Reid, and Lanstein (1985), DeBondt and Thaler (1987), Fama and French (1992); • Aggregate: – D/P Ratio: Dow (1920), Ball (1978), Campbell and Shiller (1988) and Fama and French (1988a) – E/P Ratio: Fama and French (1988a) – B/P Ratio: Kothari and Shanken (1997) 11
  • 12. Behavioral Basis for the Model • We retain expected utility theory; all investors are Bayesian • However, informed investors 1. are overconfident about the value/precision of their pri- vate information, and 2. update their estimate of the precision of their private in- formation in a biased fashion (Self-Attribution Bias). – Confidence rises more when trades are confirmed than it falls when beliefs are disconfirmed. • We make no assumptions about whether investors under- or over-react, follow trends, etc. – all of these effects are an implication of overconfi- dence, rather than an assumption of the model 12
  • 14. Evidence of Overconfidence “...perhaps the most robust finding in the psychology of judgement is that people are overconfident.” —DeBondt/Thaler (1995) Overconfidence of Professionals in their Judgments: • Psychologists: Oskamp (1965) • Physicians & Nurses: Christensen-Szalanski and Bushyhead (1981), Baumann, Deber, and Thompson (1991) • Engineers: Kidd (1970) • Attorneys: Wagenaar and Keren (1986) • Negotiators: Neale and Bazerman (1990) • Entrepeneurs: Cooper, Woo, and Dunkelberg (1988) • Managers: Russo and Schoemaker (1992) • Investment Bankers: Stael von Holstein (1972) • Security Analysts & Economic Forecasters: Ahlers and Lakonishok (1983), Elton, Gruber, and Gultekin (1984), Froot and Frankel (1989), DeBondt and Thaler (1990), DeBondt (1991). 14
  • 15. Evidence of Overconfidence “...perhaps the most robust finding in the psychology of judgment is that people are overconfident.” -DeBondt/Thaler (1995) • There is pervasive evidence of the overconfidence of profes- sionals in their judgments • People perceive themselves as: – More able than they actually are. – More able than average. – More favorably than they are viewed by others. • Individuals underestimate their prediction error variance in experimental settings: • In our model, investors are overconfident in their ability to generate generate private information – Gathering new private information through interviews with firm management, etc., – Processing publicly available information – Note that we do not specify how investors process infor- mation, just that they are overconfident about the results of this processing! • In our model, informed agents’ overconfidence is manifested in their overestimation of the precision of their information. 15
  • 16. Self-Attribution Bias • Individuals do not know their ability/precision; they must estimate it. • Behavioral evidence suggests that agents update estimates of their precision in a biased fashion: – People discount unfavorable information and magnify fa- vorable information in updating beliefs about their own abilities. • Fischoff (1982), Langer and Roth (1975), Miller and Ross (1975), Taylor and Brown (1988). • Consistent with evidence of cognitive dissonance. • In our model, their estimate of the precision (1/σ2 ) of their signals increases more with confirming information than it decreases with dis-confirming information. 16
  • 17. The Overconfidence Model • “Idealized” setting is a continuum of risk-averse agents, some of which receive information and are overconfident about it. – For tractability, we have two continuous masses of agents: 1. Risk neutral overconfident informed traders (I’s) 2. Risk averse fully rational uninformed traders (U’s), with exponential utility. – This should yield the same qualitative results as the ide- alized setting. ∗ In Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (2001), we explore the ramifications of making both agents risk- averse, and of having a full set of risky assets. • Further, we assume that all informed receive the same signal. s1 = θ + where θ is the true firm value. – The same qualitative results would obtain with a contin- uum of ex-ante identical individuals who receive and are overconfident about information signals of the form s1,i = θ + + δi, where δi is independent across risk averse individuals. • We have two versions of the model – a simplified static confidence version – a full dynamic confidence version 17
  • 18. The Static Overconfidence Model Four dates: 0 1 2 3time Private Signal Public Signal Realization θ ∼ N(¯θ, σ2 θ) s1 = θ + s2 = θ + η. θ 1. Date 0: identical prior beliefs, equilibrium allocations. 2. Date 1: I’s receive a common noisy private signal about un- derlying security value and trade with U’s. • I’s underestimate σ2 (as σ2 C < σ2 ) 3. Date 2: Noisy public signal arrives, re-trade. 4. Date 3: Conclusive public information arrives, liquidate, con- sume. • Because σ2 C is too small, stock prices: – overreact to private information arrival – underreact to public information arrival. • Expected future price movement is proportional to −E[ ] 18
  • 19. The Full (Dynamic) Confidence Model time Private Signal Public Signal Public Signal Public Signal 1 2 3 4 sI φ2 φ3 φ4 ... 0 • Again, there is a single private signal at time 1 ˜sI = ˜θ + ˜ ˜ ∼ N(0, σ2 ) • Now, at date 2 through T, a public signal ˜φt is released ˜φt = ˜θ + ˜ηt where – ˜ηt ∼ i.i.d. N(0, σ2 η). – σ2 η is common knowledge. • Φt is the average of all public signals through time t Φt = 1 (t − 1) t τ=2 ˜φτ – Φt is a sufficient statistic for the set of all past φ’s • The ad hoc variance updating rule I’s use is; – If sign(sI − Φt−1) = sign(φt − Φt−1) and |sI − Φt−1| < 2σΦ,t then vC,t = (1 + k)vC,t−1 – Otherwise vC,t = (1 − k)vC,t−1 • (1 + k)/(1 − k) is an index of the investor’s attribution bias 19
  • 20. Equilibrium • At each date, all individuals maximize expected utility as a function of terminal wealth with respect to their beliefs. • Prices are set such that the aggregate demands for the risky and numeraire securities at each date equal aggregate supply. • At each date individuals can trade at the market price to modify their bundles of risky and numeraire securities. • Individuals make decisions at each date based on their avail- able information, including the market price, and I’s overcon- fident beliefs about precision. • It is common knowledge that I’s believe with certainty that the noise variance of s1 is σ2 C and that U’s believe with cer- tainty it is less than σ2 C. 20
  • 21. Model Implications • We determine the implications of the overconfidence model for the documented equity-market anomalies: 1. Return Autocorrelations 2. Price-Scaled Variables 3. Event studies – Selective and Non-selective events 4. Earnings/returns correlations at varying horizons 21
  • 22. Model Implications: Return Autocorrelations • The response of prices to private information: 1 2 33’ Favorable Private Signal Unfavorable Private Signal Price Time • There are distinct Overreaction and Correction Phases. • Overreaction occurs because of overconfidence in the initial signal. • Continuing overreaction occurs because arrival of public in- formation on average causes the confidence of the informed to grow. – Thus, our theory suggests that the apparent short-term underreaction suggested by momentum can be a result of continuing overreaction. ∗ See Jegadeesh and Titman (2001). – Price, on average, is pushed even further in the direction of trader’s initial private information. • In the correction phase price converges to the true value of the security. 22
  • 23. Price Movements with Static Confidence • With just overconfidence, and no self-attribution bias, the price response to a positive private signal is: 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 period Av.Price • This plot assumes a constant information arrival rate, expo- nential decay. • With this AR(1) price impulse response function , returns are ARMA(1, 1), and autocorrelations are proportional to −(1 − φ)φτ , where φ is the rate of decay in the price plot above. • Negative autocorrelations at all lags and all horizons. • Thus, static overconfidence is consistent with long-run rever- sals, but not with short-run momentum. 23
  • 24. Equilibrium of the Dynamic Model • In equilibrium, the security price is: ˜Pt = EC[˜θ|sI, Φt]. – For tractability, we assume that at each t, I revalues the security using Bayesian updating as if he knew the preci- sion of his signal to be σC,t with certainty. • Hard to solve analytically, so we simulate this. • We perform 50,000 iterations, each time drawing ˜θ, ˜sI and the set of φt’s from appropriate distributions. • The simulation parameters for the results presented here are: k = 0.75 k = 0.1 σ2 θ = 1 σ2 = 1 σ2 η = 7.5 T = 120 σ2 C,1 = 1 • Model not calibrated. 24
  • 25. Simulation Results • The (price) impulse response function for sI = 1 with Attribution Bias without Attribution Bias 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 period AveragePrice • The price-change autocorrelogram for full simulation is: 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 lag Autocorrelation • This is consistent with the empirical evidence. 25
  • 26. • The Long-Horizon Regression Coefficient for a regression of price changes on price changes: R(t, t + τ) = α + βR(t − τ, t) + 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 −1 −0.8 −0.6 −0.4 −0.2 0 0.2 0.4 horizon correlation 26
  • 27. Model Implications: Event Studies • Basic implication of overconfidence model is (1) Overreaction to Private Information, and (2) Underreaction to Public. • The model does imply that a security’s return on a public- information release date is negatively correlated with the fu- ture return. • However, counter-intuitively, the static confidence model does not imply that the correlation of the future return with the public signal is itself negative. – Static Confidence Model ⇒ cov(P3 − P2, s2) = 0 • Intuition: – Assume σθ = σ1 = σ2 Prior s1 s2 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 0 0 -1 -1 -2 -2 • Suppose s2 = 2, then E[θ|s2] = 1, S1 = 0 or 2 equally likely. • Bias equally likely to be up or down. • Even though underreaction, knowing s2 does not help predict sign of future returns. 27
  • 28. • If event is selective (based on mispricing or E[ |P1, s2]), it will forecast future returns. • Model is consistent with: Dividend Initiations Splits SEO’s (IPO’s) Repurchases Div. Omissions Event-Date 28
  • 29. Implications: Selective Events • Suppose managers act to correct pricing errors: – issue shares when stock overvalued – repurchase when stock undervalued – signal (split, dividend increase, forecast earnings favor- ably, boost accruals or cash flows) when undervalued • However, market revalues stubbornly ⇒ – average abnormal post-event return has same sign as event- date reaction. • Consistent with any prior runup or rundown • Informed outsider may also exploit misvaluations: – Analyst buy/sell recommendations – Toehold purchases, takeover bids? • Implications: – For good news events, the post-event abnormal re- turns will be larger when B/M high or pre-event perfor- mance poor (more negative initial valuation error). ∗ Ikenberry, Lakonishok, and Vermaelen (1995): B/M and repurchase – For bad news events, the post-event abnormal returns more negative when B/M low or pre-event performance good (more positive initial valuation error). ∗ Ikenberry, Rankine, and Stice (1996): prior perfor- mance and splits 29
  • 30. Implications: Earnings Growth and Future Returns • Many PEAD studies use non-selective measures – We need full dynamic model to account for this reaction. • In simulation, we define a public-information/“earnings” change as: ∆et = ˜φt − Φt−1 = ˜φt − E[˜φt|φs, s = 2, . . . , t − 1] • ∆et is therefore the deviation of φt from its expected value based on all past public signals. • Simulation: average correlation between information changes and future prices changes looks like: 20 40 60 80 100 120 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 x 10 −3 lag Cross−correlation • Broadly consistent with both post-earnings announcement drift, and long-run post-earnings reversals. – Magnitude of the effects depends on the intensity of the attribution bias relative to the variance of the public sig- nals. 30
  • 31. Implications: Price Scaled Variables • High price-scaled measures of fundamentals (e.g., E/P, D/P, B/M, 1/M) imply high future returns. • Favorable private signal ⇒ M ↑, B/M ↓. – Overreaction ⇒ long run M ↓ • Adverse private signal ⇒ M ↓, B/M ↑. – Overreaction ⇒ long run M ↑ • Therefore, high B/M ⇒ high long run future returns. • Aggregate price-scaled measures will forecast future market returns – if overconfidence about economy-wide information. • Price-scaled measures will forecast cross sectional patterns – if overconfidence about firm-specific information. • Price-scaled variables can dominate standard risk-measures if investors are sufficiently overconfident. • Standard fundamental ratio anomalies support overreaction theories, refute underreaction theories. 31
  • 32. Implications: Managerial Actions • Raise capital when fundamental ratios are low (stock overval- ued) • Issue shares after firm’s stock price has recently increased (consistent with Lucas and McDonald (1990).) • If overconfidence about common factors, issue after firm’s in- dustry or stock market has risen or B/M low (consistent with IPO evidence of Pagano, Panetta, and Zin- gales (1998)). • When book/market low, favor public over rights issues. • When book/market low, favor equity over debt issues. • When book/market low or after firm’s stock has risen, favor repurchase over dividend. Should managers disclose as much as possible prior to issuance? • Can exploit overconfidence by not disclosing. • But sometimes public disclosure can intensify an overreaction. 32
  • 33. Relation to Existing Theories Overconfidence: • Kyle and Wang (1997): being overconfident as a commitment to trade aggressively. • Wang (1998): Overconfidence → info-based trading without noise traders. • Odean (1998): Overconfidence with private but not a public signal, determinants of volatility, volume, and market depth. Overconfidence increases volatility, overreaction to private signals, • Caball´e and S´akovics (1996): Beliefs about beliefs about... • Benos (1996): Kyle (1985) model with overconfidence. Positive Feedback Strategies • DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990): Security autocorrelation patterns based on mechanistic positive feed- back investment strategies. Berk (1995): Recognizes that market value reflects discounting of risk. 33
  • 34. Noise Trader Approach • Prices are moved by trading that seems unrelated to the ar- rival of information. • Also important: investor mistakes involving misinterpretation of genuine new information. • Noise traders can be viewed as overconfident traders taking the limit, holding constant the individual’s perceived preci- sion, as his signal becomes very noisy. Do overconfident traders go broke? • Not if overconfidence helps them intimidate others, or encour- ages high-return risks. 34
  • 35. Further Empirical Implications • Firms should prefer debt over equity when B/M is high or following stock-price rundown. • Firms should prefer repurchases over dividends when B/M is low. • Positive correlation between initial event reaction and post- event performance. • Less under-reaction to non-selective corporate events. • Positive abnormal returns after toehold disclosures • Post-event performance better for good-news events when B/M high or pre-event performance poor. • Post-event performance worse for bad news events when B/M low or pre-event performance good. 35
  • 36. Other Comments on Overconfidence The over-weening conceit which the greater part of men have of their own abilities, is an ancient evil remarked by the philosophers and moralists of all ages. ... The distant prospect of hazards, from which we can hope to ex- tricate ourselves by courage and address, is not disagreeable to us, and does not raise the wages of labour in any employment. —The Wealth of Nations, p. 107, 110 • Smith: overconconfidence affects market prices in enterprises where outcome depends on ability. • Does the ‘overweening conceit’ of mankind affect stock market prices? 36
  • 37. Conclusions • Approach to anomalies: – Parsimonious – Based on strong psychological evidence – Explains wide range of phenomena plus new evidence • Possible further avenues: – Empirical testing – Institutions versus individuals 37
  • 38. References Abarbanell, Jeffery S., 1991, Do analysts’ earnings forecasts incorporate information in prior stock price changes?, Journal of Accounting and Economics 14, 147–165. , and Victor Bernard, 1992, Analysts’ overreaction / underreaction to earnings information as an explanation for anomalous stock price behavior, Journal of Finance 47, 1181–1207. Agrawal, Anup, Jeffery F. Jaffe, and Gershon Mandelker, 1992, The post-merger per- formance of acquiring firms in acquisitions: A re-examination of an anomaly, Journal of Finance 47, 1605–1621. , 1996, The pre-acquisition performance of target firms: A re-examination of the inefficient management hypothesis, Working paper, Wharton School. Ahlers, David, and Josef Lakonishok, 1983, A study of economists’ consensus forecasts, Management Science 29, 1113–1125. Ball, Ray, 1978, Anomalies in relationships between securities’ yields and yield- surrogates, Journal of Financial Economics 6, 103–126. Basu, S., 1983, The relationship between earnings yield, market value, and return for NYSE common stocks: Further evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 12, 126– 156. Baumann, Andrea O., Raisa B. Deber, and Gail G. Thompson, 1991, Overconfidence among physicians and nurses: The micro-certainty, macro-uncertainty phenomenon, Social Science & Medicine 32, 167–174. Berk, Jonathan, 1995, A critique of size related anomalies, Review of Financial Studies 8, 275–286. Bernard, Victor L., and Jacob K. Thomas, 1989, Post-earnings-announcement drift: Delayed price response or risk premium?, Journal of Accounting Research, Supplement 27, 1–48. , 1990, Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings, Journal of Accounting and Economics 13, 305–340. Brav, Alon, and Paul A. Gompers, 1997, Myth or reality? The long-run underperfor- mance of initial public offerings: Evidence from venture and nonventure capital-backed companies, Journal of Finance 52, 1791–1821. Brown, Steven J., and Peter F. Pope, 1996, Post-earnings announcement drift?, Working Paper, New York University. Caball´e, Jordi, and J´ozsef S´akovics, 1996, Overconfident speculation with imperfect competition, Working Paper,Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona. 38
  • 39. Campbell, John Y., and John H. Cochrane, 1999, By force of habit: A consumption- based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior, Journal of Political Economy 107, 205–251. Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller, 1988, The dividend-price ratio and expecta- tions of future dividends and discount factors, Review of Financial Studies 1, 195–228. Chopra, Navin, Josef Lakonishok, and Jay R. Ritter, 1992, Measuring abnormal perfor- mance: Do stocks overreact?, Journal of Financial Economics 31, 235–268. Christensen-Szalanski, Jay J., and James B. Bushyhead, 1981, Physicians’ use of prob- abilistic information in a real clinical setting, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 7, 928–935. Cooper, Arnold C., Carolyn W. Woo, and William C. Dunkelberg, 1988, Entrepeneurs’ perceived chances for success, Journal of Business Venturing 3, 97–108. Daniel, Kent D., 2001, The power and size of mean reversion tests, Journal of Empirical Finance 8, 493–535. , David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 2001, Overconfidence, arbi- trage, and equilibrium asset pricing, Journal of Finance 56, 921–965. Davis, James, Eugene F. Fama, and Kenneth R. French, 2000, Characteristics, covari- ances, and average returns: 1929-1997, Journal of Finance 55, 389–406. DeBondt, Werner F. M., 1991, What do economists know about the stock market?, Journal of Portfolio Management 17, 84–91. , and Richard H. Thaler, 1985, Does the stock market overreact?, Journal of Finance 40, 793–808. , 1987, Further evidence on investor overreaction and stock market seasonality, Journal of Finance 42, 557–581. , 1990, Do security analysts overreact?, American Economic Review 80, 52–57. DeLong, J. Bradford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence Summers, and Robert J. Waldmann, 1990, Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation, Journal of Finance 45, 375–395. Desai, Hemang, and Prem C. Jain, 1995, An analysis of the recommendations of the ‘superstar’ money managers at Barron’s annual roundtable, Journal of Finance 50, 1257–1274. , 1997, Long-run common stock returns following stock splits and reverse splits, Journal of Business 70, 409–434. Dow, Charles Henry, 1920, Scientific Stock Speculation (Magazine of Wall Street: New York). 39
  • 40. Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber, and Mustafa N. Gultekin, 1984, Professional ex- pectations: Accuracy and diagnosis of errors, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 19, 351–363. Fama, Eugene F., 1998, Market efficiency, long-term returns and behavioral finance, Journal of Financial Economics 49, 283–306. , and Kenneth R. French, 1988a, Dividend yields and expected stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 22, 3–25. , 1988b, Permanent and temporary components of stock prices, Journal of Po- litical Economy 96, 246–273. , 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns, Journal of Finance 47, 427– 465. , 1998, Value versus growth: The international evidence, Journal of Finance 53, 1975–1999. Fischoff, Baruch, 1982, For those condemned to study the past: Heuristics and biases in hindsight, in Daniel Kahneman, Paul Slovic, and Amos Tversky, ed.: Judgement under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases (Cambridge University Press: Cambridge). Froot, Kenneth, and Jeffery A. Frankel, 1989, Forward discount bias: Is it an exchange risk premium?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 139–161. Gompers, Paul, and Josh Lerner, 1998, Venture capital distributions: Short-run and long-run reactions, Journal of Finance. Graham, Benjamin, and D. Dodd, 1934, Security Analysis (McGraw Hill: New York, N.Y.). Grinblatt, Mark, Ronald W. Masulis, and Sheridan Titman, 1984, The valuation effects of stock splits and stock dividends, Journal of Financial Economics 13, 97–112. Ikenberry, David, Josef Lakonishok, and Theo Vermaelen, 1995, Market underreaction to open market share repurchases, Journal of Financial Economics 39, 181–208. Ikenberry, David, Graeme Rankine, and Earl K. Stice, 1996, What do stock splits really signal?, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 357–375. Jaffe, Jeffrey, Donald B. Keim, and Randolph Westerfield, 1989, Earnings yields, market values, and stock returns, Journal of Finance 44, 135–148. Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 1993, Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency, Journal of Finance 48, 65–91. , 2001, Profitability of momentum strategies: An evaluation of alternative ex- planations, Journal of Finance 56, 699–720. Kidd, John B., 1970, The utilization of subjective probabilities in production planning, Acta Psychologica 34, 338–347. 40
  • 41. Kim, Myung-Jig, Charles R. Nelson, and Richard Startz, 1988, Mean reversion in stock prices? A reappraisal of the empirical evidence, Review of Economic Studies 58, 551–528. Kothari, S.P., and Jay Shanken, 1997, Book-to-market, dividend yield, and expected market returns: A time-series analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 44, 169–203. Kyle, Albert, and F. Albert Wang, 1997, Speculation duopoly with agreement to dis- agree: Can overconfidence survive the market test?, Journal of Finance 52, 2073–2090. Lakonishok, Josef, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1994, Contrarian investment, extrapolation and risk, Journal of Finance 49, 1541–1578. Langer, Ellen J., and Jane Roth, 1975, Heads I win tails it’s chance: The illusion of control as a function of the sequence of outcomes in a purely chance task, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32, 951–955. Lo, Andrew W., and A. Craig MacKinlay, 1988, Stock market prices do not follow random walks: Evidence from a simple specification test, Review of Financial Studies 1, 41–46. Loughran, Tim, and Jay R. Ritter, 1995, The new issues puzzle, The Journal of Finance 50, 23–52. Lucas, Deborah J., and Robert L. McDonald, 1990, Equity issues and stock price dy- namics, Journal of Finance 45, 1019–1043. MacKinlay, A. Craig, 1995, Multifactor models do not explain deviations from the CAPM, Journal of Financial Economics 38, 3–28. Mendenhall, Richard, 1991, Evidence of possible underweighting of earnings-related in- formation, Journal of Accounting Research 29, 170–180. Michaely, Roni, Richard H. Thaler, and Kent L. Womack, 1995, Price reactions to dividend initiations and omissions: Overreaction or drift?, Journal of Finance 50, 573–608. Michaely, Roni, and Kent Womack, 1999, Conflict of interest and the credibility of underwriter analyst recommendations, Review of Financial Studies 12, 573–608. Miller, Dale T., and Michael Ross, 1975, Self-serving bias in attribution of causality: Fact or fiction?, Psychological Bulletin 82, 213–225. Neale, Margaret, and Max Bazerman, 1990, Cognition and Rationality in Negotiation (The Free Press: New York). Odean, Terrance, 1998, Volume, volatility, price and profit when all traders are above average, Journal of Finance 53, 1887–1934. Oskamp, Stuart, 1965, Overconfidence in case study judgements, Journal of Consulting Psychology 29, 261–265. 41
  • 42. Pagano, Marco, Fabio Panetta, and Luigi Zingales, 1998, Why do companies go public? an empirical analysis, Journal of Finance 53, 27–64. Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers, 1988, Mean reversion in stock returns: Evidence and implications, Journal of Financial Economics 22, 27–59. Rau, Raghavendra P., and Theo Vermaelen, 1998, Glamour, value and the post- acquisition performance of acquiring firms, Journal of Financial Economics 49. Rosenberg, Barr, Kenneth Reid, and Ronald Lanstein, 1985, Persuasive evidence of market inefficiency, Journal of Portfolio Management 11, 9–17. Rozeff, Michael S., and Mir A. Zaman, 1988, Market efficiency and insider trading: New evidence, Journal of Business 61, 25–44. Russo, J. Edward, and Paul J. H. Schoemaker, 1992, Managing overconfidence, Sloan Management Review 33, 7–17. Seyhun, H. Nejat, 1986, Insiders’ profits, costs of trading, and market efficiency, Journal of Financial Economics 61, 189–212. , 1988, The information content of aggregate insider trading, Journal of Business 61, 1–24. Spiess, D. Katherine, and John Affleck-Graves, 1995, Underperformance in long-run stock returns following seasoned equity offerings, Journal of Financial Economics 38, 243–268. Stael von Holstein, C., 1972, Probabilistic forecasting: An experiment related to the stock market, Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 8, 139–158. Stattman, Dennis, 1980, Book values and stock returns, The Chicago MBA: A Journal of Selected Papers 4, 25–45. Taylor, Shelley E., and Jonathan D. Brown, 1988, Illusion and well-being: A social psychological perspective on mental health, Psychological Bulletin 103, 193–210. Wagenaar, Willem, and Gideoan Keren, 1986, Does the expert know? The reliability of predictions and confidence ratios of experts, in Erik Hollnagel, Giuseppe Mancini, and David D. Woods, ed.: Intelligent Decision Support in Process Environment (Springer: Berlin). Wang, F. Albert, 1998, Strategic trading, asymmetric information and heterogeneous prior beliefs, Journal of Financial Markets 1, 321–352. Womack, Kent L., 1996, Do brokerage analysts’ recommendations have investment value?, Journal of Finance 51, 137–168. 42