SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 42
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
Does it pay to do good?
An analysis of CEO Compensation at Large American Charities
Jessica Reif, B.S. ILR Honors Candidate
April 2014
Cornell University School of Industrial and Labor Relations
Adviser: Professor Kevin Hallock
Second Reader: Professor Robert Smith
1
Introduction
Many donors are appalled to learn that the executives managing their favorite charities
earn six-figure salaries. The national media and watchdog organizations frequently draw public
attention to the arena of nonprofit compensation (Wallock 2013, Charity Navigator 2013).
Though only a small fraction of the public is educated in compensation, articles such as the “Ten
Insanely Overpaid Nonprofit Execs” published in the Huffington Post draw millions of readers
and hundreds of commenters (Strachan 2013). Recent financial scandals involving CEOs at large
charities including United Way, the Smithsonian Institution, and Covenant House have shaken
the public’s faith in nonprofits (Frumkin 2011).
Charity Navigator, a nonprofit institution that seeks to aggregate publicly available
financial information from charitable organizations to assist donors and would-be donors, also
stresses the importance of executive compensation in evaluating charities. Annually, its research
division publishes a study of CEO compensation at charitable organizations, highlighting
differences based on organization size, mission, and location. The 2013 study notes, “Many
donors assume that charity leaders work for free or minimal pay” (2013 CEO Compensation
Study). While reassuring donors that the median salary for nonprofit CEOs increased only 2.5%
from the previous year, Charity Navigator encourages donors to be vigilant about excessive
nonprofit compensation – particularly at organizations where the CEO is paid $1 million or
higher (2013 CEO Compensation Study).
Six- and seven-figure compensation packages at large charities have led to action by
some state governments. A December 2013 report from the Massachusetts Attorney General’s
office called for reform of compensation disclosure at nonprofits, after a study of 25 large
2
Massachusetts-based charities showed CEOs earning over half-million dollar compensation
packages in addition to lavish perks (Wallock 2013). In May 2013, New York Governor Andrew
Cuomo issued an executive order prohibiting charities who receive state funding from paying
more than $199,000 to any employee. Similar measures were enacted by Florida and New Jersey
(Wallock 2013).
While very few consumers review the executive compensation practices of the for-profit
companies to whom they bring their business, executive pay carries particular importance to
citizens interested in charitable giving and the governments that provide tax-exemptions to these
organizations. To build trust from the public, nonprofit organizations must prove to their donors
that they are worthy of the contributions they receive. Without this trust, nonprofits will be
unable to garner enough public support to fundraise enough to accomplish their goals. For
donors, appropriate compensation indicates that their contributions move forward the espoused
social mission of the organization, not boost the pay of executives. Likewise, governments offer
nonprofits special tax benefits not available to for-profit companies. These financial benefits are
intended to permit the nonprofit to achieve greater social welfare, not raise executive pay. The
government legally prohibits nonprofits from paying executives beyond what is ‘reasonable’
under the totality of circumstances and from distributing excess earnings to managers, thus
executive pay is subject to special oversight and government scrutiny (Hansman 1980).
Many management scholars and nonprofit leaders challenge the assumption that the
compensation the public deems to be inflated is in fact too high. The consensus in management
literature is that compensation is an important tool for attracting and retaining top talent (Drucker
1990, Conyon et al. 2009). Nonprofit organizations are highly complex like their for-profit
counterparts, and therefore require educated leaders with high levels of managerial skill.
3
Individuals of this quality come with a price. In order to compete for top talent nonprofits need to
offer competitive wages to those in charge.
Without question, a lot is riding on managerial pay. Appropriate compensation of
nonprofit managers is necessary to establish the public trust needed for consistent donations, to
maintain the nonprofit’s tax-exempt status, and to reward the leaders who drive the success of
the organization. In the face of six- and seven- figure salaries at many of America’s largest
nonprofit institutions, what constitutes appropriate compensation is not an easy question to
answer. With watchdog groups criticizing organizations whose CEOs make over $1 million, the
State of New York punishing nonprofits who pay any employee over $199,000, and the
Massachusetts Attorney General concerned about nonprofit CEOs earning over half a million,
calls for oversight tend to be accompanied by an arbitrary numerical figure for what level of
compensation is appropriate.
Conversely, the compensation packages awarded to executives at the largest charities are
anything but arbitrary. They are the output of highly complex processes, often involving a
variety of input variables, a team of outside consultants, benchmarking exercises, compensation
committees, and a thorough evaluation of the executive’s performance in key areas. Nonprofit
organizations are required to disclose the resources they use to determine executive
compensation in their tax returns, and often go above-and-beyond this call by further detailing
their compensation policies on their websites.
Yet, cries for lower compensation attack the total compensation figure rather than the
well-documented process used to arrive at that number. Furthermore, the debate ignores the mix
of components that comprise an executive pay. Existing literature discusses how executive pay is
associated with other financial measures, most notably organizational size as measured by assets
4
or annual program expenses. Additionally, many studies attempt to explain the gap between
executive compensation at for-profit and nonprofit organizations (Drucker 1990, Oster 1998).
Though certainly useful insight, neither body of research gives credence to the arguments of
those individuals and governments calling for lower executive compensation or to the charities
that award their CEOs with compensation others deem to be unreasonable. This paper will begin
to reconcile the gap between the cries for lower pay in charitable organizations and the variables
the previous literature has found to be associated with higher compensation by examining how
specific pay determination practices used by charitable organizations are associated with total
compensation.
The national debate over nonprofit compensation must expand beyond a narrow focus on
total CEO pay to a conversation about the practices nonprofit organizations employ to determine
how their leaders are rewarded for their work. The aim of this research is to provide insight into
how executive compensation is determined, and what influence compensation consultants and
contracts may have on top executive pay. This paper will proceed in six steps. First, it will
provide a brief summary of the American nonprofit context, including the requirements
governing CEO pay. Next, it will provide a literature review of the current body of research on
nonprofit executive compensation. Third, it will provide the hypotheses of this study. Fourth, it
will explain the methodology I employed to test the hypotheses. The fifth section will describe
the results, and the sixth section will conclude with a summary of findings and suggestions for
further research.
5
Section I - The American Nonprofit Context
Nonprofits are a fundamental part of the American tradition and emerge from the free
market to meet societal needs that go unaddressed by the state. Frumkin and Keating write, “the
nonprofit organizational form allows society to overcome market failures and to increase the
output of certain goods and services, without moving to direct government provision or the
provision of subsidies to for-profit firms” (Frumkin 2011, 3). By reducing the need for state
subsidies and in-kind transfers in a variety of areas, nonprofits lift a great burden from the
government.
The nonprofit sector is growing at a rapid pace, with a 25% increase in the number of
organizations from 2001 to 2011. In 2010, nonprofits accounted for 5.4% of Gross Domestic
Product and 10% of total employment. The rate of growth in this $779 billion industry has
surpassed that of the private sector (Roeger, Blackwood, Pettijohn 2012). In exchange for
taking on this burden of creating greater societal welfare, nonprofits are granted two key tax
benefits. First, nonprofits are provided with exemptions from income, sales, and property taxes.
This indirectly subsidizes the activity of the nonprofits, thus allowing them to achieve greater
output at a lower cost. Second, nonprofits can offer their donors tax deductions for their
charitable gifts. This encourages the public to donate to charitable organizations by allowing
them to deduct the dollars they donate from their taxable income. Both of these tax benefits are
help nonprofits achieve their mission.
Because tax exemption enables nonprofits to undercut for-profit firms’ prices for the
same activity, one might ask why all firms don’t operate as nonprofits. To quality for tax exempt
status, organizations must meet the eligibility requirements set out in Section 501(c) of the tax
6
code and consent to certain governance requirements. While some industries, such as religious
organizations, are almost entirely comprised of nonprofit organizations, in other industries, such
as healthcare, nonprofit organizations and for-profit companies exist side-by-side. The IRS
governance requirements allow nonprofits to increase social welfare by increasing the production
of certain goods and services without encroaching on the free-market by subsidizing for-profit
firms, while regulating them enough to ensure that they are not abusing the tax advantages they
receive.
Eligibility Requirements
Section 501(c) broadly defines nonprofits as organized for “charitable, religious,
educational, scientific, or other purposes.” Nonprofit organizations exceeding $25,000 in annual
revenue are required to file a Form 990 with the IRS. This publicly available document discloses
information from the nonprofit’s financial statements and includes additional schedule filings for
certain designations of nonprofits. The IRS has 29 classifications for nonprofits, with the far
most popular classification being 501c(3).
A 501c(3) nonprofit is one whose purpose is “Religious, Educational, Charitable,
Scientific, Literary, Testing for Public Safety, to Foster National or International Amateur Sports
Competition, or Prevention of Cruelty to Children or Animals Organizations” (Internal Revenue
Service 501c3 guidelines). These organizations tend to align with the classical interpretation of
the word “charity,” in a way other tax-exempt designations, such as labor unions and sports
clubs, do not. 501c(3) organizations are public-serving rather than member-serving, and typically
rely on grants from the government and donations from the public to succeed.
While the IRS code gives broad definitions of nonprofits, Salamon’s research described
six characteristics that define America nonprofits (1996). First, these organizations are formally
7
constituted to fulfill an established mission. Nonprofits typically have a public mission
statement, outlining the organization’s broad objectives and purpose. Second, nonprofits are
private institutions not operated by the government. While some nonprofits rely heavily on
government grants for support, managers of the organization are unaffiliated with the state.
Third, nonprofits are not created to generate wealth for their owners. The non-distribution
constraint designed for maintaining this principle will be described in the “governance
requirements” section. Fourth, nonprofits are self-governing and maintain full control over their
activities, so long as they meet the standards set forth by the IRS code. Fifth, nonprofits are
voluntary in nature. Their activity is not compelled by the government or any other entity.
Finally, nonprofits are designed to serve the public interest. They are organized to, in some way,
“do good” (Salamon 1996).
Governance Requirements
With managerial performance difficult to measure and a noncompetitive operating
environment, nonprofit executives have potential for corruption. Several legal mechanisms exist
to regulate pay and discourage poor managerial behavior, including the non-distribution
constraint and the “reasonable but not excessive” compensation requirement. A failure to meet
these governance standards can result in sanctions, the most extreme being revocation of the
organization’s tax-exempt status.
The Non-Distribution Constraint. Executive compensation in for-profit companies
typically reflects the financial performance of the firm. The promise of increased bonuses
incentivizes executives to cut costs wherever possible and run the business with a clear focus on
the bottom line. In turn, higher profits create higher earnings for shareholders and higher
compensation for executives – a “win-win” situation for investors and managers (Frumkin 2011).
8
There is a fundamental problem with this approach applied to nonprofit executives. A
narrow focus on financial metrics is inappropriate to reward nonprofit management, because the
mission of a nonprofit is to fulfill a societal need rather than generate profit. Hansmann notes
that nonprofits are not barred from earning profits, so long as those profits are invested in the
social mission of the organization rather than distributed executives. He calls this restriction the
“non-distribution constraint” (Hansmann 1980, 835). The non-distribution constraint does not
prevent nonprofit employees from receiving pay or receiving incentive compensation, it simply
prohibits the distribution of net earnings to those in charge (Hansmann 1980).
The non-distribution constraint ensures that nonprofits’ excess earnings will be retained
and used to provide future services, rather than distributed to managers. This measure
discourages leaders from cutting program costs for the sake of higher compensation, as Boards
avoid tying executive rewards to the financial performance of the organization. The constraint
also underscores the importance of appropriating funds to the social mission of the organization,
rather than diverting them for personal gain. This is important for two groups: the government,
who as previously discussed essentially subsidizes the operations of the organizations in the form
of tax-exemptions, and the public. Donors and others who pay for the services that the
organizations provide expect their contributions to be used for the services, not the leaders’
paychecks.
Reasonable but not excessive compensation. While nonprofits are prohibited from
distributing excess revenue to executives, managers are not expected to work without pay. The
IRS recognizes the importance of competitive compensation in attracting and retaining talent to
lead nonprofits, and thus actively encourages compensation committees to reward executives
9
with “reasonable” compensation, without paying excessively. The IRS defines excessive
compensation as compensation that “exceeds what is reasonable under all of the circumstances.”
While this vague yardstick of what constitutes reasonable provides little guidance for
determining executive pay, the IRS lists several mechanisms for determining executive pay on
Form 990. As of 2008, filing organizations must disclose which of the following six mechanisms
it employed to establish the compensation of its CEO or Executive Director: compensation
committees, independent compensation consultants, Form 990s of other organizations, written
employment contracts, compensation surveys or studies, and approval by the board or
compensation committee. Though organizations are not legally required to use any of these
methods of determining CEO compensation, a clearly defined process for how pay is determined
may reduce the possibility of an IRS investigation of the organization’s pay practices.
Management scholars debate the question of what compensation is reasonable for
nonprofit executives. Compensation studies consistently show nonprofit employees earn less
than their counterparts in similar positions in for-profit firms (Ruhm and Barokski 2000).
Some scholars suggest that paying nonprofit managers levels of pay similar to those at for-profit
firms would create a conflict of interest. They theorize that nonprofit executives engage in “labor
donations,” forgoing the higher pay in the for-profit sector for the sake of doing good through
nonprofit employment (Rose-Ackerman 1986, Preston 1989). Other scholars contend that lower
pay is necessary in the nonprofit sector to deter managers whose biggest concerns are monetary
Rewards from seeking employment there (Hansmann 1980). In both cases, researchers advocate
for the continuation of lower pay for nonprofit managers on the premise that executives who run
organizations seeking non-monetary outcomes knowingly consent to lower pay than those who
do not.
10
On the contrary, other scholars contend that it is imperative for nonprofit executives to
earn similar pay to individuals in similar roles in for-profit firms (Drucker 1990). They argue that
the success of a nonprofit hinges on its ability to attract and retain top quality managers who are
willing to bear the uncertainties of working at a nonprofit, such as inconsistent funding and often
difficult to measure outcomes. The social orientation of nonprofit organizations does not
eliminate the demanding nature of managing a complex organization, and thus it shouldn’t solely
govern how much nonprofit mangers earn (Letts, Ryan, and Grossman 1999).
Determining a level of executive compensation that is reasonable but not excessive
proves to be yet another challenge facing nonprofit organizations. With limited guidance on how
reasonable is defined, there is an extra burden on boards to provide a thorough, transparent, and
honorable process for determining managerial pay.
Sanctions. In addition to losing public trust, nonprofits that violate the non-distribution
constraint or offer excessive executive compensation packages face legal sanctions. Until 2002,
the only punitive measure for inappropriate compensation available to the IRS was a complete
revocation of the organization’s tax-exempt status. The IRS seldom employed this drastic
measure, as proving a violation was extremely difficult given the vague nature of the rules. More
recently, the IRS adopted a less threatening punitive measure: an excise tax. Rather than
revoking a nonprofit’s tax-exempt status, the tax serves as an intermediate sanction for
nonprofits found to violate the legal restrictions governing executive compensation. Executives
of organizations found to pay excessive compensation must forfeit the portion of their pay ruled
excessive in addition to a 25% excise tax on the amount. Oversight boards who approved the
executive compensation must also pay a penalty (Internal Revenue Service 501c policies).
11
Though enforcement action is still rare, several nonprofits are sanctioned each year with this
relatively moderate penalty.
12
Section II – Literature Review
Carroll, Hughes, and Luksetich note, “literature concerned with the determinants of
executive compensation in the nonprofit sector pales in comparison to the quantity and depth of
the theoretical and empirical research in the for-profit sector of the economy” (2005, 19). While
much remains unknown about executive compensation at nonprofits, previous research has made
significant headway in answering many of the common questions about nonprofit pay practices.
This review will outline the existing research in the arena of nonprofit compensation and will
contain five parts. First, it will discuss some of the variables correlated with executive pay,
specifically focusing on organizational size and IRS classification. Second, it will summarize the
possible explanations for year-to-year changes in CEO pay presented by prior management
research. Next, it will elaborate on the difficulties of implementing pay-for-performance systems
in the nonprofit setting and the metrics of performance used by nonprofits that do offer
performance pay. Fourth, it will touch upon the wage gap between nonprofits and for-profit
companies. Finally, it will discuss the limitations that a lack of quality nonprofit data has
imposed upon prior research. This body of literature informs the research hypotheses in the
following section.
Predictors of Nonprofit CEO Pay
Previous research has identified associations between organizational size, IRS
classification, and executive pay. A more recent study has identified a link between free cash
flows and CEO pay as well.
1. Organizational Size
13
The most tried-and-true predictor of CEO pay in nonprofits is organizational size.
Murphy (1998) notes that larger organizations require leaders capable of more complex tasks and
exercising control over more operations, thus organizational size is a proxy for managerial skill.
The most commonly used measures of organizational size in previous nonprofit compensation
studies are total fixed assets and total program expenses. Hallock used total assets and log of
total assets as a proxy for size, noting that an organization’s assets are typically linked to its
operations (2000). Frumkin and Keating (2011) argue that it is necessary to use both total assets
and total program expenses as proxies for organizational size. Total program expenses exclude
fundraising and administrative costs, measuring only the expenses related to the specific
mission-related activity of the nonprofit. They note that boards of directors at nonprofits
generally set CEO compensation based on annual budgets and scale of operations compared to
industry peers, and total program expenses are an appropriate representation of annual budget
(Frumkin and Keating 2011).
Regardless of the measure of size, the results have consistently demonstrated that CEOs
of larger organizations receive larger paychecks. Nonprofit compensation studies consistently
show a link between organization size and executive compensation (Oster 1998, Hallock 2000).
In a study of CEO compensation at 6,590 nonprofits, Frumkin and Keating found increases in
CEO pay by $0.25 and $0.07 for each additional thousand dollars in fixed assets and program
expenses, respectively (2011). Similarly, Hallock found increases of $0.10 in pay for every
thousand dollars of fixed assets (2000).
While these studies were not limited to 501(c)(3) organizations, a 2013 Charity Navigator
CEO Compensation Study confirmed that the trend of larger organizations offering higher CEO
pay is evident within the context of charities as well. This study examined CEO pay at 3,929
14
mid- to large-sized charities, and found that the median compensation earned was $125,942 in
2011. The median compensation varied substantially with organization size, however; large
charities with more than $13.5 million in expenses paid median CEO compensation of $244,209,
medium-sized organizations with between $3.5 million and $13.5 million in expenses paid
median CEO compensation of $145,230, and smaller organizations paid median compensation of
$95,661. There were also clear distinctions in pay among the charities based on size, with the
largest charities of over $500 million in annual expenses paying their CEOs a median salary of
$422,578 (Frumkin and Keating, 2011).
While program expenses, total expenses, and fixed assets may serve as proxies for
organizational size, the measures can be misleading when used to represent the impact of the
organization. For example, consider a nonprofit that provides free malaria vaccinations to
children. Changes such as increased volunteer labor or lower costs of vaccination and travel can
allow the nonprofit to increase its impact without increasing its program spending or assets. The
relationship between expenses or assets and the scope of the organization’s activities is not
always clear, and thus one must be careful when using these measures to evaluate the efficacy of
a nonprofit or its executives.
2. IRS Classifications
As previously mentioned, nonprofits are classified by the IRS based on the nature of their
activities. Several studies explore the differences in executive compensation practices based on
their IRS classifications. Frumkin and Keating note that industry-specific regressions have much
greater explanatory power than those that seek to explain executive compensation in all
nonprofits (2001); certain variables carry more weight in particular subsectors. In all sub-sectors
except religious nonprofits, Frumkin and Keating found nonprofit CEOs typically are paid a
15
substantial fixed component independent of variables such as programs or assets. This amount
varied across the subsectors, with the lowest found in arts organizations at $81,139.98 and
highest in healthcare organizations at $151,477.30. The arts and human services sub-sectors are
unique in that CEO compensation is more closely linked to an organization’s fixed assets. Their
study found increases in pay of $1.29 and $0.50 for each additional thousand dollars of fixed
assets in arts and human services nonprofits, respectively. Significant relationships between
fixed assets and CEO pay were not found in the education, health, religious, or “other” sub-
sectors (Frumkin and Keating 2011).
The arts, education, health, religious, and “other” classifications of nonprofits exhibited
no statistically significant association between changes in CEO pay and changes in dollar growth
in contributions (Frumkin and Keating 2011). As changes in contributions are typically a
considered to be a performance measure for nonprofits, this suggests a weak performance-pay
relationship.
Similarly, the 2013 Charity Navigator study showed median salaries to be drastically
different across IRS classifications. Education had the highest median total compensation at
$170,178, followed by Arts at $159,650, and Health at 137,919 (2013 CEO Compensation
Study). As indicated by Frumkin and Keating’s research, religious charities compensate
significantly less than other nonprofits, with a median CEO package of $82,746 (2011).
3. Free Cash Flows
Keating and Frumkin introduced the free cash flow hypothesis, which speculates that
CEO compensation will be higher in nonprofits that have relatively more free cash flows
available. They note, “unrestricted funds within organizations give nonprofit boards the ability to
use “free cash” for non-essential and non-budget items, including increased salaries and benefits
16
for senior staff’ (2001, 14). There are several reasons why a nonprofit might have unrestricted
funds available, including commercial revenue not subject to donor oversight, income from an
endowment, or undesignated donations. Two of these variables were found to have a significant
relationship to CEO pay (2001, 21). For organizations that receive unrestricted funds through
commercial revenues, a 1% increase in commercial revenue share was associated with a $600
increase in CEO pay. Similarly, organizations with higher endowment-related income had higher
CEO pay.
Changes in Pay from Year to Year
Baber, Daniel, and Roberts studied the way changes in various accounting measures
frequently reported publicly by charity oversight agencies are related to the compensation of
CEOs at charitable organizations. They note that such agencies are typically concerned with
changes in program spending, revenue, and relative costs of administering the charity. They
hypothesized that changes in each of these three performance measures would be positively
related to changes in executive compensation, and tested their hypothesis using a sample of 331
Maryland-based charities (1999).
Their study showed significant relationship CEO Compensation and these performance
metrics. For instance, a 10% increase in annual revenues was associated with a 0.9% increase in
total compensation for the CEO. Additionally, increasing program spending by 10% was
associated with a 0.76% additional compensation for the CEO (Baber 688). The increase in CEO
compensation that was not associated with either changes in revenues or changes in program
spending was 5.8%. These data suggest that changes in performance measures from year to year
may have some bearing on CEO pay (Baber, Daniel, Roberts 1999).
17
The Baber, Daniel, and Roberts’ study also notes that charities are inclined to report a
breakeven condition whenever possible, as charities with excess revenue may appear overfunded
and charities operating on a deficit may appear irresponsible; salaries are a discretionary expense
item that can be raised if a charity is not already at or below its breakeven point (1999, 691).
These adjustments may account for some year-to-year changes in CEO compensation.
Pay-for-Performance
Pay-for-performance systems dominate executive compensation structures in for-profit
companies, yet are still rare in the nonprofit setting. Steinberg notes that while incentive
contracts are not entirely prohibited by the non-distribution constraint, some pay-for-
performance metrics may compromise donor trust by creating a perception that their
contributions are diverted away from the organization’s purpose in favor of higher executive
compensation (Steinberg 1990). For instance, consider a CEO who receives a percentage of
funds raised at a fundraiser. Even if that percentage is small, it has the effect of increasing the
amount that donors need to give to have the same effect on output of the organizations services
(Carroll 20). This may make it more difficult for nonprofits to attract donations.
Despite this difficulty, many nonprofit organizations use incentive pay systems to reward
managers. Pynes notes that there are innovative approaches to nonprofit pay-for-performance
that run less risk of compromising donor trust. She suggests broad banding pay structures to
allow for more lateral growth within one’s pay grade, in addition to skill-based pay, merit pay,
and gainsharing (Pynes 1997). Other researchers have noted the importance of performance-
based pay systems to create risk-sharing among executives and the firms they manage (Rose-
Ackerman 1986).
18
Nonprofit For-Profit Wage Gap
Though the wage gap between for-profit and nonprofit organizations is not a primary
concern of this paper, the theoretical explanations for the difference inform our understanding of
nonprofit executive compensation and thus deserve brief attention here. As Hallock outlines,
there are four dominant theoretical reasons for the gap (2000). First, nonprofit employees engage
in labor donations. This means they knowingly accept a wage lower than what their skill,
education, and experience would command in the for-profit sector and essentially donate the
difference to the organization (Preston 1989). The second explanation is that nonprofit workers
accept lower pay in exchange for more favorable working conditions, such as more flexible
hours or job stability. This concept is known as compensating wage differentials. The third
explanation deals with the efficiency-wage hypothesis, and holds that workers whose outcomes
are difficult to measure are paid more than their market value and work must work hard to
maintain their position to avoid losing their jobs and having to accept a lower paying position.
The final explanation is that those who accept nonprofit positions may have skills that would be
more useful in another sector (Hallock 2000).
Limitations of Existing Research
While previous research has made substantial headway in uncovering the determinants of
nonprofit CEO pay, researchers encounter common roadblocks when attempting to study this
phenomenon. First, a lack of accurate data plagues the nonproft research community. Though
recent changes to the Form 990 have required nonprofits to disclose the compensation of their
top five most highly-paid officers more clearly, prior to 2007 the data were reported without a
corresponding name. This made it difficult to determine whether or not the CEO changed from
year to year. Similarly, the breadth of objectives of nonprofits makes it extremely difficult to
19
compare one nonprofit’s goals to another’s goals. Because a variety of non-accounting metrics
may be employed to determine executive compensation, comparisons from organization to
organization are difficult.
20
Section III - Research Hypotheses
With the unique context constraints and requirements in mind, I examine the processes
used to determine executive compensation at the largest American charities. I take a different
approach than the recent literature, focusing less on the outcome of pay itself and more on the
methods employed to reach that outcome. I evaluate the role of organizational size, as well as
the influence of compensation consultants and employment contracts in determining executive
pay.
A. Organizational Size
As previously discussed, a great deal of prior research shows an association between a
nonprofit organization’s assets and the pay of its CEO (Oster 1980, Hallock 2000, Frumkin and
Keating 2011). The prevalence of this finding is consistent with the notion that CEOs managing
larger, more complex organizations earn more than those who manage smaller ones. Because the
scope of operations of nonprofit organizations are difficult to compare and other proxies for
organizational size used in the for-profit setting such as market share and gross revenue are less
relevant to nonprofits, assets is the most reliable proxy for organizational size.
I expect that this finding will hold true even among our sample of the largest organizations, and
as such:
H1: Larger organizations will offer higher total pay to their CEOs.
B. Compensation Consultants
Given the dearth of research on the use of compensation consultants in the nonprofit
sector, my hypothesis is informed largely by associations confirmed in studies of for-profit firms.
Employing outside consultants to determine executive pay has been repeatedly associated with
21
higher compensation in the for-profit sector. Executive compensation expert Graef Crystal said
in 1991:
Executive compensation in the United States did not go out of control simply
through some random process; it went out of control because of the actions – or
inactions – of a number of parties. The first cultprits in what will be a litany of
culprits are compensation consultants (Conyon 401).
A number of studies have confirmed his assertion, showing CEO compensation is higher in firms
utilizing compensation consultants to set executive pay (Conyon 2011; Armstrong, Ittner,
Larcker 2012). A study of 755 large U.S. corporations found significant increases in CEO total
pay in organizations where consultants designed the compensation packages (Cadman, Carter,
Hillegeist 263). Given the similarity of the roles of consultants in the for-profit and nonprofit
setting, I expect these findings will hold true with charities, and therefore propose:
H2: Nonprofit organizations who use compensation consultants will have higher
paid CEOs.
C. Employment Contracts
The use of employment contracts for CEOs of both nonprofit and for-profit firms is
somewhat controversial. Zhao elaborates on the ways in which a CEO is protected by a contract.
Her job is secure until his contract expires, enabling her to pursue higher risk opportunities. She
is also guaranteed certain compensation, has quantifiable measures of performance, and is
granted generous change-in-control provisions. Yet, these contracts can also be very
entrenching, making it difficult to make large annual adjustments when necessary (Zhao 2005).
Lund and Polsky argue that CEO employment contracts laced with incentive pay actually have
diminishing returns and that firms should reconsider the extent to which their compensation
packages emphasize specific performance measures (2011). Specifically, they note that
22
incentives tied to particular accounting measures are ineffective when outcomes are difficult to
measure. Despite these limitations, contracts typically provide some level of guaranteed reward
compensation (2011, 683-4).
Because contracts usually ensure CEOs some automatic reward compensation in addition
to performance-based incentives, I posit:
H3: Charity CEOs with employment contracts receive higher total pay.
23
Section IV – Method
A. Sample Population
The organizations chosen for the sample are those which appeared in Forbes Magazine’s
annual list of the largest 200 American charities as measured by total assets for the years 2008,
2009, 2010, and 2011. The data Forbes uses to compile the annual list come from the National
Center for Charitable Statistics. Though Forbes always employs the same methodology for
determining its annual list, the organizations that make the cut vary substantially each year. A
one-time grant or campaign can lead assets to spike in one fiscal year, securing an organization a
spot on the list for that year but not the next. Only the 115 organizations that appeared on the list
for each of the four consecutive years were included in the sample, because the focus of this
study is charitable organizations who were consistently among the largest throughout the period
of interest.
I chose to use the organizations listed by Forbes because these are the nonprofits that
have the closest ties to the general public. Compensation practices at the organizations the public
subsidizes, through both taxpayer-funded government grants and private donations, carry the
most weight on how the public thinks about charity compensation. There are two notable
exclusions that Forbes makes when compiling the list, which make it an optimal group for this
study. First, large charitable organizations that do not solicit donations from the public or grants
from the government are not included in the group. Consider for example the Bill and Melinda
Gates Foundation, which is funded primarily through the assets of a single family. Second,
organizations that primarily solicit donations and grants from individuals who have received
their services in some capacity are excluded from the group. This exclusion is important because
24
it eliminates institutions whose primary donor base is not the general public, such as colleges and
universities who primarily solicit donations from alumni. A complete list of the organizations
used in the sample and the number of observations from each organization can be found in the
Appendix.
B. Data Collection
Each organization is required to file a Form 990 tax return each year, and the returns are
subsequently made publicly available. Returns were retrieved from each organization for the
years 2008, 2009, 2010, and 2011. Most of the returns were available on the organizations’
websites or nonprofit charity rating agencies such as GuideStar and Charity Navigator. In a few
rare cases, the organization’s controller provided the returns electronically directly from the
charity.
I obtained data from the Form 990 for the organization’s total revenue, total expenses,
total salaries & benefits expenses, total fundraising expenses, assets and liabilities for each year.
I also recorded the Schedule J disclosure of which of the following resources the organization
used to set CEO pay: compensation committee, independent consultants, other organizations’
Form 990s, an employment contract, a study or survey, and/or approval by the board of directors.
I also recorded the name, base compensation, bonus and incentive pay, other reportable
compensation, retirement and deferred compensation, nontaxable benefits, and total
compensation of each CEO. In a few cases, I was unable to obtain copies of the organizations’
tax returns, leaving 441 usable observations.
C. Testing the Hypotheses
To test the first hypothesis, I used log of total assets as a proxy for organizational size,
consistent with previous research (Hallock 2000). I also considered the log of the number of
25
employees as a second proxy for organizational size. I regress log of total pay accounting on logs
of assets and employees. To test the second hypothesis, I add the independent variable for
whether or not the organization used a consultant. This shows whether the addition of a
consultant has any association with executive pay. Similarly, I test the third hypothesis using the
independent variable of whether or not the CEO was under contract. This shows whether
association exists between employment contracts and CEO pay. All calculations were performed
using STATA 13.0.
26
Section V – Results and Discussion
Table 1
Summary Statistics on Charity CEO Compensation (in thousand USD)
Component Observations Mean
Std.
Dev. Min
25th
Percentile Median
75th
Percentile Max
Base 441 384 298 19 224 337 451 3208
Bonus 441 62 197 0 0 0 50 1950
Other Pay 441 93 419 0 0 10 45 7087
Retirement 441 64 188 0 5 80 42 2076
Nontaxable
Benefits 0 27 22 1 8 22 39 74
Total Pay 441 629 758 80 282 427 635 9185
Organizational Size
I found no significant association between the log of assets and the log of CEO total pay
in this population, contrary to the findings of several other nonprofit compensation studies
(Hallock 2000, Oster 1980). One reason why this might be the case is that the sample in this
study consists exclusively of the largest organizations by asset volume. It is possible that asset
levels are associated with CEO pay when assets range from the levels of mid-sized organizations
to the levels of large organizations, but that this affect disappears after a certain threshold has
been reached.
27
Figure 1.
Pay and Assets
Another proxy for organizational size, the log of the number of employees, did show a
significant association with increased executive compensation. This measure has not traditionally
appeared in compensation literature, but may be particularly important in the non-profit setting
where financial metrics take a backseat to the social orientation of the organization. At charitable
organizations, the complexity of a CEO’s position may be more closely associated with the
number of people he manages rather than the organization’s assets, thus organizational size as
measured by number of employees is a more reliable predictor of CEO pay.
Figure 2.
Pay and Employees
28
Consultants
I found that total CEO pay was significantly higher in organizations that used
compensation consultants to set pay for their top executive. Organizations who hired consultants
offered mean total pay of $773,207 compared to $363,481 in organizations that did not use
consultants (p <0.001). Interestingly, there was a statistically significant difference in each of the
individual compensation components that make-up total pay, with the exception of nontaxable
compensation. Though base compensation is still the largest component of total pay for
organizations that use consultants and organizations that do not, bonus pay, other reportable
compensation, and retirement compensation was significantly higher in the organizations that
used consultants. CEO pay packages offered by organizations that employed consultants tend to
more closely mirror those offered by for-profit firms, with bonus compensation and other
reportable compensation comprising a very significant portion of total pay.
Table 2.
Mean Compensation in Thousands by whether a Consultant is used
Mean Consultant No Consultant p-value
Base 384 446 272 0.000
Bonus 62.4 84.4 22.2 0.001
Other Comp 92.8 132 20.3 0.007
Retirement Comp 63.8 84.6 25.7 0.002
Nontaxable Benefits 25.6 27.4 26.0 0.528
Total Pay 629 774 363 0.001
N 441 285 156
Given the significant gap in pay in organizations that use consultants relative to those that
do not, it is necessary to investigate possible differences between the two groups of
organizations. There was no significant difference in the assets of organizations that used
consultants and the assets of those who did not. However, the mean number of employees at an
29
organization that used a consultant was 2,378 compared to only 947 at organizations that did not
(p < 0.005). Because we already know a positive correlation exists between total compensation
and number of employees, we regress the log of total pay on the log of assets and the log of
employees as an indication of whether using a consultant would still be associated with higher
pay all else held constant. In Table 3, we see that using a consultant is still associated with higher
total pay controlling for organizational size as measured by assets or employees. This is
consistent with H2.
Table 3
Log of Total Pay Regression accounting for use of a consultant,
assets, and employees.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Consultant 0.69*** 0.55*** 0.55*** 0.11
(0.07) (0.06) (0.06) (0.09)
Log of Assets -0.10*** -0.10*** 0.02
(0.02) (0.03) (0.03)
Log of Employees 0.18*** 0.18*** 0.08*
(0.02) (0.02) (0.03)
Constant 5.67*** 5.13*** 5.12*** 5.41***
(0.05) (0.19) (0.20) (0.26)
R2
0.1946 0.3988 0.4 0.86
Time Indicators NO NO YES YES
Organization Indicators NO NO NO YES
N 441 441 441 441
Note: *** significant at 0.01, ** significant at 0.05, * significant at 0.10.
Standard errors in italics.
I also investigated the year-to-year pay differences in the organizations that reported
using a compensation consultant in some years but not in others. At the individual organization
level, there was no significant difference in pay from year-to-year associated with using a
30
compensation consultant in some years but not others. It is important to note, however, that the
Form 990 does not make it clear whether or not an organization must indicate that it has used a
compensation consultant if the consultant designed the compensation package currently used in
another tax year. Using a compensation consultant to design a plan in one year can have an
impact on other years as well, and thus the stability of pay in years in which an organization did
not use a consultant is unsurprising.
The coefficient on the indicator variable for whether the organization used a consultant is
0.55, indicating that controlling for other characteristics, organizations using a consultant pay top
managers 55% more than those that don’t. This seems large and is worthy of additional
consideration. Note, however, that if we control for the organizational indicator variable, there is
no significant difference in pay for CEOs in years that their pay is determined by compensation
consultants relative to years where it is not. This may be misleading, however, because IRS
instructions do not indicate whether or not using a multiple year compensation plan designed by
a consultant in a prior year requires the organization to disclose that it used a consultant on the
Schedule J. It is possible that the effects of using a consultant in one year spill over into
following years.
Contracts
Though not as large as the effect of consultants, employment contracts were also
associated with higher CEO pay. The mean CEO total pay in organizations using employment
contracts was $790,289 versus $517,645 in those who did not (p < 0.001). As Table 3 shows,
there were significant differences in base compensation, bonus compensation, and other
reportable compensation associated with the use of employment contracts.
31
Table 4
Mean Compensation in Thousands on whether a Contract was used
Mean Contract No Contract p-value
Base 384.4 470 326 0.000
Bonus 62.4 90.0 43.4 0.014
Other Comp 92.8 147 55.1 0.023
Retirement Comp 63.8 53.4 71.0 0.334
Nontaxable Benefits 25.6 26.0 27.5 0.472
Total Pay 629 790 518 0.010
N 441 180 261
Once again, it is important to distinguish what other characteristics organizations who use
employment contracts are likely to have. As with those who use consultants, there was no
significant difference in the volume of assets held by organizations that use contracts and those
who did not. The average employee count, however, fell at 2,433 for organizations that used
employment contracts and 1,484 for organizations that did not (p < 0.05).
To discern whether employment contracts are associated with higher CEO pay, we
regress the log of total pay with respect the log of employee count, the log of assets, and an
indicator variable for whether a CEO employment contract was used. As Table 5 shows,
employment contracts are associated with higher executive pay (p < 0.001). Column (3) shows
that this association held true for the four-year sample period, but is mitigated when I control for
the changes in each individual organization as shown in Column (4). Note however that when I
control for the organization indicator variables, there is no significant difference in total pay in
years a contract was used and years no contract was used.
32
Table 5
Log of Total Pay Regression accounting for use of a contract,
assets, and employees.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Contract 0.37*** 0.35*** 0.35*** 0.05
(0.07) (0.06) (0.06) (0.03)
Log of Assets -0.08*** -0.08*** 0.02
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
Log of Employees 0.21*** 0.21*** 0.08*
(0.01) (0.01) (0.03)
Constant 5.96*** 5.07*** 5.07*** 5.44***
(0.04) (0.21) (0.22) (0.26)
R-squared 0.0605 0.3329 0.336 0.89
Time Indicators NO NO YES YES
Organization Indicators NO NO NO YES
N 441 441 441 441
Note: *** significant at 0.01, ** significant at 0.05, * significant at 0.10. Standard
errors in italics.
These findings are consistent with H3 and show that all other things equal, organizations
who use employment contracts tend to pay more among this sample population. The coefficient
on the indicator variable was 0.35 in Column (1), indicating that controlling for the number of
employees and assets, organizations that use employment contracts pay 35% more than those
that do not. As with the consulting indicator variable shown in Table 3, this is large and merits
additional research.
33
Section VI – Discussion and Concluding Remarks
Because of heightened media and watchdog group scrutiny, reasonable executive
compensation is of paramount importance in America’s largest charities. These organizations
must not only pay their CEOs compensation that meets the unique governance requirements of
the American nonprofit setting, but also compensation that is deemed reasonable in the eyes of
donors. Amidst these concerns, organizations must also offer compensation that is fair as to
retain high-performing executives.
The IRS began requiring nonprofit organizations to disclose the resources they use to
determine executive compensation in 2008, which gives us unique insight into what practices
charities use to determine the pay of their top officers. I have shown that there is a significant
association between the use of compensation consultants and higher CEO pay in the largest
American charities. Furthermore, I have shown that this relationship holds true even when
controlling for organizational size as measured by assets or number of employees. I have also
shown a significant relationship between the use of employment contracts and CEO pay. As with
consultants, this association holds true even when controlling for measures of organizational
size.
Like previous research on nonprofit compensation, this study was limited by a lack of
available data. Only the information provided on organization’s Form 990 tax returns was used
for our calculations, and all of these data were entered manually and is subject to human error.
Furthermore, a lack of clear instructions to nonprofits on what level of consultation requires
them to “check the box” for using a compensation consultant on the Form 990 may have led to
reporting inconsistencies among the sample population.
34
Further research is necessary to explain why the use of compensation consultants and
employment contracts is associated with higher CEO pay, and whether this association can be
explained by organizational differences other than organizational size. A formal analysis of the
practices used by consultants and provisions of nonprofit CEO employment contracts could help
explain why this association exists, and whether donors should perceive it as problematic. In
spite of these limitations, the results of this study help inform our understanding of pay in the
charitable sector. Compensation consultants and employment contracts tend to be associated with
higher CEO base salaries and bonuses and higher total pay in organizations that use these
resources.
We know that there is enormous pressure for nonprofit institutions to maintain public
trust. When the IRS began requiring charitable institutions to disclose which resources they used
to determine CEO compensation, organizations may have felt compelled to use all six of the
listed resources to signal to donors that they have a thorough executive compensation
determination process. Perhaps organizations that use all of the listed practices have more
capable managers and therefore pay more – or perhaps indicating the use of compensation
consultants and employment contracts should signal a red flag rather than reassurance for donors.
35
Appendix
Organization Name Observations
Alzheimer's Association 4
American Cancer Society 4
American Civil Liberties Union Foundati 4
American Diabetes Association 4
American Heart Association 4
American Kidney Fund 4
American Museum of Natural History 4
Art Institute of Chicago 4
Arthritis Foundation 4
Big Brothers Big Sisters of America 3
Billy Graham Evangelistic Association 4
Boy Scouts of America 4
Boys & Girls Clubs of America 4
Brother's Brother Foundation 4
CARE USA 4
Catholic Charities USA 4
Catholic Medical Mission Board 4
Catholic Relief Services 4
Children International 4
Children's Hospital of Chicago - Lurie 1
Children's Hospital of Philadelphia 4
Children's Memorial Hospital 3
Christian Aid Ministries 4
Christian Broadcasting Network 4
Christian Foundation for Children and A 4
City of Hope 4
Cleveland Clinic Foundation 4
Combined Jewish Philanthrophies 4
Compassion International 4
Conservation Fund 4
Conservation International Foundation 4
Covenant House 4
Cystic Fibrosis Foundation 4
Dana-Farber Cancer Institute 4
Direct Relief International 4
Disabled American Veterans 4
Doctors Without Borders USA 4
Ducks Unlimited 4
Easter Seals 4
36
Educational Media Foundation 4
Father Flanagan's Boys' Home 4
Feed the Children 4
Focus on the Family 4
Food for the Poor 4
Greater Chicago Food Depository 4
Habitat for Humanity International 4
Heart to Heart International 4
Humane Society of the United States 4
In Touch Ministries 4
InterVarsity Christian Fellowship 4
International Fellowship of Christians 4
International Medical Corps 4
JA Worldwide 4
Jewish Federation of Metropolitan Chica 4
Jewish Federation of Metropolitan Detro 4
Juvenile Diabetes Research Foundation 4
Kids in Distressed Situations 4
Kingsway Charities 4
Leukemia & Lymphoma Society 4
MAP International 4
Make-A-Wish Foundation of America 4
March of Dimes Foundation 4
Marine Toys for Tots Foundation 4
Matthew 25: Ministries 4
Mayo Clinic 4
Medical Teams International 4
Memorial Sloan-Kettering Cancer Center 4
Mercy Corps 4
Metropolitan Museum of Art 4
Metropolitan Opera Association 2
Mission to the World (PCA) 4
Mount Sinai School of Medicine and Hosp 4
Muscular Dystrophy Association 4
Museum of Fine Arts, Houston 4
Museum of Modern Art 4
National Audubon Society 4
National Cancer Coalition 4
National Multiple Sclerosis Society 4
National Public Radio 4
National Wildlife Federation 4
Natural Resources Defense Council 4
Nature Conservancy 4
37
New York Public Library 4
New York-Presbyterian Hospital 4
Operation Smile 4
PATH 4
Paralyzed Veterans of America 4
Planned Parenthood Federation of Americ 4
Project HOPE 4
Project Orbis International 4
Public Broadcasting Service 4
Robin Hood Foundation 4
Rotary Foundation of Rotary Internation 4
Samaritan's Purse 4
Scholarship America 4
Scripps Research Institute 4
Shriners Hospitals for Children 4
Smithsonian Institution 4
Special Olympics 4
Teach for America 4
Trinity Broadcasting Network 4
Trust for Public Land 4
UJA/Federation of New York 4
United Negro College Fund 4
United States Fund for UNICEF 3
United Way 4
Volunteers of America 4
WETA 4
World Vision 4
World Wildlife Fund 4
Wycliffe Bible Translators 4
YMCA 3
Young Life 4
Total observations 443
38
References
"2013 CEO Compensation Study." Charity Navigator. Charity Navigator, n.d. Web. 15 Nov.
2013.
<http://www.charitynavigator.org/__asset__/studies/2013_CEO_Compensation_Study_
Final.pdf>.
Armstrong, Christopher S., Christopher D. Ittner, and David F. Larcker. "Corporate governance,
compensation consultants, and CEO pay levels." Review of Accounting Studies 17.2
(2012): 322-351. Print.
Baber, W., L. Daniel, and A. Roberts. "Compensation to Executives of Eleemosynary
Organizations: An Empirical Study of the Role of Accounting Performance Measures ."
Working paper, George Washington University - (1999): 1-65. Print.
Balassiano, K., and S. M. Chandler. "The Emerging Role of Nonprofit Associations in Advocacy
and Public Policy: Trends, Issues, and Prospects." Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector
Quarterly 39.5 (2010): 946-955. Print.
Barakski, Carey, and Christopher Ruhm. "Compensation in the Nonprofit Sector." National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 7562 (2000): 2-45. Print.
Barrett, William. "America's 200 Largest Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 19 Nov. 2008.
Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/2008/11/19/americas-largest-charities-pf-
charities08-cx_wb_1119charity_land.html>.
Barrett, William. "America's 200 Largest U.S. Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 24 Nov.
2009. Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/2009/11/23/charitable-giving-gates-
foundation-personal-finance-charity-09-intro.html>.
Barrett, William. "America's 200 Largest Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 17 Nov. 2010.
39
Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/2010/11/16/forbes-charity-200-personal-
finance-philanthropy-200-largest-charities-charity-10-intro.html>.
Barrett, William. "The Largest U.S. Charities For 2012." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 8 Nov. 2012.
Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/sites/williampbarrett/2012/11/08/the-
largest-u-s-charities-for-2012/>.
Berresford, Susan V., and Susan Rose-Ackerman. "The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions.."
Political Science Quarterly 102.2 (1987): 348. Print.
Cadman, Brian, Mary Ellen Carter, and Stephen Hillegeist. "The incentives of compensation
consultants and CEO pay." Journal of Accounting and Economics 49.3 (2010): 263-280.
Print.
Carroll, Thomas, Patricia Hughes, and William Luksetich. "Managers of nonprofit organizations
are rewarded for performance." Nonprofit Management and Leadership 16.1 (2005): 19-
41. Print.
Conyon, Martin J., Simon I. Peck, and Graham V. Sadler. "Compensation Consultants and
Executive Pay: Evidence from the United States and the United Kingdom.." Academy of
Management Perspectives 23.1 (2009): 43-55. Print.
Conyon, Martin J., Simon I. Peck, and Graham V. Sadler. "New perspectives on the governance
of executive compensation: an examination of the role and effect of compensation
consultants." Journal of Management & Governance 15.1 (2011): 29-58. Print.
Drucker, Peter F.. Managing the non-profit organization: practices and principles. New York,
N.Y.: HarperCollins, 1990. Print.
Frumkin, Peter, and Elizabeth K. Keating. "The price of doing good: Executive compensation in
nonprofit organizations." Policy and Society 29.3 (2010): 269-282. Print.
40
Hallock, Kevin F.. "Managerial Pay and Governance in American Nonprofits." Industrial
Relations 41.3 (2002): 377-406. Print.
Hansmann, Henry. "The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise." The Yale Law Journal 89.5 (1980): 835-
901. Print.
Milofsky, Carl, Lester M. Salamon, and Helmut K. Anheier. "The Emerging Nonprofit Sector:
An Overview." Contemporary Sociology 27.1 (1998): 68. Print.
Murphy, K. “Executive Compensation.” In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds., Handbook
of Labor Economics Vol. 3. New York: North-Holland, 1998.
Oster, Sharon M. "Executive Compensation in the Nonprofit Sector." Nonprofit Management
and Leadership 8.3 (1998): 207-221. Print.
Preston, Anne E. "The Nonprofit Worker In A For-Profit World." Journal of Labor Economics
7.4 (1989): 438. Print.
Pynes, J. (1997a). Human resource management for public and nonprofit organizations. San
Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Roeger, Katie, Amy S. Blackwood, and Sarah L. Pettijohn. “The Nonprofit Alamanac 2012. The
Urban Institute. (2012). Print.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. "Altruistic nonprofit firms in competitive markets: The case of day-care
centers in the United States." Journal of Consumer Policy 9.3 (1986): 291-310. Print.
Salamon, Lester M. 1992. America’s NonproïŹt Sector. New York: The Foundation Center.
Steinberg, R., and B. H. Gray. ""The Role Of Nonprofit Enterprise" In 1993: Hansmann
Revisited." Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 22.4 (1993): 297-316. Print.
Steinberg, Richard. "Profits and incentive compensation in nonprofit firms." Nonprofit
Management and Leadership 1.2 (1990): 137-151. Print.
41
Strachan, Maxwell. "10 Insanely Overpaid Nonprofit Execs." The Huffington Post.
TheHuffingtonPost.com, 8 Apr. 2013. Web. 13 Mar. 2014.
<http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2013/04/08/10-insanely-overpaid-
nonp_n_3038162.html>.
"The 200 Largest U.S. Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 30 Nov. 2011. Web. 15 Mar. 2014.
<http://www.forbes.com/lists/2011/14/200-largest-us-charities-11.html>.
Wallack, Todd. "Massachusetts Attorney General raises questions about nonprofit executive pay
- Boston.com." Boston.com. The New York Times, 19 Dec. 2013. Web. 15 Mar. 2014.
<http://www.boston.com/news/local/massachusetts/2013/12/19/massachusetts-attorney-
general-raises-questions-about-nonprofit-executive-
pay/ZRRqAbMejcgxr05x0p790N/story.html>.
Young, Dennis R.. "An interview with Peter F. Drucker, Clark Professor of social science and
management, claremont graduate school: Part 2." Nonprofit Management and
Leadership 2.3 (1992): 295-301. Print.
Zhao, Jing. CEO Employment Contracts, Managerial Myopia and Corporate Acquisition
Decisions. N.p.: n.p., 2007. Print.

Weitere Àhnliche Inhalte

Was ist angesagt?

Casting a wider net report
Casting a wider net reportCasting a wider net report
Casting a wider net reportJustin Rico Oyola
 
Management of non profit organisation module1 uma k
Management of non profit organisation module1 uma kManagement of non profit organisation module1 uma k
Management of non profit organisation module1 uma kDr UMA K
 
Surviving Financial Distress1
Surviving Financial Distress1Surviving Financial Distress1
Surviving Financial Distress1mwerling
 
The business of social work - starting a non-profit
The business of social work - starting a non-profitThe business of social work - starting a non-profit
The business of social work - starting a non-profitALMA HERNANDEZ, JD, LMSW
 
Research paper (rd)
Research paper (rd)Research paper (rd)
Research paper (rd)EmilyDHorn
 
Partner Training: Nonprofit Industry
Partner Training: Nonprofit IndustryPartner Training: Nonprofit Industry
Partner Training: Nonprofit IndustryGrace Dunlap
 
Economic Downturn Effect on Fundraising
Economic Downturn Effect on FundraisingEconomic Downturn Effect on Fundraising
Economic Downturn Effect on FundraisingUniversity of Florida
 
2018 human trends rise of the social enterprise
2018 human trends rise of the social enterprise2018 human trends rise of the social enterprise
2018 human trends rise of the social enterpriseVALUES & SENSE
 
An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...
An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...
An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...The New School
 
ENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equality
ENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equalityENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equality
ENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equalityEric Roberson
 
Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)
Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)
Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)Dr. Ebele Mogo
 
Ash shrivastav the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...
Ash shrivastav   the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...Ash shrivastav   the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...
Ash shrivastav the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...LenaCharles3
 
Power of the PAC
Power of the PACPower of the PAC
Power of the PACJonah Ragsdale
 
Powerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall Morck
Powerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall MorckPowerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall Morck
Powerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall Morcknusbiz
 

Was ist angesagt? (20)

Casting a wider net report
Casting a wider net reportCasting a wider net report
Casting a wider net report
 
Management of non profit organisation module1 uma k
Management of non profit organisation module1 uma kManagement of non profit organisation module1 uma k
Management of non profit organisation module1 uma k
 
Surviving Financial Distress1
Surviving Financial Distress1Surviving Financial Distress1
Surviving Financial Distress1
 
At the Crossroads
At the CrossroadsAt the Crossroads
At the Crossroads
 
The business of social work - starting a non-profit
The business of social work - starting a non-profitThe business of social work - starting a non-profit
The business of social work - starting a non-profit
 
Research paper (rd)
Research paper (rd)Research paper (rd)
Research paper (rd)
 
Nonprofits & The Economy Results: Northern Palm
Nonprofits & The Economy Results: Northern Palm Nonprofits & The Economy Results: Northern Palm
Nonprofits & The Economy Results: Northern Palm
 
Partner Training: Nonprofit Industry
Partner Training: Nonprofit IndustryPartner Training: Nonprofit Industry
Partner Training: Nonprofit Industry
 
Hot Nonprofit Topics in 2013
Hot Nonprofit Topics in 2013Hot Nonprofit Topics in 2013
Hot Nonprofit Topics in 2013
 
Research Paper
Research PaperResearch Paper
Research Paper
 
Economic Downturn Effect on Fundraising
Economic Downturn Effect on FundraisingEconomic Downturn Effect on Fundraising
Economic Downturn Effect on Fundraising
 
Nonprofits & The Economy Survey: Overall Results
Nonprofits & The Economy Survey: Overall ResultsNonprofits & The Economy Survey: Overall Results
Nonprofits & The Economy Survey: Overall Results
 
2018 human trends rise of the social enterprise
2018 human trends rise of the social enterprise2018 human trends rise of the social enterprise
2018 human trends rise of the social enterprise
 
Non-Profit Management Presentation
Non-Profit Management PresentationNon-Profit Management Presentation
Non-Profit Management Presentation
 
An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...
An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...
An Introduction to Financing for Cooperatives, Social Enterprises, and Small ...
 
ENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equality
ENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equalityENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equality
ENG3317_Public_Relations_backgrounder_lgbt_workplace_equality
 
Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)
Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)
Creating and managing a non-profit ( A Presentation By Ebele Mogo, DrPH)
 
Ash shrivastav the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...
Ash shrivastav   the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...Ash shrivastav   the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...
Ash shrivastav the venture capitalist with a silicon valley solution for mi...
 
Power of the PAC
Power of the PACPower of the PAC
Power of the PAC
 
Powerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall Morck
Powerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall MorckPowerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall Morck
Powerful Independent Directors by Kathy Fogel, Liping Ma, and Randall Morck
 

Andere mochten auch

Adhesivo
AdhesivoAdhesivo
Adhesivocrisca1993
 
Tripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_Presentation
Tripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_PresentationTripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_Presentation
Tripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_PresentationJake Frasier
 
Practica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaez
Practica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaezPractica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaez
Practica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaezIE Simona Duque
 
New student orientation academic advising information
New student orientation   academic advising informationNew student orientation   academic advising information
New student orientation academic advising informationgrandpre
 
Arjun_Prathap_CV
Arjun_Prathap_CVArjun_Prathap_CV
Arjun_Prathap_CVArjun Prathap
 
Estrutura Interna da Terra
Estrutura Interna da TerraEstrutura Interna da Terra
Estrutura Interna da Terraivasantos
 
Valuation models for_pre-revenue_companies
Valuation models for_pre-revenue_companiesValuation models for_pre-revenue_companies
Valuation models for_pre-revenue_companiesjojee2k2
 
Mentoring and leading edge learning
Mentoring and leading edge learningMentoring and leading edge learning
Mentoring and leading edge learningAnn Rolfe
 
Class 18 f online
Class 18 f onlineClass 18 f online
Class 18 f onlinejordanlachance
 

Andere mochten auch (14)

Column_Margreeth-1
Column_Margreeth-1Column_Margreeth-1
Column_Margreeth-1
 
Doc2
Doc2Doc2
Doc2
 
Adhesivo
AdhesivoAdhesivo
Adhesivo
 
Tripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_Presentation
Tripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_PresentationTripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_Presentation
Tripsas_and_Frasier_MLS_Presentation
 
Ct 27 junio 2012
Ct 27 junio 2012Ct 27 junio 2012
Ct 27 junio 2012
 
Practica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaez
Practica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaezPractica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaez
Practica numero 3 mateo gomez pelaez
 
Company Resume
Company ResumeCompany Resume
Company Resume
 
New student orientation academic advising information
New student orientation   academic advising informationNew student orientation   academic advising information
New student orientation academic advising information
 
Arjun_Prathap_CV
Arjun_Prathap_CVArjun_Prathap_CV
Arjun_Prathap_CV
 
Estrutura Interna da Terra
Estrutura Interna da TerraEstrutura Interna da Terra
Estrutura Interna da Terra
 
Valuation models for_pre-revenue_companies
Valuation models for_pre-revenue_companiesValuation models for_pre-revenue_companies
Valuation models for_pre-revenue_companies
 
Mentoring and leading edge learning
Mentoring and leading edge learningMentoring and leading edge learning
Mentoring and leading edge learning
 
Class 18 f online
Class 18 f onlineClass 18 f online
Class 18 f online
 
1940s
1940s1940s
1940s
 

Ähnlich wie Reif Honors Thesis Revised

Not-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the Fire
Not-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the FireNot-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the Fire
Not-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the FireCBIZ, Inc.
 
Funding For Non-Profit Organizations
Funding For Non-Profit OrganizationsFunding For Non-Profit Organizations
Funding For Non-Profit OrganizationsCustomWrittenCollege
 
1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the Nonprof
1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the Nonprof1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the Nonprof
1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the NonprofAnastaciaShadelb
 
A Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs Illinois
A Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs IllinoisA Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs Illinois
A Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs Illinoisradarbutane60
 
Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...
Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...
Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...Kate Loge
 
Social Trends Report
Social Trends ReportSocial Trends Report
Social Trends ReportMeghan Brown
 
MGT 498_Ethics_Auge_Final
MGT 498_Ethics_Auge_FinalMGT 498_Ethics_Auge_Final
MGT 498_Ethics_Auge_FinalIan Auge, BSB/M
 
HR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docx
HR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docxHR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docx
HR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docxwellesleyterresa
 
Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3
Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3
Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3Anton Floor
 
Nonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docx
Nonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docxNonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docx
Nonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docxhenrymartin15260
 
Key Facts to Consider - Nonprofit Mergers
Key Facts to Consider - Nonprofit MergersKey Facts to Consider - Nonprofit Mergers
Key Facts to Consider - Nonprofit MergersPeterson Sullivan
 
April 2018 Newsletter
April 2018 NewsletterApril 2018 Newsletter
April 2018 Newslettertoddrobison
 
Nonprofit Trends (2)
Nonprofit  Trends (2)Nonprofit  Trends (2)
Nonprofit Trends (2)Kelley Nave
 
A460107.pdf
A460107.pdfA460107.pdf
A460107.pdfaijbm
 

Ähnlich wie Reif Honors Thesis Revised (14)

Not-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the Fire
Not-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the FireNot-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the Fire
Not-for-Profit Compensation Controversies Continue to Add Fuel to the Fire
 
Funding For Non-Profit Organizations
Funding For Non-Profit OrganizationsFunding For Non-Profit Organizations
Funding For Non-Profit Organizations
 
1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the Nonprof
1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the Nonprof1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the Nonprof
1Ethics and the Nonprofit March 2013Ethics and the Nonprof
 
A Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs Illinois
A Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs IllinoisA Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs Illinois
A Test Of Policies: Wisconsin Vs Illinois
 
Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...
Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...
Different Views Of The Comparison Between Non-Profit And...
 
Social Trends Report
Social Trends ReportSocial Trends Report
Social Trends Report
 
MGT 498_Ethics_Auge_Final
MGT 498_Ethics_Auge_FinalMGT 498_Ethics_Auge_Final
MGT 498_Ethics_Auge_Final
 
HR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docx
HR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docxHR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docx
HR, 3eAngelo S. DeNisi, Ricky W. GriffnThe amount of value.docx
 
Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3
Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3
Academic paper - Cause-related marketing V2.3
 
Nonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docx
Nonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docxNonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docx
Nonprofit Organization Revenue Origin MatrixBSHS373 Version.docx
 
Key Facts to Consider - Nonprofit Mergers
Key Facts to Consider - Nonprofit MergersKey Facts to Consider - Nonprofit Mergers
Key Facts to Consider - Nonprofit Mergers
 
April 2018 Newsletter
April 2018 NewsletterApril 2018 Newsletter
April 2018 Newsletter
 
Nonprofit Trends (2)
Nonprofit  Trends (2)Nonprofit  Trends (2)
Nonprofit Trends (2)
 
A460107.pdf
A460107.pdfA460107.pdf
A460107.pdf
 

Reif Honors Thesis Revised

  • 1. Does it pay to do good? An analysis of CEO Compensation at Large American Charities Jessica Reif, B.S. ILR Honors Candidate April 2014 Cornell University School of Industrial and Labor Relations Adviser: Professor Kevin Hallock Second Reader: Professor Robert Smith
  • 2. 1 Introduction Many donors are appalled to learn that the executives managing their favorite charities earn six-figure salaries. The national media and watchdog organizations frequently draw public attention to the arena of nonprofit compensation (Wallock 2013, Charity Navigator 2013). Though only a small fraction of the public is educated in compensation, articles such as the “Ten Insanely Overpaid Nonprofit Execs” published in the Huffington Post draw millions of readers and hundreds of commenters (Strachan 2013). Recent financial scandals involving CEOs at large charities including United Way, the Smithsonian Institution, and Covenant House have shaken the public’s faith in nonprofits (Frumkin 2011). Charity Navigator, a nonprofit institution that seeks to aggregate publicly available financial information from charitable organizations to assist donors and would-be donors, also stresses the importance of executive compensation in evaluating charities. Annually, its research division publishes a study of CEO compensation at charitable organizations, highlighting differences based on organization size, mission, and location. The 2013 study notes, “Many donors assume that charity leaders work for free or minimal pay” (2013 CEO Compensation Study). While reassuring donors that the median salary for nonprofit CEOs increased only 2.5% from the previous year, Charity Navigator encourages donors to be vigilant about excessive nonprofit compensation – particularly at organizations where the CEO is paid $1 million or higher (2013 CEO Compensation Study). Six- and seven-figure compensation packages at large charities have led to action by some state governments. A December 2013 report from the Massachusetts Attorney General’s office called for reform of compensation disclosure at nonprofits, after a study of 25 large
  • 3. 2 Massachusetts-based charities showed CEOs earning over half-million dollar compensation packages in addition to lavish perks (Wallock 2013). In May 2013, New York Governor Andrew Cuomo issued an executive order prohibiting charities who receive state funding from paying more than $199,000 to any employee. Similar measures were enacted by Florida and New Jersey (Wallock 2013). While very few consumers review the executive compensation practices of the for-profit companies to whom they bring their business, executive pay carries particular importance to citizens interested in charitable giving and the governments that provide tax-exemptions to these organizations. To build trust from the public, nonprofit organizations must prove to their donors that they are worthy of the contributions they receive. Without this trust, nonprofits will be unable to garner enough public support to fundraise enough to accomplish their goals. For donors, appropriate compensation indicates that their contributions move forward the espoused social mission of the organization, not boost the pay of executives. Likewise, governments offer nonprofits special tax benefits not available to for-profit companies. These financial benefits are intended to permit the nonprofit to achieve greater social welfare, not raise executive pay. The government legally prohibits nonprofits from paying executives beyond what is ‘reasonable’ under the totality of circumstances and from distributing excess earnings to managers, thus executive pay is subject to special oversight and government scrutiny (Hansman 1980). Many management scholars and nonprofit leaders challenge the assumption that the compensation the public deems to be inflated is in fact too high. The consensus in management literature is that compensation is an important tool for attracting and retaining top talent (Drucker 1990, Conyon et al. 2009). Nonprofit organizations are highly complex like their for-profit counterparts, and therefore require educated leaders with high levels of managerial skill.
  • 4. 3 Individuals of this quality come with a price. In order to compete for top talent nonprofits need to offer competitive wages to those in charge. Without question, a lot is riding on managerial pay. Appropriate compensation of nonprofit managers is necessary to establish the public trust needed for consistent donations, to maintain the nonprofit’s tax-exempt status, and to reward the leaders who drive the success of the organization. In the face of six- and seven- figure salaries at many of America’s largest nonprofit institutions, what constitutes appropriate compensation is not an easy question to answer. With watchdog groups criticizing organizations whose CEOs make over $1 million, the State of New York punishing nonprofits who pay any employee over $199,000, and the Massachusetts Attorney General concerned about nonprofit CEOs earning over half a million, calls for oversight tend to be accompanied by an arbitrary numerical figure for what level of compensation is appropriate. Conversely, the compensation packages awarded to executives at the largest charities are anything but arbitrary. They are the output of highly complex processes, often involving a variety of input variables, a team of outside consultants, benchmarking exercises, compensation committees, and a thorough evaluation of the executive’s performance in key areas. Nonprofit organizations are required to disclose the resources they use to determine executive compensation in their tax returns, and often go above-and-beyond this call by further detailing their compensation policies on their websites. Yet, cries for lower compensation attack the total compensation figure rather than the well-documented process used to arrive at that number. Furthermore, the debate ignores the mix of components that comprise an executive pay. Existing literature discusses how executive pay is associated with other financial measures, most notably organizational size as measured by assets
  • 5. 4 or annual program expenses. Additionally, many studies attempt to explain the gap between executive compensation at for-profit and nonprofit organizations (Drucker 1990, Oster 1998). Though certainly useful insight, neither body of research gives credence to the arguments of those individuals and governments calling for lower executive compensation or to the charities that award their CEOs with compensation others deem to be unreasonable. This paper will begin to reconcile the gap between the cries for lower pay in charitable organizations and the variables the previous literature has found to be associated with higher compensation by examining how specific pay determination practices used by charitable organizations are associated with total compensation. The national debate over nonprofit compensation must expand beyond a narrow focus on total CEO pay to a conversation about the practices nonprofit organizations employ to determine how their leaders are rewarded for their work. The aim of this research is to provide insight into how executive compensation is determined, and what influence compensation consultants and contracts may have on top executive pay. This paper will proceed in six steps. First, it will provide a brief summary of the American nonprofit context, including the requirements governing CEO pay. Next, it will provide a literature review of the current body of research on nonprofit executive compensation. Third, it will provide the hypotheses of this study. Fourth, it will explain the methodology I employed to test the hypotheses. The fifth section will describe the results, and the sixth section will conclude with a summary of findings and suggestions for further research.
  • 6. 5 Section I - The American Nonprofit Context Nonprofits are a fundamental part of the American tradition and emerge from the free market to meet societal needs that go unaddressed by the state. Frumkin and Keating write, “the nonprofit organizational form allows society to overcome market failures and to increase the output of certain goods and services, without moving to direct government provision or the provision of subsidies to for-profit firms” (Frumkin 2011, 3). By reducing the need for state subsidies and in-kind transfers in a variety of areas, nonprofits lift a great burden from the government. The nonprofit sector is growing at a rapid pace, with a 25% increase in the number of organizations from 2001 to 2011. In 2010, nonprofits accounted for 5.4% of Gross Domestic Product and 10% of total employment. The rate of growth in this $779 billion industry has surpassed that of the private sector (Roeger, Blackwood, Pettijohn 2012). In exchange for taking on this burden of creating greater societal welfare, nonprofits are granted two key tax benefits. First, nonprofits are provided with exemptions from income, sales, and property taxes. This indirectly subsidizes the activity of the nonprofits, thus allowing them to achieve greater output at a lower cost. Second, nonprofits can offer their donors tax deductions for their charitable gifts. This encourages the public to donate to charitable organizations by allowing them to deduct the dollars they donate from their taxable income. Both of these tax benefits are help nonprofits achieve their mission. Because tax exemption enables nonprofits to undercut for-profit firms’ prices for the same activity, one might ask why all firms don’t operate as nonprofits. To quality for tax exempt status, organizations must meet the eligibility requirements set out in Section 501(c) of the tax
  • 7. 6 code and consent to certain governance requirements. While some industries, such as religious organizations, are almost entirely comprised of nonprofit organizations, in other industries, such as healthcare, nonprofit organizations and for-profit companies exist side-by-side. The IRS governance requirements allow nonprofits to increase social welfare by increasing the production of certain goods and services without encroaching on the free-market by subsidizing for-profit firms, while regulating them enough to ensure that they are not abusing the tax advantages they receive. Eligibility Requirements Section 501(c) broadly defines nonprofits as organized for “charitable, religious, educational, scientific, or other purposes.” Nonprofit organizations exceeding $25,000 in annual revenue are required to file a Form 990 with the IRS. This publicly available document discloses information from the nonprofit’s financial statements and includes additional schedule filings for certain designations of nonprofits. The IRS has 29 classifications for nonprofits, with the far most popular classification being 501c(3). A 501c(3) nonprofit is one whose purpose is “Religious, Educational, Charitable, Scientific, Literary, Testing for Public Safety, to Foster National or International Amateur Sports Competition, or Prevention of Cruelty to Children or Animals Organizations” (Internal Revenue Service 501c3 guidelines). These organizations tend to align with the classical interpretation of the word “charity,” in a way other tax-exempt designations, such as labor unions and sports clubs, do not. 501c(3) organizations are public-serving rather than member-serving, and typically rely on grants from the government and donations from the public to succeed. While the IRS code gives broad definitions of nonprofits, Salamon’s research described six characteristics that define America nonprofits (1996). First, these organizations are formally
  • 8. 7 constituted to fulfill an established mission. Nonprofits typically have a public mission statement, outlining the organization’s broad objectives and purpose. Second, nonprofits are private institutions not operated by the government. While some nonprofits rely heavily on government grants for support, managers of the organization are unaffiliated with the state. Third, nonprofits are not created to generate wealth for their owners. The non-distribution constraint designed for maintaining this principle will be described in the “governance requirements” section. Fourth, nonprofits are self-governing and maintain full control over their activities, so long as they meet the standards set forth by the IRS code. Fifth, nonprofits are voluntary in nature. Their activity is not compelled by the government or any other entity. Finally, nonprofits are designed to serve the public interest. They are organized to, in some way, “do good” (Salamon 1996). Governance Requirements With managerial performance difficult to measure and a noncompetitive operating environment, nonprofit executives have potential for corruption. Several legal mechanisms exist to regulate pay and discourage poor managerial behavior, including the non-distribution constraint and the “reasonable but not excessive” compensation requirement. A failure to meet these governance standards can result in sanctions, the most extreme being revocation of the organization’s tax-exempt status. The Non-Distribution Constraint. Executive compensation in for-profit companies typically reflects the financial performance of the firm. The promise of increased bonuses incentivizes executives to cut costs wherever possible and run the business with a clear focus on the bottom line. In turn, higher profits create higher earnings for shareholders and higher compensation for executives – a “win-win” situation for investors and managers (Frumkin 2011).
  • 9. 8 There is a fundamental problem with this approach applied to nonprofit executives. A narrow focus on financial metrics is inappropriate to reward nonprofit management, because the mission of a nonprofit is to fulfill a societal need rather than generate profit. Hansmann notes that nonprofits are not barred from earning profits, so long as those profits are invested in the social mission of the organization rather than distributed executives. He calls this restriction the “non-distribution constraint” (Hansmann 1980, 835). The non-distribution constraint does not prevent nonprofit employees from receiving pay or receiving incentive compensation, it simply prohibits the distribution of net earnings to those in charge (Hansmann 1980). The non-distribution constraint ensures that nonprofits’ excess earnings will be retained and used to provide future services, rather than distributed to managers. This measure discourages leaders from cutting program costs for the sake of higher compensation, as Boards avoid tying executive rewards to the financial performance of the organization. The constraint also underscores the importance of appropriating funds to the social mission of the organization, rather than diverting them for personal gain. This is important for two groups: the government, who as previously discussed essentially subsidizes the operations of the organizations in the form of tax-exemptions, and the public. Donors and others who pay for the services that the organizations provide expect their contributions to be used for the services, not the leaders’ paychecks. Reasonable but not excessive compensation. While nonprofits are prohibited from distributing excess revenue to executives, managers are not expected to work without pay. The IRS recognizes the importance of competitive compensation in attracting and retaining talent to lead nonprofits, and thus actively encourages compensation committees to reward executives
  • 10. 9 with “reasonable” compensation, without paying excessively. The IRS defines excessive compensation as compensation that “exceeds what is reasonable under all of the circumstances.” While this vague yardstick of what constitutes reasonable provides little guidance for determining executive pay, the IRS lists several mechanisms for determining executive pay on Form 990. As of 2008, filing organizations must disclose which of the following six mechanisms it employed to establish the compensation of its CEO or Executive Director: compensation committees, independent compensation consultants, Form 990s of other organizations, written employment contracts, compensation surveys or studies, and approval by the board or compensation committee. Though organizations are not legally required to use any of these methods of determining CEO compensation, a clearly defined process for how pay is determined may reduce the possibility of an IRS investigation of the organization’s pay practices. Management scholars debate the question of what compensation is reasonable for nonprofit executives. Compensation studies consistently show nonprofit employees earn less than their counterparts in similar positions in for-profit firms (Ruhm and Barokski 2000). Some scholars suggest that paying nonprofit managers levels of pay similar to those at for-profit firms would create a conflict of interest. They theorize that nonprofit executives engage in “labor donations,” forgoing the higher pay in the for-profit sector for the sake of doing good through nonprofit employment (Rose-Ackerman 1986, Preston 1989). Other scholars contend that lower pay is necessary in the nonprofit sector to deter managers whose biggest concerns are monetary Rewards from seeking employment there (Hansmann 1980). In both cases, researchers advocate for the continuation of lower pay for nonprofit managers on the premise that executives who run organizations seeking non-monetary outcomes knowingly consent to lower pay than those who do not.
  • 11. 10 On the contrary, other scholars contend that it is imperative for nonprofit executives to earn similar pay to individuals in similar roles in for-profit firms (Drucker 1990). They argue that the success of a nonprofit hinges on its ability to attract and retain top quality managers who are willing to bear the uncertainties of working at a nonprofit, such as inconsistent funding and often difficult to measure outcomes. The social orientation of nonprofit organizations does not eliminate the demanding nature of managing a complex organization, and thus it shouldn’t solely govern how much nonprofit mangers earn (Letts, Ryan, and Grossman 1999). Determining a level of executive compensation that is reasonable but not excessive proves to be yet another challenge facing nonprofit organizations. With limited guidance on how reasonable is defined, there is an extra burden on boards to provide a thorough, transparent, and honorable process for determining managerial pay. Sanctions. In addition to losing public trust, nonprofits that violate the non-distribution constraint or offer excessive executive compensation packages face legal sanctions. Until 2002, the only punitive measure for inappropriate compensation available to the IRS was a complete revocation of the organization’s tax-exempt status. The IRS seldom employed this drastic measure, as proving a violation was extremely difficult given the vague nature of the rules. More recently, the IRS adopted a less threatening punitive measure: an excise tax. Rather than revoking a nonprofit’s tax-exempt status, the tax serves as an intermediate sanction for nonprofits found to violate the legal restrictions governing executive compensation. Executives of organizations found to pay excessive compensation must forfeit the portion of their pay ruled excessive in addition to a 25% excise tax on the amount. Oversight boards who approved the executive compensation must also pay a penalty (Internal Revenue Service 501c policies).
  • 12. 11 Though enforcement action is still rare, several nonprofits are sanctioned each year with this relatively moderate penalty.
  • 13. 12 Section II – Literature Review Carroll, Hughes, and Luksetich note, “literature concerned with the determinants of executive compensation in the nonprofit sector pales in comparison to the quantity and depth of the theoretical and empirical research in the for-profit sector of the economy” (2005, 19). While much remains unknown about executive compensation at nonprofits, previous research has made significant headway in answering many of the common questions about nonprofit pay practices. This review will outline the existing research in the arena of nonprofit compensation and will contain five parts. First, it will discuss some of the variables correlated with executive pay, specifically focusing on organizational size and IRS classification. Second, it will summarize the possible explanations for year-to-year changes in CEO pay presented by prior management research. Next, it will elaborate on the difficulties of implementing pay-for-performance systems in the nonprofit setting and the metrics of performance used by nonprofits that do offer performance pay. Fourth, it will touch upon the wage gap between nonprofits and for-profit companies. Finally, it will discuss the limitations that a lack of quality nonprofit data has imposed upon prior research. This body of literature informs the research hypotheses in the following section. Predictors of Nonprofit CEO Pay Previous research has identified associations between organizational size, IRS classification, and executive pay. A more recent study has identified a link between free cash flows and CEO pay as well. 1. Organizational Size
  • 14. 13 The most tried-and-true predictor of CEO pay in nonprofits is organizational size. Murphy (1998) notes that larger organizations require leaders capable of more complex tasks and exercising control over more operations, thus organizational size is a proxy for managerial skill. The most commonly used measures of organizational size in previous nonprofit compensation studies are total fixed assets and total program expenses. Hallock used total assets and log of total assets as a proxy for size, noting that an organization’s assets are typically linked to its operations (2000). Frumkin and Keating (2011) argue that it is necessary to use both total assets and total program expenses as proxies for organizational size. Total program expenses exclude fundraising and administrative costs, measuring only the expenses related to the specific mission-related activity of the nonprofit. They note that boards of directors at nonprofits generally set CEO compensation based on annual budgets and scale of operations compared to industry peers, and total program expenses are an appropriate representation of annual budget (Frumkin and Keating 2011). Regardless of the measure of size, the results have consistently demonstrated that CEOs of larger organizations receive larger paychecks. Nonprofit compensation studies consistently show a link between organization size and executive compensation (Oster 1998, Hallock 2000). In a study of CEO compensation at 6,590 nonprofits, Frumkin and Keating found increases in CEO pay by $0.25 and $0.07 for each additional thousand dollars in fixed assets and program expenses, respectively (2011). Similarly, Hallock found increases of $0.10 in pay for every thousand dollars of fixed assets (2000). While these studies were not limited to 501(c)(3) organizations, a 2013 Charity Navigator CEO Compensation Study confirmed that the trend of larger organizations offering higher CEO pay is evident within the context of charities as well. This study examined CEO pay at 3,929
  • 15. 14 mid- to large-sized charities, and found that the median compensation earned was $125,942 in 2011. The median compensation varied substantially with organization size, however; large charities with more than $13.5 million in expenses paid median CEO compensation of $244,209, medium-sized organizations with between $3.5 million and $13.5 million in expenses paid median CEO compensation of $145,230, and smaller organizations paid median compensation of $95,661. There were also clear distinctions in pay among the charities based on size, with the largest charities of over $500 million in annual expenses paying their CEOs a median salary of $422,578 (Frumkin and Keating, 2011). While program expenses, total expenses, and fixed assets may serve as proxies for organizational size, the measures can be misleading when used to represent the impact of the organization. For example, consider a nonprofit that provides free malaria vaccinations to children. Changes such as increased volunteer labor or lower costs of vaccination and travel can allow the nonprofit to increase its impact without increasing its program spending or assets. The relationship between expenses or assets and the scope of the organization’s activities is not always clear, and thus one must be careful when using these measures to evaluate the efficacy of a nonprofit or its executives. 2. IRS Classifications As previously mentioned, nonprofits are classified by the IRS based on the nature of their activities. Several studies explore the differences in executive compensation practices based on their IRS classifications. Frumkin and Keating note that industry-specific regressions have much greater explanatory power than those that seek to explain executive compensation in all nonprofits (2001); certain variables carry more weight in particular subsectors. In all sub-sectors except religious nonprofits, Frumkin and Keating found nonprofit CEOs typically are paid a
  • 16. 15 substantial fixed component independent of variables such as programs or assets. This amount varied across the subsectors, with the lowest found in arts organizations at $81,139.98 and highest in healthcare organizations at $151,477.30. The arts and human services sub-sectors are unique in that CEO compensation is more closely linked to an organization’s fixed assets. Their study found increases in pay of $1.29 and $0.50 for each additional thousand dollars of fixed assets in arts and human services nonprofits, respectively. Significant relationships between fixed assets and CEO pay were not found in the education, health, religious, or “other” sub- sectors (Frumkin and Keating 2011). The arts, education, health, religious, and “other” classifications of nonprofits exhibited no statistically significant association between changes in CEO pay and changes in dollar growth in contributions (Frumkin and Keating 2011). As changes in contributions are typically a considered to be a performance measure for nonprofits, this suggests a weak performance-pay relationship. Similarly, the 2013 Charity Navigator study showed median salaries to be drastically different across IRS classifications. Education had the highest median total compensation at $170,178, followed by Arts at $159,650, and Health at 137,919 (2013 CEO Compensation Study). As indicated by Frumkin and Keating’s research, religious charities compensate significantly less than other nonprofits, with a median CEO package of $82,746 (2011). 3. Free Cash Flows Keating and Frumkin introduced the free cash flow hypothesis, which speculates that CEO compensation will be higher in nonprofits that have relatively more free cash flows available. They note, “unrestricted funds within organizations give nonprofit boards the ability to use “free cash” for non-essential and non-budget items, including increased salaries and benefits
  • 17. 16 for senior staff’ (2001, 14). There are several reasons why a nonprofit might have unrestricted funds available, including commercial revenue not subject to donor oversight, income from an endowment, or undesignated donations. Two of these variables were found to have a significant relationship to CEO pay (2001, 21). For organizations that receive unrestricted funds through commercial revenues, a 1% increase in commercial revenue share was associated with a $600 increase in CEO pay. Similarly, organizations with higher endowment-related income had higher CEO pay. Changes in Pay from Year to Year Baber, Daniel, and Roberts studied the way changes in various accounting measures frequently reported publicly by charity oversight agencies are related to the compensation of CEOs at charitable organizations. They note that such agencies are typically concerned with changes in program spending, revenue, and relative costs of administering the charity. They hypothesized that changes in each of these three performance measures would be positively related to changes in executive compensation, and tested their hypothesis using a sample of 331 Maryland-based charities (1999). Their study showed significant relationship CEO Compensation and these performance metrics. For instance, a 10% increase in annual revenues was associated with a 0.9% increase in total compensation for the CEO. Additionally, increasing program spending by 10% was associated with a 0.76% additional compensation for the CEO (Baber 688). The increase in CEO compensation that was not associated with either changes in revenues or changes in program spending was 5.8%. These data suggest that changes in performance measures from year to year may have some bearing on CEO pay (Baber, Daniel, Roberts 1999).
  • 18. 17 The Baber, Daniel, and Roberts’ study also notes that charities are inclined to report a breakeven condition whenever possible, as charities with excess revenue may appear overfunded and charities operating on a deficit may appear irresponsible; salaries are a discretionary expense item that can be raised if a charity is not already at or below its breakeven point (1999, 691). These adjustments may account for some year-to-year changes in CEO compensation. Pay-for-Performance Pay-for-performance systems dominate executive compensation structures in for-profit companies, yet are still rare in the nonprofit setting. Steinberg notes that while incentive contracts are not entirely prohibited by the non-distribution constraint, some pay-for- performance metrics may compromise donor trust by creating a perception that their contributions are diverted away from the organization’s purpose in favor of higher executive compensation (Steinberg 1990). For instance, consider a CEO who receives a percentage of funds raised at a fundraiser. Even if that percentage is small, it has the effect of increasing the amount that donors need to give to have the same effect on output of the organizations services (Carroll 20). This may make it more difficult for nonprofits to attract donations. Despite this difficulty, many nonprofit organizations use incentive pay systems to reward managers. Pynes notes that there are innovative approaches to nonprofit pay-for-performance that run less risk of compromising donor trust. She suggests broad banding pay structures to allow for more lateral growth within one’s pay grade, in addition to skill-based pay, merit pay, and gainsharing (Pynes 1997). Other researchers have noted the importance of performance- based pay systems to create risk-sharing among executives and the firms they manage (Rose- Ackerman 1986).
  • 19. 18 Nonprofit For-Profit Wage Gap Though the wage gap between for-profit and nonprofit organizations is not a primary concern of this paper, the theoretical explanations for the difference inform our understanding of nonprofit executive compensation and thus deserve brief attention here. As Hallock outlines, there are four dominant theoretical reasons for the gap (2000). First, nonprofit employees engage in labor donations. This means they knowingly accept a wage lower than what their skill, education, and experience would command in the for-profit sector and essentially donate the difference to the organization (Preston 1989). The second explanation is that nonprofit workers accept lower pay in exchange for more favorable working conditions, such as more flexible hours or job stability. This concept is known as compensating wage differentials. The third explanation deals with the efficiency-wage hypothesis, and holds that workers whose outcomes are difficult to measure are paid more than their market value and work must work hard to maintain their position to avoid losing their jobs and having to accept a lower paying position. The final explanation is that those who accept nonprofit positions may have skills that would be more useful in another sector (Hallock 2000). Limitations of Existing Research While previous research has made substantial headway in uncovering the determinants of nonprofit CEO pay, researchers encounter common roadblocks when attempting to study this phenomenon. First, a lack of accurate data plagues the nonproft research community. Though recent changes to the Form 990 have required nonprofits to disclose the compensation of their top five most highly-paid officers more clearly, prior to 2007 the data were reported without a corresponding name. This made it difficult to determine whether or not the CEO changed from year to year. Similarly, the breadth of objectives of nonprofits makes it extremely difficult to
  • 20. 19 compare one nonprofit’s goals to another’s goals. Because a variety of non-accounting metrics may be employed to determine executive compensation, comparisons from organization to organization are difficult.
  • 21. 20 Section III - Research Hypotheses With the unique context constraints and requirements in mind, I examine the processes used to determine executive compensation at the largest American charities. I take a different approach than the recent literature, focusing less on the outcome of pay itself and more on the methods employed to reach that outcome. I evaluate the role of organizational size, as well as the influence of compensation consultants and employment contracts in determining executive pay. A. Organizational Size As previously discussed, a great deal of prior research shows an association between a nonprofit organization’s assets and the pay of its CEO (Oster 1980, Hallock 2000, Frumkin and Keating 2011). The prevalence of this finding is consistent with the notion that CEOs managing larger, more complex organizations earn more than those who manage smaller ones. Because the scope of operations of nonprofit organizations are difficult to compare and other proxies for organizational size used in the for-profit setting such as market share and gross revenue are less relevant to nonprofits, assets is the most reliable proxy for organizational size. I expect that this finding will hold true even among our sample of the largest organizations, and as such: H1: Larger organizations will offer higher total pay to their CEOs. B. Compensation Consultants Given the dearth of research on the use of compensation consultants in the nonprofit sector, my hypothesis is informed largely by associations confirmed in studies of for-profit firms. Employing outside consultants to determine executive pay has been repeatedly associated with
  • 22. 21 higher compensation in the for-profit sector. Executive compensation expert Graef Crystal said in 1991: Executive compensation in the United States did not go out of control simply through some random process; it went out of control because of the actions – or inactions – of a number of parties. The first cultprits in what will be a litany of culprits are compensation consultants (Conyon 401). A number of studies have confirmed his assertion, showing CEO compensation is higher in firms utilizing compensation consultants to set executive pay (Conyon 2011; Armstrong, Ittner, Larcker 2012). A study of 755 large U.S. corporations found significant increases in CEO total pay in organizations where consultants designed the compensation packages (Cadman, Carter, Hillegeist 263). Given the similarity of the roles of consultants in the for-profit and nonprofit setting, I expect these findings will hold true with charities, and therefore propose: H2: Nonprofit organizations who use compensation consultants will have higher paid CEOs. C. Employment Contracts The use of employment contracts for CEOs of both nonprofit and for-profit firms is somewhat controversial. Zhao elaborates on the ways in which a CEO is protected by a contract. Her job is secure until his contract expires, enabling her to pursue higher risk opportunities. She is also guaranteed certain compensation, has quantifiable measures of performance, and is granted generous change-in-control provisions. Yet, these contracts can also be very entrenching, making it difficult to make large annual adjustments when necessary (Zhao 2005). Lund and Polsky argue that CEO employment contracts laced with incentive pay actually have diminishing returns and that firms should reconsider the extent to which their compensation packages emphasize specific performance measures (2011). Specifically, they note that
  • 23. 22 incentives tied to particular accounting measures are ineffective when outcomes are difficult to measure. Despite these limitations, contracts typically provide some level of guaranteed reward compensation (2011, 683-4). Because contracts usually ensure CEOs some automatic reward compensation in addition to performance-based incentives, I posit: H3: Charity CEOs with employment contracts receive higher total pay.
  • 24. 23 Section IV – Method A. Sample Population The organizations chosen for the sample are those which appeared in Forbes Magazine’s annual list of the largest 200 American charities as measured by total assets for the years 2008, 2009, 2010, and 2011. The data Forbes uses to compile the annual list come from the National Center for Charitable Statistics. Though Forbes always employs the same methodology for determining its annual list, the organizations that make the cut vary substantially each year. A one-time grant or campaign can lead assets to spike in one fiscal year, securing an organization a spot on the list for that year but not the next. Only the 115 organizations that appeared on the list for each of the four consecutive years were included in the sample, because the focus of this study is charitable organizations who were consistently among the largest throughout the period of interest. I chose to use the organizations listed by Forbes because these are the nonprofits that have the closest ties to the general public. Compensation practices at the organizations the public subsidizes, through both taxpayer-funded government grants and private donations, carry the most weight on how the public thinks about charity compensation. There are two notable exclusions that Forbes makes when compiling the list, which make it an optimal group for this study. First, large charitable organizations that do not solicit donations from the public or grants from the government are not included in the group. Consider for example the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation, which is funded primarily through the assets of a single family. Second, organizations that primarily solicit donations and grants from individuals who have received their services in some capacity are excluded from the group. This exclusion is important because
  • 25. 24 it eliminates institutions whose primary donor base is not the general public, such as colleges and universities who primarily solicit donations from alumni. A complete list of the organizations used in the sample and the number of observations from each organization can be found in the Appendix. B. Data Collection Each organization is required to file a Form 990 tax return each year, and the returns are subsequently made publicly available. Returns were retrieved from each organization for the years 2008, 2009, 2010, and 2011. Most of the returns were available on the organizations’ websites or nonprofit charity rating agencies such as GuideStar and Charity Navigator. In a few rare cases, the organization’s controller provided the returns electronically directly from the charity. I obtained data from the Form 990 for the organization’s total revenue, total expenses, total salaries & benefits expenses, total fundraising expenses, assets and liabilities for each year. I also recorded the Schedule J disclosure of which of the following resources the organization used to set CEO pay: compensation committee, independent consultants, other organizations’ Form 990s, an employment contract, a study or survey, and/or approval by the board of directors. I also recorded the name, base compensation, bonus and incentive pay, other reportable compensation, retirement and deferred compensation, nontaxable benefits, and total compensation of each CEO. In a few cases, I was unable to obtain copies of the organizations’ tax returns, leaving 441 usable observations. C. Testing the Hypotheses To test the first hypothesis, I used log of total assets as a proxy for organizational size, consistent with previous research (Hallock 2000). I also considered the log of the number of
  • 26. 25 employees as a second proxy for organizational size. I regress log of total pay accounting on logs of assets and employees. To test the second hypothesis, I add the independent variable for whether or not the organization used a consultant. This shows whether the addition of a consultant has any association with executive pay. Similarly, I test the third hypothesis using the independent variable of whether or not the CEO was under contract. This shows whether association exists between employment contracts and CEO pay. All calculations were performed using STATA 13.0.
  • 27. 26 Section V – Results and Discussion Table 1 Summary Statistics on Charity CEO Compensation (in thousand USD) Component Observations Mean Std. Dev. Min 25th Percentile Median 75th Percentile Max Base 441 384 298 19 224 337 451 3208 Bonus 441 62 197 0 0 0 50 1950 Other Pay 441 93 419 0 0 10 45 7087 Retirement 441 64 188 0 5 80 42 2076 Nontaxable Benefits 0 27 22 1 8 22 39 74 Total Pay 441 629 758 80 282 427 635 9185 Organizational Size I found no significant association between the log of assets and the log of CEO total pay in this population, contrary to the findings of several other nonprofit compensation studies (Hallock 2000, Oster 1980). One reason why this might be the case is that the sample in this study consists exclusively of the largest organizations by asset volume. It is possible that asset levels are associated with CEO pay when assets range from the levels of mid-sized organizations to the levels of large organizations, but that this affect disappears after a certain threshold has been reached.
  • 28. 27 Figure 1. Pay and Assets Another proxy for organizational size, the log of the number of employees, did show a significant association with increased executive compensation. This measure has not traditionally appeared in compensation literature, but may be particularly important in the non-profit setting where financial metrics take a backseat to the social orientation of the organization. At charitable organizations, the complexity of a CEO’s position may be more closely associated with the number of people he manages rather than the organization’s assets, thus organizational size as measured by number of employees is a more reliable predictor of CEO pay. Figure 2. Pay and Employees
  • 29. 28 Consultants I found that total CEO pay was significantly higher in organizations that used compensation consultants to set pay for their top executive. Organizations who hired consultants offered mean total pay of $773,207 compared to $363,481 in organizations that did not use consultants (p <0.001). Interestingly, there was a statistically significant difference in each of the individual compensation components that make-up total pay, with the exception of nontaxable compensation. Though base compensation is still the largest component of total pay for organizations that use consultants and organizations that do not, bonus pay, other reportable compensation, and retirement compensation was significantly higher in the organizations that used consultants. CEO pay packages offered by organizations that employed consultants tend to more closely mirror those offered by for-profit firms, with bonus compensation and other reportable compensation comprising a very significant portion of total pay. Table 2. Mean Compensation in Thousands by whether a Consultant is used Mean Consultant No Consultant p-value Base 384 446 272 0.000 Bonus 62.4 84.4 22.2 0.001 Other Comp 92.8 132 20.3 0.007 Retirement Comp 63.8 84.6 25.7 0.002 Nontaxable Benefits 25.6 27.4 26.0 0.528 Total Pay 629 774 363 0.001 N 441 285 156 Given the significant gap in pay in organizations that use consultants relative to those that do not, it is necessary to investigate possible differences between the two groups of organizations. There was no significant difference in the assets of organizations that used consultants and the assets of those who did not. However, the mean number of employees at an
  • 30. 29 organization that used a consultant was 2,378 compared to only 947 at organizations that did not (p < 0.005). Because we already know a positive correlation exists between total compensation and number of employees, we regress the log of total pay on the log of assets and the log of employees as an indication of whether using a consultant would still be associated with higher pay all else held constant. In Table 3, we see that using a consultant is still associated with higher total pay controlling for organizational size as measured by assets or employees. This is consistent with H2. Table 3 Log of Total Pay Regression accounting for use of a consultant, assets, and employees. (1) (2) (3) (4) Consultant 0.69*** 0.55*** 0.55*** 0.11 (0.07) (0.06) (0.06) (0.09) Log of Assets -0.10*** -0.10*** 0.02 (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) Log of Employees 0.18*** 0.18*** 0.08* (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) Constant 5.67*** 5.13*** 5.12*** 5.41*** (0.05) (0.19) (0.20) (0.26) R2 0.1946 0.3988 0.4 0.86 Time Indicators NO NO YES YES Organization Indicators NO NO NO YES N 441 441 441 441 Note: *** significant at 0.01, ** significant at 0.05, * significant at 0.10. Standard errors in italics. I also investigated the year-to-year pay differences in the organizations that reported using a compensation consultant in some years but not in others. At the individual organization level, there was no significant difference in pay from year-to-year associated with using a
  • 31. 30 compensation consultant in some years but not others. It is important to note, however, that the Form 990 does not make it clear whether or not an organization must indicate that it has used a compensation consultant if the consultant designed the compensation package currently used in another tax year. Using a compensation consultant to design a plan in one year can have an impact on other years as well, and thus the stability of pay in years in which an organization did not use a consultant is unsurprising. The coefficient on the indicator variable for whether the organization used a consultant is 0.55, indicating that controlling for other characteristics, organizations using a consultant pay top managers 55% more than those that don’t. This seems large and is worthy of additional consideration. Note, however, that if we control for the organizational indicator variable, there is no significant difference in pay for CEOs in years that their pay is determined by compensation consultants relative to years where it is not. This may be misleading, however, because IRS instructions do not indicate whether or not using a multiple year compensation plan designed by a consultant in a prior year requires the organization to disclose that it used a consultant on the Schedule J. It is possible that the effects of using a consultant in one year spill over into following years. Contracts Though not as large as the effect of consultants, employment contracts were also associated with higher CEO pay. The mean CEO total pay in organizations using employment contracts was $790,289 versus $517,645 in those who did not (p < 0.001). As Table 3 shows, there were significant differences in base compensation, bonus compensation, and other reportable compensation associated with the use of employment contracts.
  • 32. 31 Table 4 Mean Compensation in Thousands on whether a Contract was used Mean Contract No Contract p-value Base 384.4 470 326 0.000 Bonus 62.4 90.0 43.4 0.014 Other Comp 92.8 147 55.1 0.023 Retirement Comp 63.8 53.4 71.0 0.334 Nontaxable Benefits 25.6 26.0 27.5 0.472 Total Pay 629 790 518 0.010 N 441 180 261 Once again, it is important to distinguish what other characteristics organizations who use employment contracts are likely to have. As with those who use consultants, there was no significant difference in the volume of assets held by organizations that use contracts and those who did not. The average employee count, however, fell at 2,433 for organizations that used employment contracts and 1,484 for organizations that did not (p < 0.05). To discern whether employment contracts are associated with higher CEO pay, we regress the log of total pay with respect the log of employee count, the log of assets, and an indicator variable for whether a CEO employment contract was used. As Table 5 shows, employment contracts are associated with higher executive pay (p < 0.001). Column (3) shows that this association held true for the four-year sample period, but is mitigated when I control for the changes in each individual organization as shown in Column (4). Note however that when I control for the organization indicator variables, there is no significant difference in total pay in years a contract was used and years no contract was used.
  • 33. 32 Table 5 Log of Total Pay Regression accounting for use of a contract, assets, and employees. (1) (2) (3) (4) Contract 0.37*** 0.35*** 0.35*** 0.05 (0.07) (0.06) (0.06) (0.03) Log of Assets -0.08*** -0.08*** 0.02 (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) Log of Employees 0.21*** 0.21*** 0.08* (0.01) (0.01) (0.03) Constant 5.96*** 5.07*** 5.07*** 5.44*** (0.04) (0.21) (0.22) (0.26) R-squared 0.0605 0.3329 0.336 0.89 Time Indicators NO NO YES YES Organization Indicators NO NO NO YES N 441 441 441 441 Note: *** significant at 0.01, ** significant at 0.05, * significant at 0.10. Standard errors in italics. These findings are consistent with H3 and show that all other things equal, organizations who use employment contracts tend to pay more among this sample population. The coefficient on the indicator variable was 0.35 in Column (1), indicating that controlling for the number of employees and assets, organizations that use employment contracts pay 35% more than those that do not. As with the consulting indicator variable shown in Table 3, this is large and merits additional research.
  • 34. 33 Section VI – Discussion and Concluding Remarks Because of heightened media and watchdog group scrutiny, reasonable executive compensation is of paramount importance in America’s largest charities. These organizations must not only pay their CEOs compensation that meets the unique governance requirements of the American nonprofit setting, but also compensation that is deemed reasonable in the eyes of donors. Amidst these concerns, organizations must also offer compensation that is fair as to retain high-performing executives. The IRS began requiring nonprofit organizations to disclose the resources they use to determine executive compensation in 2008, which gives us unique insight into what practices charities use to determine the pay of their top officers. I have shown that there is a significant association between the use of compensation consultants and higher CEO pay in the largest American charities. Furthermore, I have shown that this relationship holds true even when controlling for organizational size as measured by assets or number of employees. I have also shown a significant relationship between the use of employment contracts and CEO pay. As with consultants, this association holds true even when controlling for measures of organizational size. Like previous research on nonprofit compensation, this study was limited by a lack of available data. Only the information provided on organization’s Form 990 tax returns was used for our calculations, and all of these data were entered manually and is subject to human error. Furthermore, a lack of clear instructions to nonprofits on what level of consultation requires them to “check the box” for using a compensation consultant on the Form 990 may have led to reporting inconsistencies among the sample population.
  • 35. 34 Further research is necessary to explain why the use of compensation consultants and employment contracts is associated with higher CEO pay, and whether this association can be explained by organizational differences other than organizational size. A formal analysis of the practices used by consultants and provisions of nonprofit CEO employment contracts could help explain why this association exists, and whether donors should perceive it as problematic. In spite of these limitations, the results of this study help inform our understanding of pay in the charitable sector. Compensation consultants and employment contracts tend to be associated with higher CEO base salaries and bonuses and higher total pay in organizations that use these resources. We know that there is enormous pressure for nonprofit institutions to maintain public trust. When the IRS began requiring charitable institutions to disclose which resources they used to determine CEO compensation, organizations may have felt compelled to use all six of the listed resources to signal to donors that they have a thorough executive compensation determination process. Perhaps organizations that use all of the listed practices have more capable managers and therefore pay more – or perhaps indicating the use of compensation consultants and employment contracts should signal a red flag rather than reassurance for donors.
  • 36. 35 Appendix Organization Name Observations Alzheimer's Association 4 American Cancer Society 4 American Civil Liberties Union Foundati 4 American Diabetes Association 4 American Heart Association 4 American Kidney Fund 4 American Museum of Natural History 4 Art Institute of Chicago 4 Arthritis Foundation 4 Big Brothers Big Sisters of America 3 Billy Graham Evangelistic Association 4 Boy Scouts of America 4 Boys & Girls Clubs of America 4 Brother's Brother Foundation 4 CARE USA 4 Catholic Charities USA 4 Catholic Medical Mission Board 4 Catholic Relief Services 4 Children International 4 Children's Hospital of Chicago - Lurie 1 Children's Hospital of Philadelphia 4 Children's Memorial Hospital 3 Christian Aid Ministries 4 Christian Broadcasting Network 4 Christian Foundation for Children and A 4 City of Hope 4 Cleveland Clinic Foundation 4 Combined Jewish Philanthrophies 4 Compassion International 4 Conservation Fund 4 Conservation International Foundation 4 Covenant House 4 Cystic Fibrosis Foundation 4 Dana-Farber Cancer Institute 4 Direct Relief International 4 Disabled American Veterans 4 Doctors Without Borders USA 4 Ducks Unlimited 4 Easter Seals 4
  • 37. 36 Educational Media Foundation 4 Father Flanagan's Boys' Home 4 Feed the Children 4 Focus on the Family 4 Food for the Poor 4 Greater Chicago Food Depository 4 Habitat for Humanity International 4 Heart to Heart International 4 Humane Society of the United States 4 In Touch Ministries 4 InterVarsity Christian Fellowship 4 International Fellowship of Christians 4 International Medical Corps 4 JA Worldwide 4 Jewish Federation of Metropolitan Chica 4 Jewish Federation of Metropolitan Detro 4 Juvenile Diabetes Research Foundation 4 Kids in Distressed Situations 4 Kingsway Charities 4 Leukemia & Lymphoma Society 4 MAP International 4 Make-A-Wish Foundation of America 4 March of Dimes Foundation 4 Marine Toys for Tots Foundation 4 Matthew 25: Ministries 4 Mayo Clinic 4 Medical Teams International 4 Memorial Sloan-Kettering Cancer Center 4 Mercy Corps 4 Metropolitan Museum of Art 4 Metropolitan Opera Association 2 Mission to the World (PCA) 4 Mount Sinai School of Medicine and Hosp 4 Muscular Dystrophy Association 4 Museum of Fine Arts, Houston 4 Museum of Modern Art 4 National Audubon Society 4 National Cancer Coalition 4 National Multiple Sclerosis Society 4 National Public Radio 4 National Wildlife Federation 4 Natural Resources Defense Council 4 Nature Conservancy 4
  • 38. 37 New York Public Library 4 New York-Presbyterian Hospital 4 Operation Smile 4 PATH 4 Paralyzed Veterans of America 4 Planned Parenthood Federation of Americ 4 Project HOPE 4 Project Orbis International 4 Public Broadcasting Service 4 Robin Hood Foundation 4 Rotary Foundation of Rotary Internation 4 Samaritan's Purse 4 Scholarship America 4 Scripps Research Institute 4 Shriners Hospitals for Children 4 Smithsonian Institution 4 Special Olympics 4 Teach for America 4 Trinity Broadcasting Network 4 Trust for Public Land 4 UJA/Federation of New York 4 United Negro College Fund 4 United States Fund for UNICEF 3 United Way 4 Volunteers of America 4 WETA 4 World Vision 4 World Wildlife Fund 4 Wycliffe Bible Translators 4 YMCA 3 Young Life 4 Total observations 443
  • 39. 38 References "2013 CEO Compensation Study." Charity Navigator. Charity Navigator, n.d. Web. 15 Nov. 2013. <http://www.charitynavigator.org/__asset__/studies/2013_CEO_Compensation_Study_ Final.pdf>. Armstrong, Christopher S., Christopher D. Ittner, and David F. Larcker. "Corporate governance, compensation consultants, and CEO pay levels." Review of Accounting Studies 17.2 (2012): 322-351. Print. Baber, W., L. Daniel, and A. Roberts. "Compensation to Executives of Eleemosynary Organizations: An Empirical Study of the Role of Accounting Performance Measures ." Working paper, George Washington University - (1999): 1-65. Print. Balassiano, K., and S. M. Chandler. "The Emerging Role of Nonprofit Associations in Advocacy and Public Policy: Trends, Issues, and Prospects." Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 39.5 (2010): 946-955. Print. Barakski, Carey, and Christopher Ruhm. "Compensation in the Nonprofit Sector." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 7562 (2000): 2-45. Print. Barrett, William. "America's 200 Largest Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 19 Nov. 2008. Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/2008/11/19/americas-largest-charities-pf- charities08-cx_wb_1119charity_land.html>. Barrett, William. "America's 200 Largest U.S. Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 24 Nov. 2009. Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/2009/11/23/charitable-giving-gates- foundation-personal-finance-charity-09-intro.html>. Barrett, William. "America's 200 Largest Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 17 Nov. 2010.
  • 40. 39 Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/2010/11/16/forbes-charity-200-personal- finance-philanthropy-200-largest-charities-charity-10-intro.html>. Barrett, William. "The Largest U.S. Charities For 2012." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 8 Nov. 2012. Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/sites/williampbarrett/2012/11/08/the- largest-u-s-charities-for-2012/>. Berresford, Susan V., and Susan Rose-Ackerman. "The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions.." Political Science Quarterly 102.2 (1987): 348. Print. Cadman, Brian, Mary Ellen Carter, and Stephen Hillegeist. "The incentives of compensation consultants and CEO pay." Journal of Accounting and Economics 49.3 (2010): 263-280. Print. Carroll, Thomas, Patricia Hughes, and William Luksetich. "Managers of nonprofit organizations are rewarded for performance." Nonprofit Management and Leadership 16.1 (2005): 19- 41. Print. Conyon, Martin J., Simon I. Peck, and Graham V. Sadler. "Compensation Consultants and Executive Pay: Evidence from the United States and the United Kingdom.." Academy of Management Perspectives 23.1 (2009): 43-55. Print. Conyon, Martin J., Simon I. Peck, and Graham V. Sadler. "New perspectives on the governance of executive compensation: an examination of the role and effect of compensation consultants." Journal of Management & Governance 15.1 (2011): 29-58. Print. Drucker, Peter F.. Managing the non-profit organization: practices and principles. New York, N.Y.: HarperCollins, 1990. Print. Frumkin, Peter, and Elizabeth K. Keating. "The price of doing good: Executive compensation in nonprofit organizations." Policy and Society 29.3 (2010): 269-282. Print.
  • 41. 40 Hallock, Kevin F.. "Managerial Pay and Governance in American Nonprofits." Industrial Relations 41.3 (2002): 377-406. Print. Hansmann, Henry. "The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise." The Yale Law Journal 89.5 (1980): 835- 901. Print. Milofsky, Carl, Lester M. Salamon, and Helmut K. Anheier. "The Emerging Nonprofit Sector: An Overview." Contemporary Sociology 27.1 (1998): 68. Print. Murphy, K. “Executive Compensation.” In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds., Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 3. New York: North-Holland, 1998. Oster, Sharon M. "Executive Compensation in the Nonprofit Sector." Nonprofit Management and Leadership 8.3 (1998): 207-221. Print. Preston, Anne E. "The Nonprofit Worker In A For-Profit World." Journal of Labor Economics 7.4 (1989): 438. Print. Pynes, J. (1997a). Human resource management for public and nonprofit organizations. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Roeger, Katie, Amy S. Blackwood, and Sarah L. Pettijohn. “The Nonprofit Alamanac 2012. The Urban Institute. (2012). Print. Rose-Ackerman, Susan. "Altruistic nonprofit firms in competitive markets: The case of day-care centers in the United States." Journal of Consumer Policy 9.3 (1986): 291-310. Print. Salamon, Lester M. 1992. America’s NonproïŹt Sector. New York: The Foundation Center. Steinberg, R., and B. H. Gray. ""The Role Of Nonprofit Enterprise" In 1993: Hansmann Revisited." Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 22.4 (1993): 297-316. Print. Steinberg, Richard. "Profits and incentive compensation in nonprofit firms." Nonprofit Management and Leadership 1.2 (1990): 137-151. Print.
  • 42. 41 Strachan, Maxwell. "10 Insanely Overpaid Nonprofit Execs." The Huffington Post. TheHuffingtonPost.com, 8 Apr. 2013. Web. 13 Mar. 2014. <http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2013/04/08/10-insanely-overpaid- nonp_n_3038162.html>. "The 200 Largest U.S. Charities." Forbes. Forbes Magazine, 30 Nov. 2011. Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.forbes.com/lists/2011/14/200-largest-us-charities-11.html>. Wallack, Todd. "Massachusetts Attorney General raises questions about nonprofit executive pay - Boston.com." Boston.com. The New York Times, 19 Dec. 2013. Web. 15 Mar. 2014. <http://www.boston.com/news/local/massachusetts/2013/12/19/massachusetts-attorney- general-raises-questions-about-nonprofit-executive- pay/ZRRqAbMejcgxr05x0p790N/story.html>. Young, Dennis R.. "An interview with Peter F. Drucker, Clark Professor of social science and management, claremont graduate school: Part 2." Nonprofit Management and Leadership 2.3 (1992): 295-301. Print. Zhao, Jing. CEO Employment Contracts, Managerial Myopia and Corporate Acquisition Decisions. N.p.: n.p., 2007. Print.