SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 9
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
Trade Creation and Trade Diversion
Turkey and European Union
This is an analysis of trade diversion and trade creation. The analysis uses a partial equilibrium
framework, which means that we consider the effects of preferential trade liberalization with respect
to a representative industry. Later in the paper i will consider how the results from the
representative industry cases ( automobile in Turkey)can be extended to consider trade
liberalization that covers all trade sectors.

We can assume in each case that there are three countries in the world: Countries A, B, and C.
(Turkey, European union countries and Japan) Each country has supply and demand for a
homogeneous good in the representative industry. Countries A and B will form a free trade area. *1
The attention in this analysis will be on Country A, one of the two FTA members. We’ll assume that
Country A is a small country in international markets, which means that it takes international prices
as given. Countries B and C are assumed to be large countries (or regions). Thus Country A can export
or import as much of a product as desired with Countries B and C at whatever price prevails in those
markets.

We can also assume that if Country A were trading freely with either B or C, it would wish to
import the product in question. However, Country A initially is assumed not to be trading freely.
Instead, the country will have an MFN-specific tariff (i.e., the same tariff against both countries)
applied on imports from both Countries B and C.

In each case below, we will first describe an initial tariff-ridden equilibrium. Then, we will calculate
the price and welfare effects that would occur in this market if Countries A and B form an FTA. When
the FTA is formed, Country A maintains the same tariff against Country C, the non-FTA country.

Trade Diversion
In general, a trade diversion means that a free trade area diverts trade away from a moreefficient supplier outside the FTA and toward a less-efficient supplier within the FTA. In some cases,
trade diversion will reduce a country’s national welfare, but in some cases national welfare could
improve despite the trade diversion. İ will try to defend myself in both cases below.

Figure 9.10 "Harmful Trade Diversion" (disadvantage of Trade diversion) depicts the case in which
trade diversion is harmful to a country that joins an FTA. The graph shows the supply and demand
curves for Country A. PB and PC represent the free trade supply prices of the good from Countries B
and C, respectively. Note that Country C is assumed to be capable of supplying the product at a lower
price than Country B. (Note that in order for this to be possible, Country B must have tariffs or other
trade restrictions on imports from Country C, or else all of B’s market would be supplied by C.)
becouse of the agreement .

As we assume that A has a specific tariff

tB = tC = t∗ set on imports from both
Countries B and C. The tariff raises the
domestic supply prices to PTB and PTC,
respectively. The size of the tariff is
denoted by the green dotted lines in
Figure 9.10 "Harmful Trade Diversion",
which show that t∗ = PTB − PB = PTC −
PC.

Since, with the tariff, the product is cheaper from Country C, Country A will import the product
from Country C and will not trade initially with Country B. Imports are given by the red line, or by the
distance D1 − S1. Initial tariff revenue is given by the area (c + e), the tariff rate multiplied by the
quantity imported.

Next, lets assume that Countries A and B form an FTA and A eliminates the tariff on imports from
Country B. Now, tB = 0, but tC remains at t∗. The domestic prices on goods from Countries B and C
are now PB and PTC, respectively. Since PB < PTC, Country A would import all the product from
Country B after the FTA and would import nothing from Country C. At the lower domestic price, PB,
imports would rise to D2 − S2, denoted by the blue line. Also, since the no distorted (i.e., free trade)
price in Country C is less than the price in Country B, trade is said to be diverted from a moreefficient supplier to a less-efficient supplier.
The welfare effects are summarized in Table 9.16 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation:
Trade Diversion Cases".
Table 2 Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases
Country A

National Welfare

+ (b + d) − e

Consumer Surplus

+ (a + b + c + d)

Govt. Revenue
Producer Surplus

− (c + e)
−a

Free trade area effects on Country A’s consumers. Consumers of the product in the importing
country benefit from the free trade area. The reduction in the domestic price of both the imported
goods and the domestic substitutes raises consumer surplus in the market. Refer to Table 9.16
"Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases" and Figure 9.10 "Harmful
Trade Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the change in consumer surplus is represented.

Free trade area effects on Country A’s producers. Producers in the importing country suffer
losses as a result of the free trade area. The decrease in the price of their product on the domestic
market reduces producer surplus in the industry. The price decrease also induces a decrease in the
output of existing firms (and perhaps some firms will shut down), a decrease in employment, and a
decrease in profit, payments, or both to fixed costs "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation:
Trade Diversion Cases" and Figure 2 "Harmful Trade Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the
change in producer surplus is represented.

Free trade area effects on Country A’s government. The government loses all the tariff revenue
that had been collected on imports of the product. This reduces government revenue, which may in
turn reduce government spending or transfers or raise government debt. Who loses depends on how
the adjustment is made. Refer to Table 2 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade
Diversion Cases" and Figure 1 "Harmful Trade Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the tariff
revenue is represented.

Free trade area effects on Country A’s national welfare. The aggregate welfare effect for the
country is found by summing the gains and losses to consumers, producers, and the government. The
net effect consists of three components:
a) positive production efficiency gain
(b), a positive consumption efficiency gain
(c), and a negative tariff revenue loss
(d) we notice that not all the tariff revenue loss (c + e) is represented in the loss to the nation. That’s
because some of the total losses (area c) are, in effect, transferred to consumers. Refer to Table 2
"Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases" and Figure 1 "Harmful Trade
Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the change in national welfare is represented.

Because there are both positive and negative elements, the net national welfare effect can be
either positive or negative. Figure 1 "Harmful Trade Diversion" depicts the case in which the FTA
causes a reduction in national welfare. Visually, it seems obvious that area e is larger than the sum of
a and b. Thus, under these conditions, the FTA with trade diversion would cause national welfare to
fall.

If conditions were different, however, the national welfare change could be positive. Consider
Figure 3 "Beneficial Trade Diversion" (advantage). This diagram differs from Figure 2 "Harmful Trade
Diversion" only in that the free trade supply price offered by Country B, PB, is lower and closer to
Country C’s free trade supply price, PC. The description earlier concerning the pre- and post-FTA
equilibria remains the same, and trade diversion still occurs. The welfare effects remain the same in
direction but differ in magnitude. Notice that the consumer surplus gain is now larger because the
drop in the domestic price is larger. Also notice that the net national welfare effect, (b + d − e),
visually appears positive. This shows that in some cases, formation of an FTA that causes a trade
diversion may have a positive net national welfare effect. Thus a trade diversion may be, but is not
necessarily.

Figure 3 Beneficial Trade Diversions

Generally speaking, the larger the difference between the
nondistorted prices in the FTA partner country and in the
rest of the world, the more likely it is that trade diversion
will reduce national welfare.

Trade Creation
In general, trade creation means that a free trade area creates trade that would not have existed
otherwise. As a result, supply occurs from a more-efficient producer of the product. In all cases,
trade creation will raise a country’s national welfare.

Figure 4 "Trade Creation" depicts a case of trade creation. The graph shows the supply and demand
curves for Country A. PB and PC represent the free trade supply prices of the good from Countries B
and C, respectively. Note that Country C is assumed to be capable of supplying the product at a lower
price than Country B. (Note that in order for this to be possible, Country B must have tariffs or other
trade restrictions on imports from Country C, or else all of B’s market would be supplied by C.)

Figure 4 Trade Creation

Assume that A has a specific tariff, tB = tC = t∗, set on
imports from both Countries B and C. The tariff raises the
domestic supply prices to PTB and PTC, respectively. The
size of the tariff is denoted by the green dotted lines in
Figure 4"Trade Creation", which show that t∗ = PTB − PB =
PTC − PC.

Since, with the tariffs, the autarky price in Country A, labeled PA in Figure 4 "Trade Creation", is
less than the tariff-ridden prices PTB and PTC, the product will not be imported. Instead, Country A
will supply its own domestic demand at S1 = D1. In this case, the original tariffs are prohibitive.
Next, assume Countries A and B form an FTA and A eliminates the tariff on imports from Country
B. Now tB = 0, but tC remains at t∗. The domestic prices on goods from Countries B and C are now PB
and PTC, respectively. Since PB < PA, Country A would now import the product from Country B after
the FTA. At the lower domestic price PB, imports would rise to the blue line distance, or D2 − S2.
Since trade now occurs with the FTA and it did not occur before, trade is said to be created.

The welfare effects are summarized in Table 5 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade
Creation Case".

Table 5 Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Creation Case
Country A
Consumer Surplus
Producer Surplus
Govt. Revenue
National Welfare

+ (a + b + c)
−a
0
+ (b + c)

Free trade area effects on Country A’s consumers. Consumers of the product in the importing
country benefit from the free trade area. The reduction in the domestic price of both imported goods
and the domestic substitutes raises consumer surplus in the market. Refer to Table 4 "Welfare
Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Creation Case" and Figure 4 "Trade Creation" to see how
the magnitude of the change in consumer surplus is represented.

Free trade area effects on Country A’s producers. Producers in the importing country suffer
losses as a result of the free trade area. The decrease in the price of their product in the domestic
market reduces producer surplus in the industry. The price decrease also induces a decrease in
output of existing firms (and perhaps some firms will shut down), a decrease in employment, and a
decrease in profit, payments, or both to fixed costs. Refer to Table 3"Welfare Effects of Free Trade
Area Formation: Trade Creation Case" and Figure 3 "Trade Creation" to see how the magnitude of
the change in producer surplus is represented.

Free trade area effects on Country A’s government. Since initial tariffs were prohibitive and the
product was not originally imported, there was no initial tariff revenue. Thus the FTA induces no loss
of revenue.

Free trade area effects on Country A’s national welfare. The aggregate welfare effect for the
country is found by summing the gains and losses to consumers and producers. The net effect
consists of two positive components: a positive production efficiency gain (b) and a positive
consumption efficiency gain (c). This means that if trade creation arises when an FTA is formed, it
must result in net national welfare gains. Refer to Table 4 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area
Formation: Trade Creation Case" and Figure 3"Trade Creation" to see how the magnitude of the
change in national welfare is represented.

Example of Trade creation and division
if Turkey and the EU form a customs union, tariffs on EUautomobile must now be reduced, and
once they are completely removed, the free market price of 120TL will be highly attractive to Turkish
consumers. Turkish consumers will now consume moreautomobile in total because average
automobile prices will have fallen with the removal of tariffs on EU automobile producation, and
total demand for automobile rises. For example, lets asume that a total output and consumption
might increase to 32m (up by 2m), with Turkey farmers down from 20m to 15m, New Zealand
exports collapsing to just 2m, and EU increasing its output and sales of automobile to Turkey to 10m
(from 5m to 10m). Total consumption has gone up from 30m (20 + 5 + 5), to 32m (15 + 2 + 15). The
additional 2m of automobile produced and consumed is the new trade created as a result of the
removal of barriers by union members.
Furthermore, this will enable a dynamic reaction within EU and Turkey. Over time, as countries
become more integrated, increased trade will generate further efficiency gains, such as through the
application of economies of scale. Prices may fall even further, relative to those of non-member
countries, and the process of trade creation continues.
For example, with increased sales, EU can specialise further in automobile production, and
produce on large scale, bringing prices down even further (perhaps nearer to the New Zealand level).
Also, theTurkey can now free up its resources, and move them out of automobile production and
into goods and services for which Turkey has a comparative advantages over EU. Hence, over time,
trade creation will continue as a positive long-term effect of a customs union.
The major loser in this is the previous trading partner left outside the bloc - less trade now exists
between new members and their old trading partners. The process of efficient producers losing out
to inefficient ones is generally referred to as trade diversion. For example, after EU and Turkey form
a customs union, New Zealand, which was the most efficient automobile producer, suffers a loss of
sales to Turkey, from 5m to 2m, with trade diverted from New Zealand to EU. However, there is
some debate about the use of the term trade diversion. In its simplest form it means any trade
diverted away from efficient global producers as a result of the creation of a customs union. Other
economists regard trade diversion as relating to the long-term loss of trade resulting from inefficient
producers (such as EU, in our hypothetical example) becoming more efficient following membership
of the union. For example, if the price of EU butter falls from 120TL to 95TL as a result of trade
expansion within the union, it is now 5TL cheaper than New Zealand in the open market, and more
trade may now be diverted away from the formerly highly efficient New Zealand. Whichever
definition is accepted, it is clear that in this case the union has distorted trade.
Finally, i also need to consider the loss of tariff revenue that might follow the diversion of trade
from non-member countries. Given that, in our simple example, imports from New Zealand have
fallen causing a loss of tariff revenue, and tariff revenue from EU automobile has been eliminated, it
is necessary to weigh up the welfare gains and losses from the formation of the customs union.
There is no simple answer to this, and it is quite possible that a union could result in either a net loss,
or a net gain.
We can conclude that small countries (such as New Zealand, in our hypothetical case) may be at a
considerable disadvantage by not joining a customs union, or free trade area. In fact, they are
certainly likely to, as the above analysis would indicate.
Trade creation diagram
With a tariff imposed prior to the formation of a customs union with Denmark, UK farmers
supply 0 – Q2, and Q2 to Q3 is imported. The net welfare loss would be (X + Y).
Following the union, the tariff is
abandoned and the market share
of Turkey farmers falls to 0 – Q1,
and imports from Denmark
increase from Q4 – Q3, to Q1 to
Q2. The welfare gain is X + Y, and
the trade created is Q3 to Q2

Remarks:
I will take this chance to Thank my Prof DR nejat ERK for consulting me and encouraging me every
step of the way. You truly did the impossible as i honestly could not imagine having achieved what I
did, without your guidance.. You inspired me to be a better person, with every class being so full of
love and passion. It’s all those little things you did for us, treating us like we were your very own little
sons, scolding us when we did not perform to our potential, laughing with us-even though our jokes
made no sense, treating us with so much respect, and so so SO much more, you have no idea how
much those few months of being your student has impacted my life. I don’t think I will ever meet
anyone as selfless, or as impacting as you. This is too short a space for me to express how much of a
change you have made in me, but I’d like to thank you from the very bottom of my heart, for helping
me overcome what I felt was the biggest drawback in me…

prepared by:
Taherou mass kah
Economic department
çukurova university turkey
Master’s program

*1(Note that trade diversion and creation can occur regardless of whether a preferential trade
agreement, a free trade area, or a customs union is formed. For convenience, we’ll refer to the
arrangement as a free trade area [FTA].)
Reference
1) http://2012books.lardbucket.org/books/policy-and-theory-of-international-economics/s1210-economic-integration-free-trad.html
2) http://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Global_economics/Trade_creation.html
3) Victor F. Gauto: An Econometric Analysis of Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in Mercosur:
the Case of Paraguay
4) http://www.counsellors.gov.tr/detay.cfm?AlanID=6&dil=TR&ulke=D
5) http://ec.europa.eu/trade/policy/countries-and-regions/countries/turkey/
6) Selahattin Bekmez and Murat Komut at Mugla University: Competitiveness of Turkish
Automotive Industry, A Comperison with European Union Countries
7) Ali Koçyiğit and Ali Şen The Extent of Intra-Industry Trade between Turkey and the European
Union: The Impact of Customs Union.
8) http://haber.sol.org.tr/devlet-ve-siyaset/tarimda-buyuk-cokus-turkiye-en-fazla-urettigiurunleri-bile-ithal-ediyor-haberi

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Andere mochten auch

Qui soc i com soc
Qui soc i com socQui soc i com soc
Qui soc i com soc
asa3112
 
Ens Presentem Total
Ens Presentem TotalEns Presentem Total
Ens Presentem Total
mmoral53
 
EAC Mark - Eurasian Custom Union
EAC Mark - Eurasian Custom UnionEAC Mark - Eurasian Custom Union
EAC Mark - Eurasian Custom Union
Soe Hein Kyaw
 
Presentation integration
Presentation integrationPresentation integration
Presentation integration
Mohamed Ahmed
 
GM Exam Revision (April 2014)
GM Exam Revision (April 2014)GM Exam Revision (April 2014)
GM Exam Revision (April 2014)
GMAdvisor
 
Economic integration
Economic integrationEconomic integration
Economic integration
Victoria Rock
 

Andere mochten auch (17)

Europe Needs a Common Political Market
Europe Needs a Common Political MarketEurope Needs a Common Political Market
Europe Needs a Common Political Market
 
Union Custom Code
Union Custom CodeUnion Custom Code
Union Custom Code
 
Qui soc i com soc
Qui soc i com socQui soc i com soc
Qui soc i com soc
 
Ens Presentem Total
Ens Presentem TotalEns Presentem Total
Ens Presentem Total
 
EAC Mark - Eurasian Custom Union
EAC Mark - Eurasian Custom UnionEAC Mark - Eurasian Custom Union
EAC Mark - Eurasian Custom Union
 
CE Marking- EMC- Products Regulatory
CE Marking- EMC- Products RegulatoryCE Marking- EMC- Products Regulatory
CE Marking- EMC- Products Regulatory
 
'Brexit' –VAT & Customs implications for international supply chains
'Brexit' –VAT & Customs implications for international supply chains'Brexit' –VAT & Customs implications for international supply chains
'Brexit' –VAT & Customs implications for international supply chains
 
COMMON MARKET FOR EASTERN AND SOUTHERN AFRICA Experience of comesa in intra r...
COMMON MARKET FOR EASTERN AND SOUTHERN AFRICA Experience of comesa in intra r...COMMON MARKET FOR EASTERN AND SOUTHERN AFRICA Experience of comesa in intra r...
COMMON MARKET FOR EASTERN AND SOUTHERN AFRICA Experience of comesa in intra r...
 
Presentation integration
Presentation integrationPresentation integration
Presentation integration
 
GM Exam Revision (April 2014)
GM Exam Revision (April 2014)GM Exam Revision (April 2014)
GM Exam Revision (April 2014)
 
Paul Krugman Power Point
Paul Krugman Power PointPaul Krugman Power Point
Paul Krugman Power Point
 
Economic integration
Economic integrationEconomic integration
Economic integration
 
International Marketing Research:Complete Aspect.
International Marketing Research:Complete Aspect.International Marketing Research:Complete Aspect.
International Marketing Research:Complete Aspect.
 
NAFTA at 20
NAFTA at 20NAFTA at 20
NAFTA at 20
 
European Union
European UnionEuropean Union
European Union
 
European union
European unionEuropean union
European union
 
European Economic and Monetary union
European Economic and Monetary unionEuropean Economic and Monetary union
European Economic and Monetary union
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen

The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
heathfieldcps1
 
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
fonyou31
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
QucHHunhnh
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
SoniaTolstoy
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen (20)

Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
 
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
 
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdfDisha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
Disha NEET Physics Guide for classes 11 and 12.pdf
 
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
Explore beautiful and ugly buildings. Mathematics helps us create beautiful d...
 
9548086042 for call girls in Indira Nagar with room service
9548086042  for call girls in Indira Nagar  with room service9548086042  for call girls in Indira Nagar  with room service
9548086042 for call girls in Indira Nagar with room service
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
 
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
Mattingly "AI & Prompt Design: Structured Data, Assistants, & RAG"
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
 
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptxUnit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
Unit-IV- Pharma. Marketing Channels.pptx
 
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdfHoldier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
Holdier Curriculum Vitae (April 2024).pdf
 
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
Ecosystem Interactions Class Discussion Presentation in Blue Green Lined Styl...
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
 
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi  6.pdf
1029-Danh muc Sach Giao Khoa khoi 6.pdf
 
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across SectorsAPM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
APM Welcome, APM North West Network Conference, Synergies Across Sectors
 
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
Sports & Fitness Value Added Course FY..
 
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdfBASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK  LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
BASLIQ CURRENT LOOKBOOK LOOKBOOK(1) (1).pdf
 
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SDMeasures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
Measures of Dispersion and Variability: Range, QD, AD and SD
 
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpinStudent login on Anyboli platform.helpin
Student login on Anyboli platform.helpin
 
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
Advanced Views - Calendar View in Odoo 17
 

Trade creation and trade diversion

  • 1. Trade Creation and Trade Diversion Turkey and European Union This is an analysis of trade diversion and trade creation. The analysis uses a partial equilibrium framework, which means that we consider the effects of preferential trade liberalization with respect to a representative industry. Later in the paper i will consider how the results from the representative industry cases ( automobile in Turkey)can be extended to consider trade liberalization that covers all trade sectors. We can assume in each case that there are three countries in the world: Countries A, B, and C. (Turkey, European union countries and Japan) Each country has supply and demand for a homogeneous good in the representative industry. Countries A and B will form a free trade area. *1 The attention in this analysis will be on Country A, one of the two FTA members. We’ll assume that Country A is a small country in international markets, which means that it takes international prices as given. Countries B and C are assumed to be large countries (or regions). Thus Country A can export or import as much of a product as desired with Countries B and C at whatever price prevails in those markets. We can also assume that if Country A were trading freely with either B or C, it would wish to import the product in question. However, Country A initially is assumed not to be trading freely. Instead, the country will have an MFN-specific tariff (i.e., the same tariff against both countries) applied on imports from both Countries B and C. In each case below, we will first describe an initial tariff-ridden equilibrium. Then, we will calculate the price and welfare effects that would occur in this market if Countries A and B form an FTA. When the FTA is formed, Country A maintains the same tariff against Country C, the non-FTA country. Trade Diversion In general, a trade diversion means that a free trade area diverts trade away from a moreefficient supplier outside the FTA and toward a less-efficient supplier within the FTA. In some cases,
  • 2. trade diversion will reduce a country’s national welfare, but in some cases national welfare could improve despite the trade diversion. İ will try to defend myself in both cases below. Figure 9.10 "Harmful Trade Diversion" (disadvantage of Trade diversion) depicts the case in which trade diversion is harmful to a country that joins an FTA. The graph shows the supply and demand curves for Country A. PB and PC represent the free trade supply prices of the good from Countries B and C, respectively. Note that Country C is assumed to be capable of supplying the product at a lower price than Country B. (Note that in order for this to be possible, Country B must have tariffs or other trade restrictions on imports from Country C, or else all of B’s market would be supplied by C.) becouse of the agreement . As we assume that A has a specific tariff tB = tC = t∗ set on imports from both Countries B and C. The tariff raises the domestic supply prices to PTB and PTC, respectively. The size of the tariff is denoted by the green dotted lines in Figure 9.10 "Harmful Trade Diversion", which show that t∗ = PTB − PB = PTC − PC. Since, with the tariff, the product is cheaper from Country C, Country A will import the product from Country C and will not trade initially with Country B. Imports are given by the red line, or by the distance D1 − S1. Initial tariff revenue is given by the area (c + e), the tariff rate multiplied by the quantity imported. Next, lets assume that Countries A and B form an FTA and A eliminates the tariff on imports from Country B. Now, tB = 0, but tC remains at t∗. The domestic prices on goods from Countries B and C are now PB and PTC, respectively. Since PB < PTC, Country A would import all the product from Country B after the FTA and would import nothing from Country C. At the lower domestic price, PB, imports would rise to D2 − S2, denoted by the blue line. Also, since the no distorted (i.e., free trade) price in Country C is less than the price in Country B, trade is said to be diverted from a moreefficient supplier to a less-efficient supplier. The welfare effects are summarized in Table 9.16 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases". Table 2 Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases
  • 3. Country A National Welfare + (b + d) − e Consumer Surplus + (a + b + c + d) Govt. Revenue Producer Surplus − (c + e) −a Free trade area effects on Country A’s consumers. Consumers of the product in the importing country benefit from the free trade area. The reduction in the domestic price of both the imported goods and the domestic substitutes raises consumer surplus in the market. Refer to Table 9.16 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases" and Figure 9.10 "Harmful Trade Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the change in consumer surplus is represented. Free trade area effects on Country A’s producers. Producers in the importing country suffer losses as a result of the free trade area. The decrease in the price of their product on the domestic market reduces producer surplus in the industry. The price decrease also induces a decrease in the output of existing firms (and perhaps some firms will shut down), a decrease in employment, and a decrease in profit, payments, or both to fixed costs "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases" and Figure 2 "Harmful Trade Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the change in producer surplus is represented. Free trade area effects on Country A’s government. The government loses all the tariff revenue that had been collected on imports of the product. This reduces government revenue, which may in turn reduce government spending or transfers or raise government debt. Who loses depends on how the adjustment is made. Refer to Table 2 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases" and Figure 1 "Harmful Trade Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the tariff revenue is represented. Free trade area effects on Country A’s national welfare. The aggregate welfare effect for the country is found by summing the gains and losses to consumers, producers, and the government. The net effect consists of three components: a) positive production efficiency gain (b), a positive consumption efficiency gain (c), and a negative tariff revenue loss (d) we notice that not all the tariff revenue loss (c + e) is represented in the loss to the nation. That’s because some of the total losses (area c) are, in effect, transferred to consumers. Refer to Table 2
  • 4. "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Diversion Cases" and Figure 1 "Harmful Trade Diversion" to see how the magnitude of the change in national welfare is represented. Because there are both positive and negative elements, the net national welfare effect can be either positive or negative. Figure 1 "Harmful Trade Diversion" depicts the case in which the FTA causes a reduction in national welfare. Visually, it seems obvious that area e is larger than the sum of a and b. Thus, under these conditions, the FTA with trade diversion would cause national welfare to fall. If conditions were different, however, the national welfare change could be positive. Consider Figure 3 "Beneficial Trade Diversion" (advantage). This diagram differs from Figure 2 "Harmful Trade Diversion" only in that the free trade supply price offered by Country B, PB, is lower and closer to Country C’s free trade supply price, PC. The description earlier concerning the pre- and post-FTA equilibria remains the same, and trade diversion still occurs. The welfare effects remain the same in direction but differ in magnitude. Notice that the consumer surplus gain is now larger because the drop in the domestic price is larger. Also notice that the net national welfare effect, (b + d − e), visually appears positive. This shows that in some cases, formation of an FTA that causes a trade diversion may have a positive net national welfare effect. Thus a trade diversion may be, but is not necessarily. Figure 3 Beneficial Trade Diversions Generally speaking, the larger the difference between the nondistorted prices in the FTA partner country and in the rest of the world, the more likely it is that trade diversion will reduce national welfare. Trade Creation
  • 5. In general, trade creation means that a free trade area creates trade that would not have existed otherwise. As a result, supply occurs from a more-efficient producer of the product. In all cases, trade creation will raise a country’s national welfare. Figure 4 "Trade Creation" depicts a case of trade creation. The graph shows the supply and demand curves for Country A. PB and PC represent the free trade supply prices of the good from Countries B and C, respectively. Note that Country C is assumed to be capable of supplying the product at a lower price than Country B. (Note that in order for this to be possible, Country B must have tariffs or other trade restrictions on imports from Country C, or else all of B’s market would be supplied by C.) Figure 4 Trade Creation Assume that A has a specific tariff, tB = tC = t∗, set on imports from both Countries B and C. The tariff raises the domestic supply prices to PTB and PTC, respectively. The size of the tariff is denoted by the green dotted lines in Figure 4"Trade Creation", which show that t∗ = PTB − PB = PTC − PC. Since, with the tariffs, the autarky price in Country A, labeled PA in Figure 4 "Trade Creation", is less than the tariff-ridden prices PTB and PTC, the product will not be imported. Instead, Country A will supply its own domestic demand at S1 = D1. In this case, the original tariffs are prohibitive. Next, assume Countries A and B form an FTA and A eliminates the tariff on imports from Country B. Now tB = 0, but tC remains at t∗. The domestic prices on goods from Countries B and C are now PB and PTC, respectively. Since PB < PA, Country A would now import the product from Country B after the FTA. At the lower domestic price PB, imports would rise to the blue line distance, or D2 − S2. Since trade now occurs with the FTA and it did not occur before, trade is said to be created. The welfare effects are summarized in Table 5 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Creation Case". Table 5 Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Creation Case
  • 6. Country A Consumer Surplus Producer Surplus Govt. Revenue National Welfare + (a + b + c) −a 0 + (b + c) Free trade area effects on Country A’s consumers. Consumers of the product in the importing country benefit from the free trade area. The reduction in the domestic price of both imported goods and the domestic substitutes raises consumer surplus in the market. Refer to Table 4 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Creation Case" and Figure 4 "Trade Creation" to see how the magnitude of the change in consumer surplus is represented. Free trade area effects on Country A’s producers. Producers in the importing country suffer losses as a result of the free trade area. The decrease in the price of their product in the domestic market reduces producer surplus in the industry. The price decrease also induces a decrease in output of existing firms (and perhaps some firms will shut down), a decrease in employment, and a decrease in profit, payments, or both to fixed costs. Refer to Table 3"Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Creation Case" and Figure 3 "Trade Creation" to see how the magnitude of the change in producer surplus is represented. Free trade area effects on Country A’s government. Since initial tariffs were prohibitive and the product was not originally imported, there was no initial tariff revenue. Thus the FTA induces no loss of revenue. Free trade area effects on Country A’s national welfare. The aggregate welfare effect for the country is found by summing the gains and losses to consumers and producers. The net effect consists of two positive components: a positive production efficiency gain (b) and a positive consumption efficiency gain (c). This means that if trade creation arises when an FTA is formed, it must result in net national welfare gains. Refer to Table 4 "Welfare Effects of Free Trade Area Formation: Trade Creation Case" and Figure 3"Trade Creation" to see how the magnitude of the change in national welfare is represented. Example of Trade creation and division if Turkey and the EU form a customs union, tariffs on EUautomobile must now be reduced, and once they are completely removed, the free market price of 120TL will be highly attractive to Turkish consumers. Turkish consumers will now consume moreautomobile in total because average automobile prices will have fallen with the removal of tariffs on EU automobile producation, and total demand for automobile rises. For example, lets asume that a total output and consumption
  • 7. might increase to 32m (up by 2m), with Turkey farmers down from 20m to 15m, New Zealand exports collapsing to just 2m, and EU increasing its output and sales of automobile to Turkey to 10m (from 5m to 10m). Total consumption has gone up from 30m (20 + 5 + 5), to 32m (15 + 2 + 15). The additional 2m of automobile produced and consumed is the new trade created as a result of the removal of barriers by union members. Furthermore, this will enable a dynamic reaction within EU and Turkey. Over time, as countries become more integrated, increased trade will generate further efficiency gains, such as through the application of economies of scale. Prices may fall even further, relative to those of non-member countries, and the process of trade creation continues. For example, with increased sales, EU can specialise further in automobile production, and produce on large scale, bringing prices down even further (perhaps nearer to the New Zealand level). Also, theTurkey can now free up its resources, and move them out of automobile production and into goods and services for which Turkey has a comparative advantages over EU. Hence, over time, trade creation will continue as a positive long-term effect of a customs union. The major loser in this is the previous trading partner left outside the bloc - less trade now exists between new members and their old trading partners. The process of efficient producers losing out to inefficient ones is generally referred to as trade diversion. For example, after EU and Turkey form a customs union, New Zealand, which was the most efficient automobile producer, suffers a loss of sales to Turkey, from 5m to 2m, with trade diverted from New Zealand to EU. However, there is some debate about the use of the term trade diversion. In its simplest form it means any trade diverted away from efficient global producers as a result of the creation of a customs union. Other economists regard trade diversion as relating to the long-term loss of trade resulting from inefficient producers (such as EU, in our hypothetical example) becoming more efficient following membership of the union. For example, if the price of EU butter falls from 120TL to 95TL as a result of trade expansion within the union, it is now 5TL cheaper than New Zealand in the open market, and more trade may now be diverted away from the formerly highly efficient New Zealand. Whichever definition is accepted, it is clear that in this case the union has distorted trade. Finally, i also need to consider the loss of tariff revenue that might follow the diversion of trade from non-member countries. Given that, in our simple example, imports from New Zealand have fallen causing a loss of tariff revenue, and tariff revenue from EU automobile has been eliminated, it is necessary to weigh up the welfare gains and losses from the formation of the customs union. There is no simple answer to this, and it is quite possible that a union could result in either a net loss, or a net gain. We can conclude that small countries (such as New Zealand, in our hypothetical case) may be at a considerable disadvantage by not joining a customs union, or free trade area. In fact, they are certainly likely to, as the above analysis would indicate. Trade creation diagram With a tariff imposed prior to the formation of a customs union with Denmark, UK farmers supply 0 – Q2, and Q2 to Q3 is imported. The net welfare loss would be (X + Y).
  • 8. Following the union, the tariff is abandoned and the market share of Turkey farmers falls to 0 – Q1, and imports from Denmark increase from Q4 – Q3, to Q1 to Q2. The welfare gain is X + Y, and the trade created is Q3 to Q2 Remarks: I will take this chance to Thank my Prof DR nejat ERK for consulting me and encouraging me every step of the way. You truly did the impossible as i honestly could not imagine having achieved what I did, without your guidance.. You inspired me to be a better person, with every class being so full of love and passion. It’s all those little things you did for us, treating us like we were your very own little sons, scolding us when we did not perform to our potential, laughing with us-even though our jokes made no sense, treating us with so much respect, and so so SO much more, you have no idea how much those few months of being your student has impacted my life. I don’t think I will ever meet anyone as selfless, or as impacting as you. This is too short a space for me to express how much of a change you have made in me, but I’d like to thank you from the very bottom of my heart, for helping me overcome what I felt was the biggest drawback in me… prepared by: Taherou mass kah Economic department çukurova university turkey Master’s program *1(Note that trade diversion and creation can occur regardless of whether a preferential trade agreement, a free trade area, or a customs union is formed. For convenience, we’ll refer to the arrangement as a free trade area [FTA].) Reference 1) http://2012books.lardbucket.org/books/policy-and-theory-of-international-economics/s1210-economic-integration-free-trad.html 2) http://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Global_economics/Trade_creation.html 3) Victor F. Gauto: An Econometric Analysis of Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in Mercosur: the Case of Paraguay 4) http://www.counsellors.gov.tr/detay.cfm?AlanID=6&dil=TR&ulke=D 5) http://ec.europa.eu/trade/policy/countries-and-regions/countries/turkey/
  • 9. 6) Selahattin Bekmez and Murat Komut at Mugla University: Competitiveness of Turkish Automotive Industry, A Comperison with European Union Countries 7) Ali Koçyiğit and Ali Şen The Extent of Intra-Industry Trade between Turkey and the European Union: The Impact of Customs Union. 8) http://haber.sol.org.tr/devlet-ve-siyaset/tarimda-buyuk-cokus-turkiye-en-fazla-urettigiurunleri-bile-ithal-ediyor-haberi