SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 47
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
UNIVERSIDAD COMILLAS – FACULTAD DE DERECHO (ICADE)
Shadow Banking: Lucrative lending by non-bank financial entities in the
gaps of regulation.
Brent Thomas Buyse
Supervised by: Bernardino Muñiz
15 April 2015
i
Submitted to the Faculty of the School of Law (ICADE) of Universidad Pontificia Comillas in
partial discharge of the requirements for the Master in International and European Business Law.
Plagiarism Statement
I certify that this thesis is my own work, based on my personal study and/or research and that I have
acknowledged all material and sources used in its preparation, whether they be books, articles, reports,
lecture notes, and any other kind of document, electronic or personal communication. I also certify
that this thesis has not previously been submitted for assessment in any other institution, except where
specific permission has been granted from all institutions involved, or at any other time in this
institution, and that I have not copied in part or whole or otherwise plagiarized the work of other
students and/or persons.
ii
Table of Contents
Abstract.............................................................................................................................................................iii
I. Introduction..................................................................................................................................................1
II. How does shadow banking work? .......................................................................................................4
a. Alternative payment forms.................................................................................................................12
b. P2P Lending..........................................................................................................................................14
c. Inter-connectedness ............................................................................................................................17
III. Global reality of shadow banking.....................................................................................................19
a. Financial Stability Board Monitoring.............................................................................................21
b. Shadow Banking in the United States ...........................................................................................23
c. Shadow Banking in the European Union .....................................................................................26
d. Shadow Banking in China.................................................................................................................28
e. Shadow Banking in Asia.....................................................................................................................31
f. Shadow Banking in Switzerland .......................................................................................................33
IV. Financial Stability Board Policy and Regulations........................................................................34
a. System wide monitoring.....................................................................................................................35
b. Improved oversight..............................................................................................................................36
i. Mitigating risk in banks’ interactions with shadow banking activities.........................................................36
ii. Reducing the susceptibility of MMFs to “runs”.........................................................................................37
iii. Improving transparency and aligning incentives in securitization................................................................38
iv. Dampening pro-cyclicality and other financial stability risks in securities financing transactions such as repos
and securities lending ....................................................................................................................................38
v. Assessing and mitigating systemic risks posed by other shadow banking entities and activities......................39
V. Conclusion.................................................................................................................................................40
Bibliography ...................................................................................................................................................42
iii
Abstract
This thesis is going to introduce shadow banking as a global financial reality. Shadow
banking is when non-banks facilitate business just like a normal bank would. Shadow banking is an
increasingly complex idea that is responsible for the transaction of trillions of dollars of assets. It is a
system that employs simple concepts like peer-to-peer lending to more complicated such as
securitization and even more elaborate.
For the purpose of this thesis, the discussion will remain with forms of lending. The
financial crisis of 2007-2008 was posited on the flaws of poor lending practices that were
exceptionally accelerated at the fault of poorly managed, understood, and regulated shadow bank
entities. Today that reality is quickly changing.
Regulators around the world are taking notice of what risks are associated with shadow
banking. However, regulators are also seeing the large benefits that shadow banking can relate back
to national economies and the global financial system. By shrinking the size of banks by heavy
regulation it ultimately forces a lot of the lending practices out of traditional banks and into the
arena of shadow banking. That’s ultimately what regulators want in order to not have such an over
reliance on massive financial institutions.
Going forward, regulators are drafting and implementing new regulations to bring shadow
banks out from the shadows and embrace the system and an integral part of the entire financial
system. With the help of the Financial Stability Board, regulators around the world will soon realize
a financial system that sees both traditional banks and shadow banks competing for business in a
resilient financial market. This ultimately is the best scenario for both investors and tax payers.
1
I. Introduction
Put simply, shadow banking is when non-bank entities act like banks. Shadow banks are
more specifically defined as financial intermediaries that conduct functions of banking without
access to central bank liquidity or public sector credit guarantees.1
The Financial Stability Board
(FSB), an international watchdog set up to guard against future financial crises, defined shadow
banking as "credit intermediation involving entities and activities outside the regular banking system,
or non-bank credit intermediation. Shadow banking, when conducted appropriately, provides a
valuable alternative to bank funding which supports positive economic activity as well as quality
competition for banks.
The FSB has recognized five economic functions that are considered shadow banking. These
five activities are: i. management of collective investment vehicles, ii. Loan provision that is
dependent on short term funding, iii. Intermediation of market activities that is dependent on short-
term funding or on secured funding of client assets, iv. Facilitation of credit creation, and v.
securitization and securitization based credit intermediation and funding of financial activities.2
The FSB estimates that shadow banking accounts for a quarter of the global financial
system, with assets of $71 trillion at the beginning of 2013, up from $26 trillion a decade earlier.3
In
some countries, shadow banks are expanding even faster: in China, for instance, they grew by 42%
in 2012 alone.4
Mark Carney, the governor of the Bank of England and head of the Financial Stability Board
was asked to identify the greatest danger to the world economy. He stated shadow banking and in
particular in the emerging markets.5
Shadow banking certainly has the size and reach to be a global
1 (The Economist, 2014)
2 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
3 Id.
4 Id.
5 (The Economist, 2014)
2
crisis by its very inherent nature. Shadow Banking is huge, fast-growing, in certain forms poorly
understood. Shadow banking can be very good but, if carelessly managed like previously realized,
has the potential to be globally devastating.
But there is disagreement about what counts as shadow banking. The central core of shadow
banking is credit. Everything from China’s loan-making trust companies to Western peer-to-peer
lending schemes and money-market funds. A broader definition, however, would include any bank-
like activity undertaken by a firm not regulated as a bank including the mobile-payment systems
offered by Vodafone, the bond-trading platforms set up by technology firms, online crowd source
lenders like Lending Club, or the investment products sold by BlackRock.
Shadow banks differ from other nonregulated lending institutions in that these nonregulated
lenders are not lending capital of which it has an obligation to pay back. Investors put forth money
in hopes of gaining a profitable return but are not promised nor obliged to a return. Whereas
shadow banks are lending money in which they are obligated to return. This is what makes shadow
banking such a sometimes ominous figure in the financial sector.
Shadow banks can be a big boon for a country's financial sectors. Shadow banking, especially
in emerging markets, expands access to credit because the traditional banks currently are faced with
burdensome regulatory hurdles as well as problems with lending capacities. In advanced economies,
traditional banks have been lending less as a result of new regulatory landscapes. Shadow banks
provide long term credit while traditional banks cannot. As reforms continue, authorities are
recognizing that banking activities can slowly be pushed into the more resilient shadow banking
sector.6
In some ways, it is a good thing that lending is coming from outside traditional banks. Banks
are regulated for a simple reason: they have big “maturity mismatches”. Traditional banks also have
6 (Carney, 2014)
3
become enormously leveraged and are linked and connected in massively complicated ways with
other financial institutions. This makes traditional banks especially fragile. And when traditional
banks get into trouble, taxpayers are left to foot the bill in order to avoid an even greater
catastrophe, because governments both guarantee deposits and are frightened to let such big and
complicated institutions fail. So if some lending is moving from traditional banks to less dangerous
shadow bank entities, the financial system should be safer in the long run.
If a business takes a long-term loan from a pension retirement fund or a life insurer with
long-term liabilities instead of from a bank and if the loan goes wrong, the creditor will lose money.
Without the complexities of leverage coupled with the expanding web of counterparties and then
the depositors demanding their deposits, losses in one institution are less likely to damage others.
Yet shadow banks, if poorly regulated, can be just as dangerous as the traditional banks. One
of the principal culprits in the financial crisis was the “structured investment vehicle”, a legal entity
created by banks to sell loans repackaged as bonds.7
These were notionally independent, but when
they got into trouble they pulled in the banks that had set them up.8
Another source of instability
were money-market funds, through which firms and individuals invested spare cash for short-terms.
Originally, MMFs had been thought of as containing zero risk. When it became evident that these
MMFs were not risk free, they suffered a lightning fast run.
Shadow banks are proliferating because traditional banks are struggling and reorganizing.
Traditional banks have been plagued with losses incurred during the financial crisis and stifled by
new heavier regulation, questionable higher capital requirements, and perpetual legal troubles
coupled with outrageously expensive fines. The traditional banks are reshaping themselves as a
result. Lending has been cut significantly. Shadow banks are filling these gaps. Shadow banking
7 (The Economist, 2014)
8 Id.
4
encompasses a wide array of complex financial activities. As a result, this thesis will be specifically
addressing shadow banking activities as they relate to lending.
II. How does shadow banking work?
Shadow banking tends to grow rapidly when there are strict banking regulations in place, as
well as when interest rates are low resulting in investors searching for better returns, and when there
is a large demand for assets. The current environment in advanced economics is very conducive to
further the growth of shadow banking.
To better understand shadow banking, it is first important to understand how normal
traditional banks operate which gives rise to shadow banking. Banks operate by taking deposits from
individuals and commercial entities, depositors. Banks then take these assets and provide funds to
borrowers in the form of a loan. There is generally an overall maturity mismatch with this behavior
however. Depositors generally need quick short term access to their funds that have been deposited
while at the same time borrowers need long term sources of funding. Banks are able to take
advantage of this because it is very rare that all depositors will demand withdraw on their deposits at
the same time. Therefore, banks can maintain only a small portion of total deposits in the form of
liquid assets and be able to lend out the rest in loans. This is known as "quantitative asset
transformation"9
because it changes the maturity of a short term asset into that of a long term asset,
being the loan. This also changes the liquidity of the bank in that the deposits are in a leveraged
state. This is the most common form in which banks generate revenue. Unfortunately, as history has
shown us, this can leave banks in a very tight position and with little avenues of escape in the event
9 (Noeth & Sengupta, 2011)
5
that all the depositors desire their funds in a simultaneous wave. Such an event is known as a panic
and such events have occurred several times over the centuries of modern banking.
In response to such depositor behavior, many modern economies have created deposit
insurance for bank deposits. Thus resulting in central banks becoming the "lender of last resort" to
banks. By creating deposit insurance it gives depositors and the banks a guarantee to a specific value
thus allowing depositors access to their deposits and it prevents banks from becoming insolvent and
collapsing. This is not a perfect system in that it create a moral hazard on the part of the banks. This
moral hazard is arguable the origin of the shadow banking sector.
Banks investing in risky loans benefit from a higher return on the loan issued. The higher the
risk, the greater the likelihood the burden is then placed on taxpayers to pay and bailout depositors
in the event that the enormity of risky loans fail resulting in an issue of insolvency for the bank. This
has resulted in regulators to require banks to maintain capital levels at certain minimum standards in
relation to the riskiness of their lending behavior. This means that banks whose lending practice is
very prudent and does not take on large risks is thus not required to maintain the same capital level
as a bank who engages in chronically risky lending behavior with slim chances of successful return.
The tradeoff is prudent lending does not lead to a high return whereas risky lending does. This is the
inherent dichotomy of risk vs reward to which regulators try to mitigate risk in order to ensure a
banks do not fail and a healthy banking system is maintained for the overall stability of a healthy and
growing economy.
In response to capital requirements regulation, banks created what are known as "off-
balance-sheet entities."10
These off-balance-sheet entities, also known as incognito leveraged entities,
are design is to create the perspective of a less burdened bank in order to lower the capital
requirement. The balance sheet of a bank shows the various assets, liabilities, and net value. This is
10 (Smith, 2015)
6
the most fundamental evaluation of the real position that a bank, or any commercial entity, currently
sits. "Off-balance-sheet entities are assets or debts that do not appear on a company's balance sheet.
For example, oil-drilling companies often establish off-balance-sheet subsidiaries as a way to finance
oil exploration projects. In a clean and clear example, a parent company can set up a subsidiary
company and spin it off by selling a controlling interest or the entire company to investors. Such a
sale generates profits for the parent company from the sale, transfers the risk of the new business
failing to the investors and lets the parent company remove the subsidiary from its balance sheet.”11
This is a common practice which mitigates risk while allowing a parent corporation to create
separateness and limited liability. Too often, however, off–balance-sheet entities are used to
artificially make commercial entities look more financially secure than they actually are. A complex
array of investment vehicles, most famously the subprime-mortgage securities and credit default
swaps, are used to remove debts from corporate balance sheets. The parent company lists proceeds
from the sale of these items as assets but does not list the financial obligations that come with them
as liabilities. When banks issue loans the loans are typically kept on the bank's books as an asset. If
those loans are securitized and sold off as investments the securitized debt, for which the bank is
ultimately liable, is not kept on the bank's books. Herein lies the foundation of shadow banking. It is
an alternative form to the main practice of tradition banks which is qualitative asset transformation.
The credit intermediation, the act of lending funds raised by depositors, through the shadow
banking system is very similar to traditional bank and this is what fulfills the principle functions of
banks being that of qualitative asset transformation. Banks fulfill this by simply the issuing of loans
in a liquid asset which are provided for to the bank by depositors in the form of a liquid asset
deposit. This is a very simple and straight forward process with a limited number of parties
11 Id.
7
involved. Shadow banking involves a much more complicated process to achieve the same goal,
which is with many benefits as well as cautions.
The depositors in shadow banking are wholesale investors who in turn sell to individual
investors and who provide the funds like a traditional depositor would. They provide an analogous
short term funds as a depositor through the use of repurchase markets(more commonly known as
repo markets) and most commonly through money market funds(such funds are also known as
money market mutual funds). On the other end of the process is the loan originator which in the
traditional model would be the bank. Here we find the "shadow bank" which is a financial
institution or can also be a traditional bank engaging in the shadow banking system.
The repurchase market where repo transactions take place. Repo transaction are whereby
commercial entities with surplus case buy a security for cash only for an issuer and then resell them
back to the issue after a short period of time, or term. This functions like a loan to the seller, issuer,
of the security. The security itself is the collateral to the loan made by the purchaser to the seller of
the security. These transaction can be very open ended and are often rolled over with frequency.
This, in turn, functions just like a deposit at a traditional bank. So analogous in fact that a repo
transaction is withdrawable on demand just like a depositor can withdraw funds on demand from a
traditional bank. However, the analogy stops there. There is no deposit insurance on a repo
transaction. The security to the "deposit" is inherent to the collateral. In the event that the issuer is
unable to repay the buyer, the buyer is entitled to sell the repo on the open market and collect the
proceeds from the open market sale, thus passing the obligation to pay to the new owner from the
original buyer. In addition, repo transaction are over collateralized. This overcollateralization results
in a haircut on the repo transaction and is dependent specifically on the level of risk involved with
the repo transaction. The loan amount is typically less than the face value of the security used as
8
collateral. Suppose the lender lends $9 million and receives $10 million of bonds at market value,
then there is a ten percent haircut.
Money Market Funds are a second method by which shadow banking is initiated. In money
market funds investors pool funds together in order to invest in a high-quality and short-term
security. Generally, such investments are issued by governments, central banks, or major well
established corporations who are financially stable. These investments in money market funds are
also withdrawable on demand just like repo transaction which is why they are nearly analogous to
traditional deposits at a bank. Due to the type of security these investment seek, they are regarded as
with no credit risk or very low credit risk. This demands on if it is a US Treasury bill which is most
common, or some other form of commercial paper which is asset backed. Such asset backed
commercial paper is highly regulated in order to ensure the genuine high quality of the security.
Asset banked commercial paper is typically backed by loan receivables or credit card receivables as
the underlying collateral.
Repo transactions and money market funds are attractive and useful in shadow banking
activities because they are safe investments and are withdrawable on demand. This makes them
function like deposits. Although they are similar in that aspect, both do function different in that
investments in money market funds are in the form of a continuing contract where as a repo
transaction is a one-time contract with fixed terms and returns. As stated previously, money market
mutual funds investment shares can be redeemed on demand. Repo transaction use securities that
are typically of a longer maturity as collateral and for short-term borrowing of cash. Both cases have
liability formed which is theoretically withdrawable on demand and of shorter maturities than that of
the assets financed. This is the mechanics of by which shadow banking systems are typically
resemblance of the functions of traditional banks.
9
Historically, traditional banks originate a loan, or issue a loan, with the intention of then
holding on to the loan. However, in modern banking this model has become unprofitable as the
result of increased competition and a changing regulatory regime. In modern banking, origination of
loans is done with the intent and purpose of then converting the issued loan into a security. This is
done by a process known as securitization. Securitization can often be a very complex process with
multiple layers, but the basics of securitization can be explained and is fundamental to the operation
of shadow banking because securitization is how bank deposit funds are used to finance repo
transactions or investments in money market funds.
The starting point to securitization is the originating bank of a loan, whether it is a home
loan or auto loan or student loan, arranges for the loan to be sold to what is known as a warehouse
bank. Warehouse banks purchase loans from a variety of banks much like a warehouse holds a
variety of goods. These warehouse banks are also known as aggregators, sellers, or sponsors. The
financing to this process is that the warehouse bank will issue a line of credit to the originator of the
loan who can then close on the loan and then pass the loan documents back to the warehouse in
exchange for the line of credit funds to be disbursed so the originator can pay out the loan.
Warehouse banks then collect large amounts of loan documents from multiple sources on a large
number of loans. These loan documents serve as collateral on the lines of credit issued to each
originating bank for each loan.
The next step in the process is the sale of these pooled loans at the warehouse bank to what
is known as an administrator. The administrator purchases the loans and then creates a special
purpose vehicle (commonly referred to as a SPV) to then hold the loans. The special purpose vehicle
then issues securities against the loans held by the special purpose vehicle. It is important to note
that the administrator’s purpose is to only purchase loans from a warehouse/aggregator and place
the loans in a SPV. The administrator does not openly sell the securities, generally. The certificates
10
to the securities are sold specifically to underwriters directly from the administrator. Underwriters
then are responsible for the sale of the securities to the ultimate investor.
The final steps in the process of securitization is the purchase of the securities by the
ultimate investor. The investor then receives regular amounts of the principal and interest on the
security related to the special purpose vehicle based on the priority of the security to the SPV. This
order is determined simply by the class, or tranche, of the security and is determined so in advance.
The ultimate investor has lots of options of what can be done with the security. The investor may
hold onto the security to its full maturity. The investor may even sell the security to another investor
and may also use the security as collateral for a repo transaction. Securitization is not always as
straight forward as just explained. Often times various steps in the process are duplicated in order to
incorporate more loans or to spin off additional securities.
Source: (Noeth & Sengupta, 2011)
11
The creation of this securities establishes the passing of the proceeds from the sale of the
securities upstream to all of the participating entities in the chain of intermediation. That being the
administrator, the aggregator and the originators of the loans. More simply, the creator of the SPV,
the warehouse bank, and then the originating bank of the loan. This also create a necessity of short-
term funding at each step of the process. This is for two possible reasons. First, the maturity is
mismatched being that the maturity of the securities is of a shorter term than the maturity on the
loan which requires the entity to "roll over:" the securities or use short term funds to pay the
investors. The second is that at each step in the securitization process the short term funding need
arises between the purchase of the loans and their subsequent sale downstream which is arguably the
most common scenario. This short term funding is where the repo transaction, money market funds
become heavily relied upon. Each time an entity utilizes the use of a repo transaction or money
market mutual fund they are performing the function of a bank because they are acquiring funding.
Each step in the securitization process is funded by a "shadow lending" activity to complete the
shadow banking process. The securitization process thus transforms longer term loans, like
mortgages and student loans, which can carry a varying degree to risk levels into financial
instruments of a shorter maturity and can considerably lower the risk. This process as a whole
mimics the function of a bank.
Shadow banking has been criticized as being redundant to traditional banks. Traditional
banking activities and shadow banking activities do achieve the same general purpose of qualitative
asset transformation, however shadow banking achieves this goal in a manner that a traditional bank
cannot. Shadow banking utilizes securitization. Securitization allows for risk diversification across
multiple borrowers, financial products, and physical geographical locations- i.e. different financial
markets. Securitization takes advantage of the economies of scale and scope by segmenting various
different activities of credit intermediation which in turn reduces over call to lending. By providing
12
such a variety of securities that differ in relation to risk and maturity, a better opportunity to
manage portfolios is provides than would normally be considered possible in the traditional banking
model. The most important difference, when securitization is done properly, is an increase of
transparency and disclosure because banks now sell assets that are then scrutinized during
securitization that they would otherwise just hold on in their rather opaque balance sheets.
a. Alternative payment forms12
Payment systems around the world have generally been operated and maintained by banks.
The processing of retail payments is another important core function of the financial system. The
way in which payment systems are developing as a result of innovative new technologies and
demand for increased convenience is leading payment systems to move outside of traditional bank.
This shift results in lower revenues for traditional banks which have in the past been very reliant on
such fees. These shadow banks which participate in the payment process have created secure
methods which mimic and can complete entire transaction without the need of a traditional bank.
Traditional banks role as the intermediary for payments is a product of these entities have
large deposits of liquid assets from depositors as well as the interconnectedness of traditional banks
throughout the financial system. Banks can transfer funds between each other in order to satisfy the
transactions between buyers and sellers with ease. As technology continues to advance, shadow
banks are beginning to fill in some, if not all, of those roles. "Most non-banks have specific and
limited functions in retail payment systems, such as providing customer interface or back-office
12 Although alternative payment forms are not a source of lending, they are important as a demonstration of how
shadow banking is advancing on all fronts on the model of traditional banking.
13
services for payment networks run by banks. Some non-banks also provide clearing and settlement
services to banks, thus playing a much larger role as an integral part of payment processing."13
Over the last several decades, electronic noncash payments have grown rapidly. The scale of
non-cash payments is enormous with an estimated 334 billion transactions globally in 2012.14
Bank
cards accounted for 61% of total number of non-cash transactions.15
Credit transfers and direct
debits together accounted for 30% of non-cash transactions.16
The remainder of transactions
consisted of checks, which continue to decline as a share of total transactions.
Electronic payments generally consist of three basic steps: authorization, clearing, and finally
settlement. The initiating step, authorization, consists of the transmission of data to the processor of
the payment for the confirmation of the identity as well as the permission to facilitate the
transaction. The second step, the clearing, involves the aggregating of the transaction. This is the
transmission of the values requested for disbursement and the final "net amount" for the
transaction. The final step, the settlement, is the electronic transfer of the funds to complete the
transaction. It is the "hand shake" between the accounts of the buyer and seller.
Shadow banks are providing similar services. Through the use of online services, shadow
banks are able to complete the entire transaction and can even do so, sometimes, without the need
for a traditional banks involvement. Some of these shadow bank payment companies have created
"closed-loop payments" in which virtual online accounts for buyers and sellers within the online
system are credited and debited without the involvement of traditional banks. Such entities and
services are becoming increasingly popular around the world. In the United States alone, in 2012,
there were over 2 billion of these sort of transaction.17
Not all shadow bank payment systems do by
13 (Borst, 2015)
14 (World Payment Reports, 2014)
15 Id.
16 Id.
17 (Federal Reserve Bank, 2014)
14
pass traditional banks, however. Many systems, such as PayPal, require account settlement with a
bank account or credit card. This does still have an effect on the payment system. For example,
several dozen purchases can be made on PayPal, but when the settlement between PayPal and a
traditional bank occurs there is only one transaction for the total amount of all purchases executed
using PayPal's payment service. One transaction which is the total of dozens of transactions.
This results in lower revenues from transaction fees for the bank. There are currently a variety of
other shadow bank payment services that are similar or identical to the model by which PayPal has
come to function and become widely used and embraced around the world
The growth of these shadow bank payment services helps fosters innovation as well as
improve efficiency in the current market place for transactions. Traditional banks view these new
alternatives as a challenge to their well-established structure of fees by which large sums of revenue
are generated. Without absolute regulation, traditional banks will have to adopt in terms of
technology as well as re-evaluating the manner and method by which fees are assessed for electronic
transactions.
b. P2P Lending
As a result of banks restructuring and focus on conforming to new regulatory standards
since the financial crisis new alternatives have percolated which also contributes to the shadow
banking sector. These smaller shadow bank entities take the forms as payday lenders, pawnbrokers
and even loan sharks as well as other similar "institutions". Nobody is too worried by competition to
banks in their ancillary businesses: if, say, Google can help people manage their money more
efficiently, that is to be welcomed.18
The most important and potentially revolutionizing for the
18 (The Economist, 2014)
15
financial sector is a form of "grassroots finance" known as peer-to-peer (P2P) lending. The worry is
in the creation of credit intermediation, which P2P does not do. It is a good thing that lending
outside the banking system is expanding.
P2P Lending is a process by which any range of entities in search of funds are matched,
generally by an online electronic intermediary, to entities which are seeking to lend. Lending entities
earn a higher interest rate than what is currently possible on a deposit at a bank while the borrowers
generally will pay less than they would have to pay for a loan from a bank.
Peer-to-peer lending is developing around the world at a fast pace. Growth is seen in large
volumes. In Britain, loan volumes are doubling every six months. They have just passed the £1
billion mark ($1.7 billion), though this is tiny against the country’s £1.2 trillion in retail deposits.19
In
America, the two largest P2P lenders, Lending Club and Prosper, have 98% of the market.20
They
issued $2.4 billion in loans in 2013, up from $871m in 2012.21
The scale of P2P is still modest in size. The two largest P2P lending firms in the United
States have thus far lent only $5 billion combined.22
This is small in comparison to the total
personal-loan market of $1.8 trillion in the United States.23
But the rate of growth is rapid. At the
smaller of the two, Prosper, the value of new loans agreed in March totaled $77million, which was
more than four times that a year earlier.24
Its lending has grown by 3,000% in eight years. Such
exponential growth is a common theme in this sector.25
Another common theme, for now, is that
default are low.
19 (The Economist, 2014)
20 Id.
21 Id.
22 (The Economist, 2014)
23 Id.
24 Id.
25 Id.
16
These P2P loans are generally an unsecured personal loan regardless if it is a business or a
private individual. Some P2P intermediaries even allow the investor to decide the loans to which
they ultimately underwrite. Additionally, P2P intermediaries can also bundle the loans for investors,
or multiple investors, in a securitized fashion in order to give a dynamic return with inherent
security.
Regulators are also taking note of P2P lending. The new worry about P2P lending is that a
poorly managed platform might collapse and take all of the investors’ money in the collapse. Funds
placed with P2P lenders are not covered by the state-backed guarantees that protect retail deposits in
banks. At a conference organized by the P2P Finance Association executives were worried about the
risks of a “Bitcoin-style bust” that could rattle confidence in the new and fragile lending sector. New
regulatory rules are likely to insist that P2P businesses create separate funds gathered from savers
and coordinate for third parties to manage outstanding loans if they cease trading. Some platforms
offer something of a substitute. Zopa and most other British companies have started “provision
funds”, which aim (but do not promise) to make good on loans that sour.26
These smooth the risk
for lenders, but blunt the original P2P concept. Purists fear such arrangements could recreate the
moral hazard that has plagued conventional banking.
The promising aspect to P2P intermediaries in the shadow banking sector is that in the event
of a default on a loan the loss is passed directly to the lender. The reason why this is important is
because it does not place traditional deposits at risk at a traditional bank nor does it place any
burden on central bank deposit insurance. P2P intermediary lending allows for access to liquidity
and assets in a manner in which that does not ultimately put any adverse risk to the tax payer. In
addition, P2P lending also ends the worrisome and dangerous mismatches often seen in other areas
of shadow banking between short-term deposits and long-term loans inherent in conventional
26 (The Economist, 2014)
17
banking but generally by locking lenders in for the loan’s duration.27
It is a system of "lender
beware" which is in conformity to the new modern idea of investments and investing.
c. Inter-connectedness
Inter-connectedness between shadow banks and traditional banks poses a significant threat
to the viability and sustainability of financial systems in specific countries and the greater global
financial system. As what was discovered in the financial crisis, traditional banks and shadow banks
were significantly inter-connected to such an extent that failures and runs that occurred outside of
the traditional banking sector caused great stress and strain on traditional banks by a phenomenon
known as contagion.
Inter-connectedness takes two main forms. These forms are direct and indirect links. Direct
links are established when shadow banks are either forming part of a traditional banks credit
intermediation process, or are directly owned by a traditional bank, or are benefiting from direct
support from a traditional bank. Indirect linkages are established when both shadow banks and
traditional banks have invested in similar assets or are exposed to common entities.
According to the FSB report on global shadow banking, interconnectedness has declined on
a year over year basis.28
Traditional banks assets to OFI's(shadow bank entities) declined from $4.3
trillion at the end of 2012 to #$3.9 trillion at the end of 2013.29
Traditional banks liabilities to OFIs
declined as well from $4.7 trillion to $4.4 trillion.30
Additionally, Australia and Chile experienced the
most decrease in the exposure of their traditional banking system to shadow bank entities. Not all
countries have experienced the same results. Spain as well as the Netherlands have seen increases of
27 Id.
28 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
29 Id.
30 Id.
18
risk. In fact the funding risk for traditional banks, which is the extent to which traditional banks rely
on shadow banks for funding, showed the greatest increases in Indonesia, India, Italy, and Spain.
Modest increases were seen in the United Kingdom and Brazil. The countries with the highest
growth all remain around 5% of banks total assets which is not a significantly alarming statistic in
the aggregate. Yet, the United Kingdom and Brazil saw moderate increases when already they each
maintain a very high level of bank asset percentage.
Source: (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
19
III. Global reality of shadow banking
Shadow banking is a global reality. Shadow banking has become the single greatest
alternative to traditional banking activity. This is made apparent by the absolute enormity of the
shadow banking sector. Using data from the Financial Stability Board's Global Shadow Banking
Monitoring Report (GSBMR) an analysis of the global shadow banking sector as well as the shadow
banking sectors in key financial jurisdictions and financial regions can help better understand the
current state of the shadow banking sector and it's future. The total coverage of the monitoring
report accounts for nearly 80% of global GDP as well as roughly 90% of the global financial
system.31
Shadow banking is a complement and a valuable addition to traditional banking in that it
expands access to credit as well as spreading risk and providing more liquidity to the markets. In
developing economies finance companies and microcredit lenders often provide credit and
investments to underbanked communities. In advanced economies, various types of financial
intermediaries have been stepping in to provide long-term credit to the private sector while banks
have been reorganizing their balance sheets in order to be compliant with new regulatory structures
(see: April 2014 Global Financial Stability Report). Lending activities by shadow bank entities is a
significant portion of total lending activity in the United States economy and is rising in many
countries as well, notably in the European Union.
Although there are many obvious and valuable benefits to the shadow banking sector, the
global financial crisis exposed that without proper regulation shadow banking can put the stability of
the financial system at a serious risk. In advanced economies, some shadow bank entities, like money
31 Id.
20
market funds and SPVs, were highly leveraged or had large holdings of illiquid assets leading up to
the crisis. As a result they were fatally vulnerable to ensuing "runs" when investors withdrew massive
quantities of assets with hardly any notice. This led to a fire sales of assets which in turn intensified
the financial fallout by depressing the value of assets and resulted in traditional banks feeling the
heat and stress of the collapse. Since the crisis, economies and government around the world have
undergone regulatory reforms in cooperation with each other and the FSB. The FSB has been
instrumental in these reforms because the FSB has recommended greater transparency on asset
values, governance improvements, reforms on ownership of assets, stricter oversight and most
importantly improved regulation of shadow banks.
In advanced economies, shadow banking appears to be shifting to less-well-monitored
activities in the wake of new regulations. Only investment funds, especially bond funds, country
specific entities, and “other” entities continued to grow after 2008.32
The growth of the “other”
entities signals a shift in risk to financial stability toward the newer and less understood activities and
could perhaps suggests that these may comprise new forms of direct lending and over-the-counter
derivatives trading.
In emerging market economies, overall growth of shadow banking remains strong. Shadow
banking assets as a proportion of GDP expanded from 6 percent to 35 percent between 2002 and
2012, while banking sector assets grew from 30 percent to 70 percent of GDP over the same
period.33
This growth, however, can be characterized as a normal part of an emerging economy
continuing to develop its financial markets. The growth of shadow banking has been led by the
growth of activities and financial companies that operate financial instruments similar to that of
MMFs. In some countries, including Brazil and South Africa, mutual funds have also been growing
32 (International Monetary Fund, October 2014)
33 Id.
21
strongly; in others, including Mexico and Turkey, real estate investment trusts have expanded
especially fast (albeit from a low base). In dollar terms, China’s shadow banking sector became the
fifth largest among FSB jurisdictions in 2012.34
a. Financial Stability Board Monitoring
The focus of the monitoring is to look at all non-bank financial intermediation. There are
two measures, broad and narrow, in which the GSBMR measures the shadow banking sector. The
broad measure is referred to as the Monitoring Universe of Non-Bank Financial Intermediation
(MUNFI).35
The data collected by MUNFI castes a wide net in collection of data that is relative to
shadow banking. Thus, the data inherently captures elements that do not strictly meet all the
characteristics that are embodied in shadow banking as it is currently understood. The narrow
measure focusses on the subset of non-bank credit intermediation which does potentially pose
systemic risk to the financial system. A set of criteria are applied to the data in order to narrow down
and filter out entities that are not part of credit intermediation.
The broad measure (MUNFI), thus, is measured by the global financial assets of other
financial intermediates in a specific country or geographical region. Whereas, the narrow measure
takes the data from the MUNFI and withdraws financial assets of non -bank financial entities not
involved in bank-like credit intermediation, financial assets related to those non-bank financial
entities that are prudentially consolidated into a banking group, financial entities whose activities do
not exhibit risks associated with shadow banking including maturity and liquidity transformation or
34 Id.
35 It is important to note, however, that in regional analysis by FSB Regional Consultative Groups(RCG) may deviate
from the standard process as outlined by the FSB. RCG's may exercise this discretion in order to better accommodate
region or nation specific entities that perform shadow banking functions that might otherwise be left out by the standard
FSB process. The goal of each assessment, either by the FSB or a RCG, is to ensure the capturing of data and statistics
which most accurately outlines the various risk implications associated with shadow banking.
22
leverage. The broad measure as well as the narrow measure of shadow banking are both important
indicators of the size, composition and growth trends of non-bank financial intermediaries.
Source: (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
FSB broad estimates shows an increase in shadow banking activity in the euro area, the
United Kingdom, and the United States, while narrower gauges of shadow banking might suggest
stagnation at first glance. After a mild drop around 2008, the FSB measures show varying degrees of
recovery in the United States, the euro area, and the United Kingdom. In contrast, the flow of funds
and noncore liabilities measures remain broadly constant, which reflects two opposing forces: the
decline in the role of certain activities after the crisis, such as securitization and lending via repos and
securities, and a concomitant rise in other activities, including those of country-specific entities. The
pickup in the FSB measures can be partly explained by positive valuation effects from the growth in
the investment fund industry. The large difference between broad and narrow measures reflects
significant activity within the financial system that is not fully captured by other shadow banking
measures.
The goal of the new regulation is to replace a shadow banking system which was prone to
failure due to excess with a shadow banking system that contribute to strong, sustainable balanced
23
growth in the global economy.36
The time is coming now where shadow banking is coming out of
the “shadows” and is to become a sustainable and contributing market based financial competent of
the greater financial sector in the world.
b. Shadow Banking in the United States
Shadow banking in the United States can trace its origins back to securitization in the 1970s,
when Ginnie Mae, a Government Sponsored Enterprise(GSE), began to guarantee mortgage pass-
through securities, as a way to foster the secondary mortgage market and promote
homeownership.37
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, both GSE's as well, followed shortly thereafter.
From there securitization quickly spread to other areas and in the 1980s the first "asset backed
security" was created. The growth in shadow bank activity continued to grow and in 1989 began to
outpace the activity of traditional banks. Shadow banking has continued to do so through 2007.38
Despite the serious losses and new regulatory framework which is requiring banks in the US
to reorganize, total shadow bank liabilities still measure in size nearly in equal amounts to traditional
banks. Although the past five years of shadow banking activity in the United States has been on the
decline, this trend is now seen to be reversing. As the American economy continues to grow and
improve, so does the growth in demand for access to credit. The increase in regulatory requirements
in the United States gives shadow banks a competitive advantage against their traditional counter
parts.
36 (Carney, 2014)
37 (TD Bank Group, 2014)
38 Id.
24
Source: (Adrian & Ashcraft, Shadow Banking Regulation, 2014)
The size of the financial assets/liabilities of the US shadow banking system was nearly USD
20 trillion in March 2008 and USD 15 trillion in the second quarter of 2011, larger than the
traditional banking system.39
The shadow banking sector is not as big as the peak in 2008, but gross
liabilities of shadow banking are just slightly below liability of traditional banks. Shadow liabilities
increased by over $200 billion in 2013.40
This was roughly one-quarter of the lending that was done
by traditional banks.41
In the second half of 2013, shadow bank liabilities increased by 60 cents for
every dollar in traditional bank liabilities.42
The recent growth is captured in agency and GSE backed
securities as well as MMFs.43
This indicates that “increased capital and liquidity standards for
depository institutions and insurance companies are likely to increase the returns to shadow banking
activity.” Although many indicators point to the continued growth in shadow banking activity in the
39 (Pozsar, Adrian, Ashcraft, & Boesky, 2010)
40 (TD Bank Group, 2014)
41 Id.
42 Id.
43 (Pozsar, Adrian, Ashcraft, & Boesky, 2010)
25
United States, regulators are keen to implement regulation on shadow banking as to strength the
entirety of the financial sector to prevent previous errors and gaps in regulation in 2008.
The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act substantially changed
the nature of shadow banking in the United States, among many of its implementations throughout
the financial sector. Dodd-Frank now requires issuers of ABS and ABCP to maintain a portion of
the issuance on balance sheet. This makes issuance of such instruments more expensive and impacts
the commercial viability of the products as well because of the new capital liquidity standards as
established by Basel III. At the same time, these regulations have also fostered improved
transparency of the instruments. Furthermore, the SEC has placed restrictions on the amount of
maturity and the amount of liquidity transformation that may take place with a MMF.
Even with the greater regulatory oversight, the growth in shadow banking remains
significant. Continued innovation in the future of financial products creates new opportunities for
substantial growth potential in a perpetually dynamic financial sector. Economists at the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York expect “shadow banking to adapt to these new regulations” and “new
forms of regulatory arbitrage and shadow banking to emerge.”44
Shadow banking declined significantly during the crisis and subsequent recession in the
United States. The recovery has been slow. As stronger more resilient balance sheet for traditional
banks has improved competition among traditional banks, the recovery and growth in the economy
is fueling growth in shadow banking. The recovery in shadow banking will continue to garner much
attention as investors are looking to see how a newly regulated shadow banking system will continue
to enhance credit intermediation in the financial sector after its disastrous contribute to the financial
crisis.
44 (Adrian & Ashcraft, Shadow Banking Regulation, 2014)
26
c. Shadow Banking in the European Union
Shadow banking is also finding its place in the European Union. Although overall shadow
banking in the EU is smaller than that of the activity in the United States, it is still significant. The
shadow banking sector in the EU is roughly valued at €10.8 trillion in 2011. This accounts for
around 38% of total bank activity in the euro area. The shadow banking sector in the EU also differs
greatly from that of the United States. The sector is very stable in terms of growth and traditional
banks continue to be the main source of credit intermediation in Europe. Roughly three times the
amount of assets are intermediated by traditional banks than shadow banks in the euro area.
It is worth noting that, in the second quarter of 2011, almost 70% of the assets of the “other
intermediaries” grouping (€7.6 trillion) were held by miscellaneous financial institutions. A stock-
taking exercise carried out by the European System of Central Banks (ESCB) in 2009 revealed that
around 19% of the residual “other miscellaneous intermediaries” correspond to financial holding
companies, captive institutions (i.e. those providing financial services to a limited group of
companies) and money lenders.45
Moreover, 15% is constituted by non-deposit taking institutions
engaging in lending (factoring, leasing and other forms) and 10% by securities and derivatives
dealers.46
A remaining 52% is made up of unidentified miscellaneous financial institutions. An
important part of the euro area financial sector remains therefore relatively unexplored by official
statistics.47
Securitization is smaller in volume in the euro area than in the United States. However, the
euro area is not a homogenous group—witness the strength of shadow banking in a country like the
Netherlands where non-financial banking institutions (NFBI) have the largest percentage of total
45 (Bakk-Simon, Borgioli, & Giron, 2012)
46 Id.
47 Id.
27
assets (45%) compared to the US (35%), the euro area (30%), and the UK (25%)48
. In fact, euro area
banks have increasingly been relying on funding from other financial institutions, including
securitization vehicles.49
In order to identify the possible systemic relevance of shadow banking, it is important to
understand the interconnections with the regulated banking system. Over the recent past, the
interconnectedness between traditional banks and shadow banks has increased, which has also
increased Europe's exposure to contagion from runs in the shadow banking sector.
The British proportion of shadow banking operations relative to traditional banking is much
greater than in continental Europe. This may be explained by the strong connections of British
banks with the City. Another characteristic of British banks, but also of French and Spanish banks,
is the development of their activities at the international level, much more so than most US banks.
The move into the international financial area is largely due to the response to increased competition
and increased globalized standards among traditional banks. Although the response is to new
financial stimuli, this is not necessarily a new phenomenon. For the United Kingdom, France and
Spain, the internationalization of banking activity is a compliment and parallel to those countries as
colonial powers. Another factor which encouraged the expansion of banks abroad more recently
was European integration. Due to the creation of the European area and the Eurozone, banks are
much more internationalized and convene business on a scale that is unique to most of the world.50
Overall, shadow banking activities in Europe have the pedigree to become a serious threat to
the economy. However, due to the current climate of the European economy and regulation already
established, the majority of financial activity is currently taking place in the traditional banking
sector. However, there is room for growth to be made in the shadow banking sector which can help
48 (Jeffers & Plihon, 2014)
49 Id.
50 Id.
28
grow the European economy as a whole similar to how the shadow banking sector is making
improvements in the American economy. Despite the potential room for growth, regulators and
bankers alike need to be keenly aware of the interconnectedness not only between traditional banks
and shadow banks in Europe, but also between banks in the euro area and banks in the United
States. Close interconnectedness is what helped spread the crisis in its infancy. Regulators need to
take steps to curb this potential threat.
d. Shadow Banking in China
While shadow banking in the United States and European Union has seen somewhat of a
decline or stagnation since the financial crisis, China's shadow banking sector continues to flourish
and grow. Shadow banks, which barely existed before China’s credit surge in 2009, now have assets
of at least 30 trillion yuan ($4.9 trillion), or more than 50% of GDP, according to estimates by ANZ
Bank.51
This is alarming. This growth in the shadow banking sector of China has been fueled by
concerns of traditional bank credit intermediation as well as concerns over growing inflation. The
Chinese government, in 2010, established strategic restrictions on the traditional banking system
through the implementation of increasing interest rates and increased reserve requirements.52
These
new regulations slowed the growth rate of the credit intermediation that was of concern. Very
quickly traditional banks found ways to keep originating credit by the use of off balance sheet
entities. Now, the fastest growing source of credit origination comes from the shadow banking
sector. Non-bank financial institutions accounted for nearly half of the growth in credit in China in
2013. Concerns now fall on one specific type of financial entity, trusts.
51 (The Economist, 2014)
52 (Adrian, Ashcraft, & Cetorelli, Shadow Bank Monitoring, 2013)
29
Trusts are created when bank loans are bought by trust companies. These trust companies
then sell to retail depositors various wealth management products. Banks earn fees on the
origination of loans and management of these products, but since they are off balance sheet, they do
not have to hold capital against them.53
These product also lack any form of a guarantee, generally.
More often than not, the perception is that these products carry an implicit official sector support
via a state bank. Trusts have grown very quickly in part because the central bank has limited the
traditional banks' ability to lend to economic sectors in which there is an observable overinvestment,
for example coalmining and real property. Trusts raise money by offering an attractive returns that
traditional banks could not and then lend to sectors that the regulator have prohibit traditional
banks from lending. As a result, commercial businesses in these economic sector have few
alternatives or options other than seeking funding from the shadow banking sector. Additionally,
China's central bank has placed a cap on interest for deposits which reduces Chinese savers’ return
on deposit. As a result, savings accounts produce a meager 0.35% a year and a one-year fixed deposit
earns 3.3%, which is hardly incentivizing.54
That makes trust products attractive for investors. Much
like other parts of the world, shadow banking is an opportunistic alternative of last resort for
financial mobility and success.
In addition to trust loans, there also exists entrusted loans. These are loans originated by
non-banks which are cash-rich companies that desire to lend to other companies in order to put
their capital to work. These non-bank loans are sold to trust companies and serviced by banks.
Banks also use entrusted loans as a mechanism to continue originating loan to circumvent the loan
quota restrictions, which funds the off balance sheet entity. Banks, as a result of these shadow
53 Id.
54 (The Economist, 2014)
30
activities, have increased their stake of ownership in various trust companies to better facilitate
distribution channel.
Source: (The Economist, 2014)
Historically, Increases in a country’s debt on the scale of China’s have almost always ended
in a financial crisis of some sort. In the event that a series of defaults occur in the trust sector,
investors would lose faith in these high-yield investment products. That would result in short-term
lending elements drying up, leaving many banks in a crippled position to continue financing.
China’s trust sector resembles the pre-crisis activity of shadow banking in many western
economies. Much of it looks like a blatant attempt by Chinese banks to get around the restrictions
regulators have placed on them. Trust companies are essentially thinly veiled covering for banks. A
conduit to allow the banks to sell the financial instrument that they otherwise could not due to
regulatory restrictions.
The rise of shadow banking in China appears to not be the result of financial innovation, but
actually driven by the reaction of the tightly regulated economic sectors and the heightened
restrictions to the traditional banking sector. Fortunately for China and the world, China has the
financial capacity to absorb many non-performing loans which would prevent an ill-fated "run" on
31
the banks. Standard & Poor’s, a ratings agency, argues that reforms could lead to “a turbulent period
in which funding could dry up as the domestic market struggles to re-price risk”.55
In addition,
combined debts (shadow and traditional) in China are smaller in relation to China's GDP than many
combined debts in western economies leading up to the financial crisis.
e. Shadow Banking in Asia
The Working Group on Shadow Banking of the FSB Regional Consultative Group for Asia
(RCGA) conducted a study on shadow banking in Asia. The Working Group conducted a survey
among RCGA members to examine the profile of non-bank financial intermediaries (NBFIs), the
regulations governing these entities, the definition of shadow banking applied by members, the
distinction between shadow banking and NBFIs, the potential risks emanating from NBFIs and the
applicability of FSB’s recommendations on shadow banking to Asia.
The RCGA is comprised of Australia, Cambodia, China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia,
Japan, Korea, Malaysia, New Zealand, Pakistan, Philippines, Singapore, Sri Lanka, Thailand and
Vietnam.5657
Ten of the 16 members of this group are classified as emerging economies based on
standard economic indicators.58
In the emerging economies, shadow banking provides commercial
entities and individual’s access to credit where traditional banks could not or are absent from the
local market.59
This has allowed for greater liquidity and economic inclusion to a larger audience who
would otherwise be forgotten. Shadow banking activity in Asia is not a systemic threat nor does it
account for a significant portion of total finance. In addition, the vast majority of the shadow
55 (The Economist, 2014)
56 (Financial Stability Board, February 2015)
57 Analysis for China is markedly different than the rest of the region due to the national specific entities in the shadow
banking sector and due to the enormous size and growth of the Chinese economy.
58 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
59 Id.
32
banking activity is domestic with minimal risk from cross-border transaction. The financial systems
in the Asian economies remains "traditional bank" dominant.60
Shadow banking activities account
for less than half of total assets in the financial system.61
However, the amount of shadow banking
activity in each country does vary greatly. China and Japan have large and intricate shadow banking
sectors. Total OFI assets in Japan comprise roughly half of all OFI assets in Asia.62
Furthermore,
Hong Kong and Singapore are major financial centers in Asia and as a result have a large OFI asset
amount in relation to the size of their economies.
Asian markets should continue to move towards more innovative and sophisticated financial
markets in order to ensure economic development by increasing the efficiency of the allocated
savings available and the financial stability of the region.63
This is also important for the global
economy to help alleviate the global imbalances and the associated reserves accumulated in the
Asian region which is partly to blame for a lack of financial sophistication in the region.64
As a whole Asia is not at risk from shadow banking like other major economies, United
States and European Union for example, due to the fact that the financial markets in Asia are not as
wholly developed as their western counterparts nor are the products they offer at the same level of
complexity like they are offered in America and Europe.65
Financial products originating from non-
banks is just not complex nor enormous enough to pose a serious risk to the financial stability of
Asia as a whole. This is a very positive statistic because it allows for the Asian economies to
continue to grow and develop and use shadow banking in a manner that helps promote economic
growth and financial stability. The future for Asia's financial sectors, both shadow and traditional,
60 Id.
61 NBFIs comprise 33%, OFIs comprise 15%
62 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
63 (Hannoun, 2008)
64 Id.
65 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
33
are very bright so long as shadow banking is use responsibly while traditional banks are regulated in
accordance with the high quality international standard.
f. Shadow Banking in Switzerland
Switzerland has long been known as a majorly important financial, and more importantly,
banking hub in the world. According to data collected by the MUNFI and after the implementation
of the narrowing down criteria, Switzerland's shadow banking sector is roughly USD $502 billion
(CHF 481 billion).6667
This corresponds to roughly 81% of Swiss GDP.68
When applying the shadow
banking activities as defined by the FSB, Switzerland's shadow banking sector reduces to (CHF 315
billion) which accounts for 53% of Swiss GDP.69
Switzerland maintains a relatively low risk to financial stability issues related to shadow
banking. This can be attributed to three reasons. First, the size of Switzerland's shadow banking
sector is significantly smaller than its traditional banking sector unlike many other countries and
regions. Second, the assets that are in existence in the shadow banking sector are believed to be of
low to moderate bank-like systemic risk. This means that even in the event of a disruption in the
shadow banking sector, the resulting issues would be minor and very well manageable. Third, bond
funds are other investment funds, which make up 60% of shadow banking assets in Switzerland are
supervised by the Swiss Financial Market Supervisory Authority (FINMA).70
66 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
67 CHF1.00 = $1.017 USD, XE Currency Conversion
68 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
69 Id.
70 Id.
34
IV. Financial Stability Board Policy and Regulations
The FSB71
monitors and assesses vulnerabilities affecting the global financial system and
proposes actions needed to address them. In addition, it monitors and advises on market and
systemic developments, and their implications for regulatory policy.72
Transforming shadow banking into resilient market-based financing has been one of the
core elements of the FSB’s regulatory reform agenda to address the fault lines that contributed to
the global financial crisis and to build safer, more sustainable sources of financing for the real
economy.73
Two major issues were made apparent in the aftermath of the financial crisis that were
contributory to the crisis itself. These two issues centered on a heavy reliance of short-term
wholesale funding, a variety of incentive problems in securitized and structured finance markets that
weakened lending standards, and a general lack of transparency that hid growing amounts of
leverage and maturity mismatch, as well as the ultimate bearer of the associated risks.74
As the prices
dropped for securitized assets, the terms for collateralized financing constricted, which then
triggered a fire sales particularly by investors who were significantly mismatched and leveraged. As
the markets grinded up to a halt, several investment vehicles became insolvent and failed, MMMFs
experienced quick panic runs, and the entire shadow banking system came to a screeching halt. The
viability of the banking system was also threatened and the supply of credit to the real economy was
drastically restricted.
The FSB has adopted a two-pronged strategy to deal with these issues, which they call "fault
lines." First, the FSB has created a system-wide monitoring framework to track developments in the
shadow banking system with a view to identifying the build-up of systemic risks and initiating
71 The FSB was established in April 2009 as the successor to the Financial Stability Forum (FSF)
72 (Financial Stability Board, 2015)
73 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014)
74 Id.
35
corrective actions where necessary.75
Second, the FSB is coordinating and contributing to the
development of policy measures in five areas where oversight and regulation needs to be
strengthened to reduce excessive build-up of leverage, as well as maturity and liquidity mismatching
in the system: (i) mitigating risks in banks’ interactions with shadow banking entities; (ii) reducing
the susceptibility of MMFs to “runs”; (iii) improving transparency and aligning incentives in
securitization; (iv) dampening pro-cyclicality and other financial stability risks in securities financing
transactions such as repos and securities lending; and (v) assessing and mitigating financial stability
risks posed by other shadow banking entities and activities.76
a. System wide monitoring
The first prong of the approach to address the issues from the financial crisis as established
by the FSB is the implementation of system wide monitoring. This monitoring assess sources of
systemic risks. The FSB has thus begun conducting annual monitoring exercises to assess global
trends and risks in the shadow banking system. These exercises have prompted an increasing
number of national and regional authorities to regularly assess the risks of their own shadow banking
sectors. The system wide monitoring now covers a total of 25 jurisdictions which represents 80% of
global GDP and 90% of global financial system assets.77
In addition, the FSB’s Regional
Consultative Groups (RCGs) of the Americas and Asia (which include non-FSB member
authorities) have recently started to conduct their own monitoring based on the annual FSB
monitoring exercises.78
75 Id.
76 Id.
77 Several jurisdictions (e.g. Australia, Canada, Germany and the Netherlands) and the European Central Bank (ECB)
have also published analyses of their respective shadow banking system, leveraging on the FSB annual monitoring
exercises. The International Monetary Fund has conducted some analysis using the data collected in the FSB annual
monitoring exercise in their October 2014 Global Financial Stability Report
(http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2014/02/pdf/ c2.pdf).
78 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014)
36
The increase in monitoring on a national and regional scale better covers jurisdictions where
shadow banking entities are often located which helps increase the understanding of their operations
and the risks they might contain as well as the benefits to which are applied. As monitoring
continues and improves it is expected that these exercises will continue to benefit from further
improvements in collecting data by jurisdictions and rectify identified data gap inconsistencies.
b. Improved oversight
The second issue the FSB is addressing through its policy recommendations is the improvement of
oversight.79
In coordinating and contributing to the development of policy measures, the FSB has
addressed five areas where oversight and regulation needs to be strengthened to reduce excessive
build-up of leverage, as well as maturity and liquidity mismatching in the system.
i. Mitigating risk in banks’ interactions with shadow banking activities
The financial crisis revealed that both the shadow banking sector and the traditional banking
sector were both intertwined with each other leading to heavy risk exposures. The FSB requested
the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) to develop the policy recommendations to
ensure that future risk spill-over to traditional banks from shadow bank are mitigated.
The BCBS put forth the following recommendations: (i) risk-sensitive capital requirements
for banks’ investments in the equity of funds; and (ii) the supervisory framework for measuring and
controlling banks’ large exposures.80
The first requirement establishes a more consistent and risk-
sensitive approach for computing regulatory capital requirements for banks’ investments in equity of
79 Id.
80 Id.
37
funds, by appropriately reflecting both the risk of the fund’s underlying investments and its leverage.
Implementation goes into effect on 1 January 2017.
The supervisory framework for limiting banks’ large exposures to single counterparties seeks
to protect the traditional banking sector from the risk of default of shadow bank entities. In order to
meet the goal of this framework, the definition of a large exposure is now strengthened to limit
carve outs and exemptions which shadow banks were previously able to take advantage of and to
more clearly and consistently capture exposures to funds, securitization structures and other
vehicles.81
Banks will also be subject to a hard limit on large exposures of 25% of Tier 1 capital (15%
for global systemically important banks), which is more prudent than the 25% of total capital
currently applied in most jurisdictions.82
The framework will be fully implemented by 1 January
2019.
ii. Reducing the susceptibility of MMFs to “runs”
During the financial crisis, MMFs proved wildly susceptible to contagion. The basis of the
policy as implemented by the FSB originates from the IOSCO which provides the basis for
common standards of regulation and the management of MMF worldwide. It also includes
recommendations that regulators are to require a conversion of MMFs that have a stable Net Asset
Value(NAV) to a floating Net Asset Value.
National and regional authorities have since made progress in adjusting and implementing
their regulatory frameworks for MMFs in conformity with these reforms. Notably, the world’s
largest MMF market, the United States, adopted amendments to the rules which govern MMFs that
specifically addressed risk of investor runs and maintained the benefits of MMFs.83
81 Id.
82 Id.
83 (Securities and Exchange Commission, 2014)
38
iii. Improving transparency and aligning incentives in securitization
The IOSCO published a series of reforms that are embraced by the FSB in order to improve
the transparency and alignment of incentives in securitization. These reforms improved
transparency, created a high quality and standardized risk retention requirement, and established
standardized disclosures.84
After review of the implementations on a national and regional level, the
preliminary findings indicate good progress has been made in implementing the recommendations.
A majority jurisdictions having adopted measures or taken some actions to implement the
recommendations. The resumption of sound securitization is a goal of the wider financial reform
program.
iv. Dampening pro-cyclicality and other financial stability risks in securities financing transactions such as repos and
securities lending
Securities financing transactions, including lending through securities and repo agreements
are central to financial intermediaries market making activities as well as to their various investment
and risk management strategies. Such transaction, however, are used also by shadow banks to
conduct their bank-like activities which carries obvious inherent risk from a maturity perspective as
well as liquidity transformation and risks associated with leverage.
Policy recommendations have now been put forth to reduce the risks associated with the
dependence by shadow banks have so heavily relied for a source of their wholesale short term
funding. The recommendations are standards and processes for data collection and aggregation at
the global level to enhance transparency of securities financing markets; minimum standards on cash
84 (Deutsch, 2012)
39
collateral reinvestments; requirements on re-hypothecation85
; minimum regulatory standards for
collateral valuation and management; and policy recommendations related to structural aspects of
the securities financing markets.86
These measures will help reduce excessive leverage and in turn dampen the pro-cyclicality in
financial markets. The potential impact and unintended consequences are not yet fully understood.
The FSB continues to measure and monitor the potential impact and is currently conducting a two
stage quantitative impact assessment to ensure the goals are met by the most efficient manner.
v. Assessing and mitigating systemic risks posed by other shadow banking entities and activities
Recognizing that shadow banking entities and activities take a variety of forms and evolve
over time, the FSB has developed a forward-looking high-level policy framework for adoption by
authorities to detect and assess the sources of financial stability risks from shadow banking in the
non-bank financial space, and apply appropriate policy measures where necessary to mitigate these
risks.87
The framework comprises: (i) an assessment of non-bank financial entity types based on five
economic functions88
; (ii) the adoption of policy tools to mitigate financial stability risks where
necessary; and (iii) information-sharing by FSB member authorities through the FSB process to
maintain international consistency in applying the framework, minimize gaps in regulation and
detect new adaptations.89
By focusing on economic functions (or activities) rather than legal forms,
this framework is intended to allow authorities to capture innovations and adaptations. Furthermore,
85 The practice by banks and brokers of using, for their own purposes, assets that have been posted as collateral by their
clients. Clients who permit re-hypothecation of their collateral may be compensated either through a lower cost of
borrowing or a rebate on fees. (Rehypothecation, 2015)
86 (Financial Stability Board, 2013)
87 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014)
88 Each of the five economic functions involves non-bank credit intermediation that poses bank-like systemic risks (e.g.
maturity/liquidity transformation and leverage).
89 Id.
40
it is expected that the framework will provide a structured process to further enhance the FSB’s
annual monitoring exercise as well as for authorities to assess the need for extending the regulatory
perimeter.
In an active step the FSB has established an information-sharing exercise for the exchange of
information on the status of national and regional authorities’ implementation of the FSB
framework and to improve the detailed information-sharing methods for future uses. Thus far, the
FSB has seen that most non-bank financial entities that authorities judged to be potentially involved
in shadow banking activities have relevant authorities responsible for their oversight, and a range of
policy tools is available to address the respective risks.90
These new regulations are draft in mind of various national reactions and needs across the
global. The FSB sees the benefits as well as the risks that shadow banking and shadow entities pose
to the financial stability of a nation or region. With that in mind, these recommendations are
designed for various legislative bodies and securities authorities to implement in a globally
standardized way to enhance the resilience of shadow banking for the next generation.
V. Conclusion
Shadow banks are proliferating because traditional banks are being stifled by regulations and
continue their mandated reorganizing. Traditional banks have been plagued with losses incurred
during the financial crisis, questionable higher capital requirements, and perpetual legal troubles
coupled with outrageously expensive fines. The traditional banks are reshaping themselves as a
result. Lending has been cut significantly. Shadow banks are filling these gaps. Shadow banking
90 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014)
41
encompasses a wide array of complex financial activities. Activities that regulators seek to either
limit, like securitization, or P2P lending which regulators look to as the future of the banking system.
Regulators are trying to manipulate the shadow banking sector in a good way. The shadow
banking sector was a significant contributor, if not the origins of, the financial crisis of 2007-2008.
Shadow banking became overly leveraged and the clear transparency quickly became opaque and
then as its name implies, shadowy. The shadow banking sector can be very fragile and prone to
instability just like the traditional banking model. In traditional banking this weakness comes from
"runs" on the bank by depositors. This has happened several times throughout history in western
banking. This gave rise to the Great Depression in the United States and then the contagion in
which all other banks become at risk just due to the failure of one bank. Western countries created
deposit insurance in order to mitigate this risk and give depositors the rational comfort that their
deposits are safe even in the worst of financial climates. This is what regulators hope to avoid with
the new plan for the shadow banking sector.
The sector allows greater access to capital and assets without placing risk on the banks and
in turn the tax payers. Now credit can be established by investors who carry the burden and the risk
of default. This allows for greater transparency and an overall healthier financial sector around the
world. Shadow banking is going to continue to be a financial reality. The lessons from 2007-2008
were bitter to swallow, but as the global economy continues its recovery, shadow banking will be
leading the financial industry in giving various economies around the world the access to quick liquid
capital that they need in order to sustain growth and continue to build a stronger, more resilient,
financial market.
42
Bibliography
Adrian, T., & Ashcraft, A. (2014). Shadow Banking Regulation. Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Adrian, T., Ashcraft, A., & Cetorelli, N. (2013). Shadow Bank Monitoring. Federal Reserve Bank of
New York.
Bakk-Simon, K., Borgioli, S., & Giron, C. (2012). Shadow Banking in the Euro Area: An Overview.
European Central Bank.
Borst, N. (2015, January). Non-Banks and Retail Payments: Innovations in China and the United
States. Asia Focus.
Carney, M. (2014, June 16). Taking shadow banking out of the shadows to create sustainable
market-bsaed finance. Financial Times.
Deutsch, T. (2012). Public Comment on Global Development in Securitization Regulation. International
Organization of Securities Commissions.
Federal Reserve Bank. (2014, July 1). The 2013 Federal Reserve Payments Study: Recent and Long-
Term Trends in the United States: 2000–2012.
Financial Stability Board. (2013). Strengthening Oversight and Regulation of Shadow Banking.
Financial Stability Board. (2014). Global Shadow Banking Report.
Financial Stability Board. (2015). What we do. Retrieved from
http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/what-we-do/vulnerabilities-assessment/
Financial Stability Board. (February 2015). List of Members of the FSB Regional consultative group for Asia.
Financial Stability Board. (November 2014). Transforming Shadow Banking into Resilient Market-based
Financing.
Hannoun, H. (2008). Financial deepening without financial excesses. Bank for International Settlements.
International Monetary Fund. (October 2014). Global Financial Stability Report - Risk Taking, Liquidity,
and Shadow Banking: Curbing Excess while promoting Growth. Washington.
Jeffers, E., & Plihon, D. (2014). Universal Banking and Shadow Banking in Europe.
Noeth, B. J., & Sengupta, R. (2011, October). Is Shadow Banking Really Banking? The Regional
Economist.
Pozsar, Z., Adrian, T., Ashcraft, A., & Boesky, H. (2010). Shadow Banking. Federal Reserve Bank of
New York.
Rehypothecation. (2015). Retrieved from Investopedia:
http://www.investopedia.com/terms/r/rehypothecation.asp
43
Securities and Exchange Commission. (2014, July). Money Market Fund Reform, Amendments to
Form PF.
Smith, L. (2015). Off-Balance-Sheet Entities: An Introduction. Retrieved from Investopedia:
http://www.investopedia.com/articles/analyst/022002.asp
TD Bank Group. (2014, May 10). Shadow Banking in America: Bank in the Spotlight. TD Economics.
The Economist. (2014, May 10). A quest of trust. The Economist.
The Economist. (2014, May 1). Banking without banks. The Economist.
The Economist. (2014, September 6). China's shadow banks: A moving target. The Economist.
The Economist. (2014, May 10). Shadow banking in China: Battling the darkness.
The Economist. (2014, May 10). The lure of shadow banking. The Economist.
The Economist. (2014, May 10). We try harder.
World Payment Reports. (2014). Developments in Global Payments Landscape.

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Was ist angesagt?

Functions of commercial banks
Functions of commercial banksFunctions of commercial banks
Functions of commercial banks
Harshit Patni
 
Commercial Banks
Commercial BanksCommercial Banks
Commercial Banks
Rani More
 
Commercial banking
Commercial bankingCommercial banking
Commercial banking
Poonam Patel
 
Retail & wholesale banking done
Retail & wholesale banking doneRetail & wholesale banking done
Retail & wholesale banking done
nileshsen
 
Commercial banking
Commercial bankingCommercial banking
Commercial banking
Dharmik
 

Was ist angesagt? (20)

A
AA
A
 
Universal banking
Universal bankingUniversal banking
Universal banking
 
Functions of commercial banks
Functions of commercial banksFunctions of commercial banks
Functions of commercial banks
 
Financeinenterprisemanagement
FinanceinenterprisemanagementFinanceinenterprisemanagement
Financeinenterprisemanagement
 
Deposits
DepositsDeposits
Deposits
 
chapter 3 : commercial bank
chapter 3 : commercial bank chapter 3 : commercial bank
chapter 3 : commercial bank
 
Consortium Finance
Consortium FinanceConsortium Finance
Consortium Finance
 
Financial Institutions in Vietnam
Financial Institutions in VietnamFinancial Institutions in Vietnam
Financial Institutions in Vietnam
 
Commercial Banks
Commercial BanksCommercial Banks
Commercial Banks
 
Function of commercial bank
Function of commercial bankFunction of commercial bank
Function of commercial bank
 
Commercial bank
Commercial bank Commercial bank
Commercial bank
 
Credit Risk Management and Loan Recovery in Nigerian Deposit Money Banks
Credit Risk Management and Loan Recovery in Nigerian Deposit Money BanksCredit Risk Management and Loan Recovery in Nigerian Deposit Money Banks
Credit Risk Management and Loan Recovery in Nigerian Deposit Money Banks
 
Retail Loans
Retail LoansRetail Loans
Retail Loans
 
Financial Economics - Commercial Banking
Financial Economics - Commercial BankingFinancial Economics - Commercial Banking
Financial Economics - Commercial Banking
 
Wholesale banking
Wholesale bankingWholesale banking
Wholesale banking
 
Choosing you Financial Institution from First Credit Union
Choosing you Financial Institution from First Credit UnionChoosing you Financial Institution from First Credit Union
Choosing you Financial Institution from First Credit Union
 
Commercial banking
Commercial bankingCommercial banking
Commercial banking
 
commercial bank and its functions.
commercial bank and its functions.commercial bank and its functions.
commercial bank and its functions.
 
Retail & wholesale banking done
Retail & wholesale banking doneRetail & wholesale banking done
Retail & wholesale banking done
 
Commercial banking
Commercial bankingCommercial banking
Commercial banking
 

Andere mochten auch

Planeación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonso
Planeación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonsoPlaneación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonso
Planeación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonso
José Alonso Simón
 

Andere mochten auch (15)

Presentacion de computacion
Presentacion de computacionPresentacion de computacion
Presentacion de computacion
 
Historia telecomunicaciones
Historia telecomunicacionesHistoria telecomunicaciones
Historia telecomunicaciones
 
COLORS OF LOVE BY MARVIN UGORJI
COLORS OF LOVE BY MARVIN UGORJICOLORS OF LOVE BY MARVIN UGORJI
COLORS OF LOVE BY MARVIN UGORJI
 
Mixology Benmayor Entertainment
Mixology Benmayor Entertainment Mixology Benmayor Entertainment
Mixology Benmayor Entertainment
 
subh muhrat(summer)
subh muhrat(summer)subh muhrat(summer)
subh muhrat(summer)
 
Anastasia Sleptsova
Anastasia SleptsovaAnastasia Sleptsova
Anastasia Sleptsova
 
Presentacion de computacion
Presentacion de computacionPresentacion de computacion
Presentacion de computacion
 
Menores, alcohol y drogas.
Menores, alcohol y drogas.Menores, alcohol y drogas.
Menores, alcohol y drogas.
 
Sambhalpur catchment Study
Sambhalpur catchment StudySambhalpur catchment Study
Sambhalpur catchment Study
 
Pinturas de joão timane pintura de joão timane artista plástico de moçambique
Pinturas de joão timane pintura de joão timane   artista plástico de moçambiquePinturas de joão timane pintura de joão timane   artista plástico de moçambique
Pinturas de joão timane pintura de joão timane artista plástico de moçambique
 
Planeación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonso
Planeación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonsoPlaneación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonso
Planeación estratégica negociación 1 jose alonso
 
Mensura - Corporate Presentation (French)
Mensura - Corporate Presentation (French)Mensura - Corporate Presentation (French)
Mensura - Corporate Presentation (French)
 
Keluarga anda memiliki asam urat tinggi inilah 25 cara mengobati dan menormal...
Keluarga anda memiliki asam urat tinggi inilah 25 cara mengobati dan menormal...Keluarga anda memiliki asam urat tinggi inilah 25 cara mengobati dan menormal...
Keluarga anda memiliki asam urat tinggi inilah 25 cara mengobati dan menormal...
 
Mensura - Corporate Presentation (Dutch)
Mensura - Corporate Presentation (Dutch)Mensura - Corporate Presentation (Dutch)
Mensura - Corporate Presentation (Dutch)
 
Syllabus 2016 dec-20
Syllabus 2016 dec-20Syllabus 2016 dec-20
Syllabus 2016 dec-20
 

Ähnlich wie Brent Buyse Thesis

Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...
Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...
Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...
RizkiArdiansyah22
 
liquidity concepts, instruments and procedure
liquidity concepts, instruments and procedureliquidity concepts, instruments and procedure
liquidity concepts, instruments and procedure
Samiksha Chawla
 
UE Libro verde Shadow banking
UE Libro verde Shadow bankingUE Libro verde Shadow banking
UE Libro verde Shadow banking
ManfredNolte
 
Sanjay final project of mahindra finance
Sanjay final project of mahindra financeSanjay final project of mahindra finance
Sanjay final project of mahindra finance
SanjayGar
 
Management of financial institutions
Management of financial institutionsManagement of financial institutions
Management of financial institutions
josiahtera
 

Ähnlich wie Brent Buyse Thesis (20)

An Empirical Study on Universal Banking and its Potential for Indian Market C...
An Empirical Study on Universal Banking and its Potential for Indian Market C...An Empirical Study on Universal Banking and its Potential for Indian Market C...
An Empirical Study on Universal Banking and its Potential for Indian Market C...
 
Informe del banco internacional de pagos sobre el sistema financiero a la som...
Informe del banco internacional de pagos sobre el sistema financiero a la som...Informe del banco internacional de pagos sobre el sistema financiero a la som...
Informe del banco internacional de pagos sobre el sistema financiero a la som...
 
Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...
Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...
Rizki Ardiansyah_(2020-460)-MEJ-Concepts,Cases,and Regulation in Financial Fr...
 
liquidity concepts, instruments and procedure
liquidity concepts, instruments and procedureliquidity concepts, instruments and procedure
liquidity concepts, instruments and procedure
 
UE Libro verde Shadow banking
UE Libro verde Shadow bankingUE Libro verde Shadow banking
UE Libro verde Shadow banking
 
Sanjay final project of mahindra finance
Sanjay final project of mahindra financeSanjay final project of mahindra finance
Sanjay final project of mahindra finance
 
shadow banking
shadow bankingshadow banking
shadow banking
 
disso final
disso finaldisso final
disso final
 
2_International Banking.pdf
2_International Banking.pdf2_International Banking.pdf
2_International Banking.pdf
 
Credito whitepaper
Credito whitepaperCredito whitepaper
Credito whitepaper
 
Credit risk mgt
Credit risk mgtCredit risk mgt
Credit risk mgt
 
Shadow Banking
Shadow BankingShadow Banking
Shadow Banking
 
Vskills basel iii professional sample material
Vskills basel iii professional sample materialVskills basel iii professional sample material
Vskills basel iii professional sample material
 
Diversity of forms-The Banking sector
Diversity of forms-The Banking sectorDiversity of forms-The Banking sector
Diversity of forms-The Banking sector
 
Vietnam - Banking - Modernizing the System - What must be done:
Vietnam - Banking - Modernizing the System - What must be done: Vietnam - Banking - Modernizing the System - What must be done:
Vietnam - Banking - Modernizing the System - What must be done:
 
Indian financial system
Indian financial systemIndian financial system
Indian financial system
 
Strengthening oversight and regulation of shadow banking
Strengthening oversight and regulation of shadow bankingStrengthening oversight and regulation of shadow banking
Strengthening oversight and regulation of shadow banking
 
savings bank account services by karnataka bank
savings bank account services by karnataka banksavings bank account services by karnataka bank
savings bank account services by karnataka bank
 
Management of financial institutions
Management of financial institutionsManagement of financial institutions
Management of financial institutions
 
Chapter 3
Chapter 3Chapter 3
Chapter 3
 

Brent Buyse Thesis

  • 1. UNIVERSIDAD COMILLAS – FACULTAD DE DERECHO (ICADE) Shadow Banking: Lucrative lending by non-bank financial entities in the gaps of regulation. Brent Thomas Buyse Supervised by: Bernardino Muñiz 15 April 2015
  • 2. i Submitted to the Faculty of the School of Law (ICADE) of Universidad Pontificia Comillas in partial discharge of the requirements for the Master in International and European Business Law. Plagiarism Statement I certify that this thesis is my own work, based on my personal study and/or research and that I have acknowledged all material and sources used in its preparation, whether they be books, articles, reports, lecture notes, and any other kind of document, electronic or personal communication. I also certify that this thesis has not previously been submitted for assessment in any other institution, except where specific permission has been granted from all institutions involved, or at any other time in this institution, and that I have not copied in part or whole or otherwise plagiarized the work of other students and/or persons.
  • 3. ii Table of Contents Abstract.............................................................................................................................................................iii I. Introduction..................................................................................................................................................1 II. How does shadow banking work? .......................................................................................................4 a. Alternative payment forms.................................................................................................................12 b. P2P Lending..........................................................................................................................................14 c. Inter-connectedness ............................................................................................................................17 III. Global reality of shadow banking.....................................................................................................19 a. Financial Stability Board Monitoring.............................................................................................21 b. Shadow Banking in the United States ...........................................................................................23 c. Shadow Banking in the European Union .....................................................................................26 d. Shadow Banking in China.................................................................................................................28 e. Shadow Banking in Asia.....................................................................................................................31 f. Shadow Banking in Switzerland .......................................................................................................33 IV. Financial Stability Board Policy and Regulations........................................................................34 a. System wide monitoring.....................................................................................................................35 b. Improved oversight..............................................................................................................................36 i. Mitigating risk in banks’ interactions with shadow banking activities.........................................................36 ii. Reducing the susceptibility of MMFs to “runs”.........................................................................................37 iii. Improving transparency and aligning incentives in securitization................................................................38 iv. Dampening pro-cyclicality and other financial stability risks in securities financing transactions such as repos and securities lending ....................................................................................................................................38 v. Assessing and mitigating systemic risks posed by other shadow banking entities and activities......................39 V. Conclusion.................................................................................................................................................40 Bibliography ...................................................................................................................................................42
  • 4. iii Abstract This thesis is going to introduce shadow banking as a global financial reality. Shadow banking is when non-banks facilitate business just like a normal bank would. Shadow banking is an increasingly complex idea that is responsible for the transaction of trillions of dollars of assets. It is a system that employs simple concepts like peer-to-peer lending to more complicated such as securitization and even more elaborate. For the purpose of this thesis, the discussion will remain with forms of lending. The financial crisis of 2007-2008 was posited on the flaws of poor lending practices that were exceptionally accelerated at the fault of poorly managed, understood, and regulated shadow bank entities. Today that reality is quickly changing. Regulators around the world are taking notice of what risks are associated with shadow banking. However, regulators are also seeing the large benefits that shadow banking can relate back to national economies and the global financial system. By shrinking the size of banks by heavy regulation it ultimately forces a lot of the lending practices out of traditional banks and into the arena of shadow banking. That’s ultimately what regulators want in order to not have such an over reliance on massive financial institutions. Going forward, regulators are drafting and implementing new regulations to bring shadow banks out from the shadows and embrace the system and an integral part of the entire financial system. With the help of the Financial Stability Board, regulators around the world will soon realize a financial system that sees both traditional banks and shadow banks competing for business in a resilient financial market. This ultimately is the best scenario for both investors and tax payers.
  • 5. 1 I. Introduction Put simply, shadow banking is when non-bank entities act like banks. Shadow banks are more specifically defined as financial intermediaries that conduct functions of banking without access to central bank liquidity or public sector credit guarantees.1 The Financial Stability Board (FSB), an international watchdog set up to guard against future financial crises, defined shadow banking as "credit intermediation involving entities and activities outside the regular banking system, or non-bank credit intermediation. Shadow banking, when conducted appropriately, provides a valuable alternative to bank funding which supports positive economic activity as well as quality competition for banks. The FSB has recognized five economic functions that are considered shadow banking. These five activities are: i. management of collective investment vehicles, ii. Loan provision that is dependent on short term funding, iii. Intermediation of market activities that is dependent on short- term funding or on secured funding of client assets, iv. Facilitation of credit creation, and v. securitization and securitization based credit intermediation and funding of financial activities.2 The FSB estimates that shadow banking accounts for a quarter of the global financial system, with assets of $71 trillion at the beginning of 2013, up from $26 trillion a decade earlier.3 In some countries, shadow banks are expanding even faster: in China, for instance, they grew by 42% in 2012 alone.4 Mark Carney, the governor of the Bank of England and head of the Financial Stability Board was asked to identify the greatest danger to the world economy. He stated shadow banking and in particular in the emerging markets.5 Shadow banking certainly has the size and reach to be a global 1 (The Economist, 2014) 2 (Financial Stability Board, 2014) 3 Id. 4 Id. 5 (The Economist, 2014)
  • 6. 2 crisis by its very inherent nature. Shadow Banking is huge, fast-growing, in certain forms poorly understood. Shadow banking can be very good but, if carelessly managed like previously realized, has the potential to be globally devastating. But there is disagreement about what counts as shadow banking. The central core of shadow banking is credit. Everything from China’s loan-making trust companies to Western peer-to-peer lending schemes and money-market funds. A broader definition, however, would include any bank- like activity undertaken by a firm not regulated as a bank including the mobile-payment systems offered by Vodafone, the bond-trading platforms set up by technology firms, online crowd source lenders like Lending Club, or the investment products sold by BlackRock. Shadow banks differ from other nonregulated lending institutions in that these nonregulated lenders are not lending capital of which it has an obligation to pay back. Investors put forth money in hopes of gaining a profitable return but are not promised nor obliged to a return. Whereas shadow banks are lending money in which they are obligated to return. This is what makes shadow banking such a sometimes ominous figure in the financial sector. Shadow banks can be a big boon for a country's financial sectors. Shadow banking, especially in emerging markets, expands access to credit because the traditional banks currently are faced with burdensome regulatory hurdles as well as problems with lending capacities. In advanced economies, traditional banks have been lending less as a result of new regulatory landscapes. Shadow banks provide long term credit while traditional banks cannot. As reforms continue, authorities are recognizing that banking activities can slowly be pushed into the more resilient shadow banking sector.6 In some ways, it is a good thing that lending is coming from outside traditional banks. Banks are regulated for a simple reason: they have big “maturity mismatches”. Traditional banks also have 6 (Carney, 2014)
  • 7. 3 become enormously leveraged and are linked and connected in massively complicated ways with other financial institutions. This makes traditional banks especially fragile. And when traditional banks get into trouble, taxpayers are left to foot the bill in order to avoid an even greater catastrophe, because governments both guarantee deposits and are frightened to let such big and complicated institutions fail. So if some lending is moving from traditional banks to less dangerous shadow bank entities, the financial system should be safer in the long run. If a business takes a long-term loan from a pension retirement fund or a life insurer with long-term liabilities instead of from a bank and if the loan goes wrong, the creditor will lose money. Without the complexities of leverage coupled with the expanding web of counterparties and then the depositors demanding their deposits, losses in one institution are less likely to damage others. Yet shadow banks, if poorly regulated, can be just as dangerous as the traditional banks. One of the principal culprits in the financial crisis was the “structured investment vehicle”, a legal entity created by banks to sell loans repackaged as bonds.7 These were notionally independent, but when they got into trouble they pulled in the banks that had set them up.8 Another source of instability were money-market funds, through which firms and individuals invested spare cash for short-terms. Originally, MMFs had been thought of as containing zero risk. When it became evident that these MMFs were not risk free, they suffered a lightning fast run. Shadow banks are proliferating because traditional banks are struggling and reorganizing. Traditional banks have been plagued with losses incurred during the financial crisis and stifled by new heavier regulation, questionable higher capital requirements, and perpetual legal troubles coupled with outrageously expensive fines. The traditional banks are reshaping themselves as a result. Lending has been cut significantly. Shadow banks are filling these gaps. Shadow banking 7 (The Economist, 2014) 8 Id.
  • 8. 4 encompasses a wide array of complex financial activities. As a result, this thesis will be specifically addressing shadow banking activities as they relate to lending. II. How does shadow banking work? Shadow banking tends to grow rapidly when there are strict banking regulations in place, as well as when interest rates are low resulting in investors searching for better returns, and when there is a large demand for assets. The current environment in advanced economics is very conducive to further the growth of shadow banking. To better understand shadow banking, it is first important to understand how normal traditional banks operate which gives rise to shadow banking. Banks operate by taking deposits from individuals and commercial entities, depositors. Banks then take these assets and provide funds to borrowers in the form of a loan. There is generally an overall maturity mismatch with this behavior however. Depositors generally need quick short term access to their funds that have been deposited while at the same time borrowers need long term sources of funding. Banks are able to take advantage of this because it is very rare that all depositors will demand withdraw on their deposits at the same time. Therefore, banks can maintain only a small portion of total deposits in the form of liquid assets and be able to lend out the rest in loans. This is known as "quantitative asset transformation"9 because it changes the maturity of a short term asset into that of a long term asset, being the loan. This also changes the liquidity of the bank in that the deposits are in a leveraged state. This is the most common form in which banks generate revenue. Unfortunately, as history has shown us, this can leave banks in a very tight position and with little avenues of escape in the event 9 (Noeth & Sengupta, 2011)
  • 9. 5 that all the depositors desire their funds in a simultaneous wave. Such an event is known as a panic and such events have occurred several times over the centuries of modern banking. In response to such depositor behavior, many modern economies have created deposit insurance for bank deposits. Thus resulting in central banks becoming the "lender of last resort" to banks. By creating deposit insurance it gives depositors and the banks a guarantee to a specific value thus allowing depositors access to their deposits and it prevents banks from becoming insolvent and collapsing. This is not a perfect system in that it create a moral hazard on the part of the banks. This moral hazard is arguable the origin of the shadow banking sector. Banks investing in risky loans benefit from a higher return on the loan issued. The higher the risk, the greater the likelihood the burden is then placed on taxpayers to pay and bailout depositors in the event that the enormity of risky loans fail resulting in an issue of insolvency for the bank. This has resulted in regulators to require banks to maintain capital levels at certain minimum standards in relation to the riskiness of their lending behavior. This means that banks whose lending practice is very prudent and does not take on large risks is thus not required to maintain the same capital level as a bank who engages in chronically risky lending behavior with slim chances of successful return. The tradeoff is prudent lending does not lead to a high return whereas risky lending does. This is the inherent dichotomy of risk vs reward to which regulators try to mitigate risk in order to ensure a banks do not fail and a healthy banking system is maintained for the overall stability of a healthy and growing economy. In response to capital requirements regulation, banks created what are known as "off- balance-sheet entities."10 These off-balance-sheet entities, also known as incognito leveraged entities, are design is to create the perspective of a less burdened bank in order to lower the capital requirement. The balance sheet of a bank shows the various assets, liabilities, and net value. This is 10 (Smith, 2015)
  • 10. 6 the most fundamental evaluation of the real position that a bank, or any commercial entity, currently sits. "Off-balance-sheet entities are assets or debts that do not appear on a company's balance sheet. For example, oil-drilling companies often establish off-balance-sheet subsidiaries as a way to finance oil exploration projects. In a clean and clear example, a parent company can set up a subsidiary company and spin it off by selling a controlling interest or the entire company to investors. Such a sale generates profits for the parent company from the sale, transfers the risk of the new business failing to the investors and lets the parent company remove the subsidiary from its balance sheet.”11 This is a common practice which mitigates risk while allowing a parent corporation to create separateness and limited liability. Too often, however, off–balance-sheet entities are used to artificially make commercial entities look more financially secure than they actually are. A complex array of investment vehicles, most famously the subprime-mortgage securities and credit default swaps, are used to remove debts from corporate balance sheets. The parent company lists proceeds from the sale of these items as assets but does not list the financial obligations that come with them as liabilities. When banks issue loans the loans are typically kept on the bank's books as an asset. If those loans are securitized and sold off as investments the securitized debt, for which the bank is ultimately liable, is not kept on the bank's books. Herein lies the foundation of shadow banking. It is an alternative form to the main practice of tradition banks which is qualitative asset transformation. The credit intermediation, the act of lending funds raised by depositors, through the shadow banking system is very similar to traditional bank and this is what fulfills the principle functions of banks being that of qualitative asset transformation. Banks fulfill this by simply the issuing of loans in a liquid asset which are provided for to the bank by depositors in the form of a liquid asset deposit. This is a very simple and straight forward process with a limited number of parties 11 Id.
  • 11. 7 involved. Shadow banking involves a much more complicated process to achieve the same goal, which is with many benefits as well as cautions. The depositors in shadow banking are wholesale investors who in turn sell to individual investors and who provide the funds like a traditional depositor would. They provide an analogous short term funds as a depositor through the use of repurchase markets(more commonly known as repo markets) and most commonly through money market funds(such funds are also known as money market mutual funds). On the other end of the process is the loan originator which in the traditional model would be the bank. Here we find the "shadow bank" which is a financial institution or can also be a traditional bank engaging in the shadow banking system. The repurchase market where repo transactions take place. Repo transaction are whereby commercial entities with surplus case buy a security for cash only for an issuer and then resell them back to the issue after a short period of time, or term. This functions like a loan to the seller, issuer, of the security. The security itself is the collateral to the loan made by the purchaser to the seller of the security. These transaction can be very open ended and are often rolled over with frequency. This, in turn, functions just like a deposit at a traditional bank. So analogous in fact that a repo transaction is withdrawable on demand just like a depositor can withdraw funds on demand from a traditional bank. However, the analogy stops there. There is no deposit insurance on a repo transaction. The security to the "deposit" is inherent to the collateral. In the event that the issuer is unable to repay the buyer, the buyer is entitled to sell the repo on the open market and collect the proceeds from the open market sale, thus passing the obligation to pay to the new owner from the original buyer. In addition, repo transaction are over collateralized. This overcollateralization results in a haircut on the repo transaction and is dependent specifically on the level of risk involved with the repo transaction. The loan amount is typically less than the face value of the security used as
  • 12. 8 collateral. Suppose the lender lends $9 million and receives $10 million of bonds at market value, then there is a ten percent haircut. Money Market Funds are a second method by which shadow banking is initiated. In money market funds investors pool funds together in order to invest in a high-quality and short-term security. Generally, such investments are issued by governments, central banks, or major well established corporations who are financially stable. These investments in money market funds are also withdrawable on demand just like repo transaction which is why they are nearly analogous to traditional deposits at a bank. Due to the type of security these investment seek, they are regarded as with no credit risk or very low credit risk. This demands on if it is a US Treasury bill which is most common, or some other form of commercial paper which is asset backed. Such asset backed commercial paper is highly regulated in order to ensure the genuine high quality of the security. Asset banked commercial paper is typically backed by loan receivables or credit card receivables as the underlying collateral. Repo transactions and money market funds are attractive and useful in shadow banking activities because they are safe investments and are withdrawable on demand. This makes them function like deposits. Although they are similar in that aspect, both do function different in that investments in money market funds are in the form of a continuing contract where as a repo transaction is a one-time contract with fixed terms and returns. As stated previously, money market mutual funds investment shares can be redeemed on demand. Repo transaction use securities that are typically of a longer maturity as collateral and for short-term borrowing of cash. Both cases have liability formed which is theoretically withdrawable on demand and of shorter maturities than that of the assets financed. This is the mechanics of by which shadow banking systems are typically resemblance of the functions of traditional banks.
  • 13. 9 Historically, traditional banks originate a loan, or issue a loan, with the intention of then holding on to the loan. However, in modern banking this model has become unprofitable as the result of increased competition and a changing regulatory regime. In modern banking, origination of loans is done with the intent and purpose of then converting the issued loan into a security. This is done by a process known as securitization. Securitization can often be a very complex process with multiple layers, but the basics of securitization can be explained and is fundamental to the operation of shadow banking because securitization is how bank deposit funds are used to finance repo transactions or investments in money market funds. The starting point to securitization is the originating bank of a loan, whether it is a home loan or auto loan or student loan, arranges for the loan to be sold to what is known as a warehouse bank. Warehouse banks purchase loans from a variety of banks much like a warehouse holds a variety of goods. These warehouse banks are also known as aggregators, sellers, or sponsors. The financing to this process is that the warehouse bank will issue a line of credit to the originator of the loan who can then close on the loan and then pass the loan documents back to the warehouse in exchange for the line of credit funds to be disbursed so the originator can pay out the loan. Warehouse banks then collect large amounts of loan documents from multiple sources on a large number of loans. These loan documents serve as collateral on the lines of credit issued to each originating bank for each loan. The next step in the process is the sale of these pooled loans at the warehouse bank to what is known as an administrator. The administrator purchases the loans and then creates a special purpose vehicle (commonly referred to as a SPV) to then hold the loans. The special purpose vehicle then issues securities against the loans held by the special purpose vehicle. It is important to note that the administrator’s purpose is to only purchase loans from a warehouse/aggregator and place the loans in a SPV. The administrator does not openly sell the securities, generally. The certificates
  • 14. 10 to the securities are sold specifically to underwriters directly from the administrator. Underwriters then are responsible for the sale of the securities to the ultimate investor. The final steps in the process of securitization is the purchase of the securities by the ultimate investor. The investor then receives regular amounts of the principal and interest on the security related to the special purpose vehicle based on the priority of the security to the SPV. This order is determined simply by the class, or tranche, of the security and is determined so in advance. The ultimate investor has lots of options of what can be done with the security. The investor may hold onto the security to its full maturity. The investor may even sell the security to another investor and may also use the security as collateral for a repo transaction. Securitization is not always as straight forward as just explained. Often times various steps in the process are duplicated in order to incorporate more loans or to spin off additional securities. Source: (Noeth & Sengupta, 2011)
  • 15. 11 The creation of this securities establishes the passing of the proceeds from the sale of the securities upstream to all of the participating entities in the chain of intermediation. That being the administrator, the aggregator and the originators of the loans. More simply, the creator of the SPV, the warehouse bank, and then the originating bank of the loan. This also create a necessity of short- term funding at each step of the process. This is for two possible reasons. First, the maturity is mismatched being that the maturity of the securities is of a shorter term than the maturity on the loan which requires the entity to "roll over:" the securities or use short term funds to pay the investors. The second is that at each step in the securitization process the short term funding need arises between the purchase of the loans and their subsequent sale downstream which is arguably the most common scenario. This short term funding is where the repo transaction, money market funds become heavily relied upon. Each time an entity utilizes the use of a repo transaction or money market mutual fund they are performing the function of a bank because they are acquiring funding. Each step in the securitization process is funded by a "shadow lending" activity to complete the shadow banking process. The securitization process thus transforms longer term loans, like mortgages and student loans, which can carry a varying degree to risk levels into financial instruments of a shorter maturity and can considerably lower the risk. This process as a whole mimics the function of a bank. Shadow banking has been criticized as being redundant to traditional banks. Traditional banking activities and shadow banking activities do achieve the same general purpose of qualitative asset transformation, however shadow banking achieves this goal in a manner that a traditional bank cannot. Shadow banking utilizes securitization. Securitization allows for risk diversification across multiple borrowers, financial products, and physical geographical locations- i.e. different financial markets. Securitization takes advantage of the economies of scale and scope by segmenting various different activities of credit intermediation which in turn reduces over call to lending. By providing
  • 16. 12 such a variety of securities that differ in relation to risk and maturity, a better opportunity to manage portfolios is provides than would normally be considered possible in the traditional banking model. The most important difference, when securitization is done properly, is an increase of transparency and disclosure because banks now sell assets that are then scrutinized during securitization that they would otherwise just hold on in their rather opaque balance sheets. a. Alternative payment forms12 Payment systems around the world have generally been operated and maintained by banks. The processing of retail payments is another important core function of the financial system. The way in which payment systems are developing as a result of innovative new technologies and demand for increased convenience is leading payment systems to move outside of traditional bank. This shift results in lower revenues for traditional banks which have in the past been very reliant on such fees. These shadow banks which participate in the payment process have created secure methods which mimic and can complete entire transaction without the need of a traditional bank. Traditional banks role as the intermediary for payments is a product of these entities have large deposits of liquid assets from depositors as well as the interconnectedness of traditional banks throughout the financial system. Banks can transfer funds between each other in order to satisfy the transactions between buyers and sellers with ease. As technology continues to advance, shadow banks are beginning to fill in some, if not all, of those roles. "Most non-banks have specific and limited functions in retail payment systems, such as providing customer interface or back-office 12 Although alternative payment forms are not a source of lending, they are important as a demonstration of how shadow banking is advancing on all fronts on the model of traditional banking.
  • 17. 13 services for payment networks run by banks. Some non-banks also provide clearing and settlement services to banks, thus playing a much larger role as an integral part of payment processing."13 Over the last several decades, electronic noncash payments have grown rapidly. The scale of non-cash payments is enormous with an estimated 334 billion transactions globally in 2012.14 Bank cards accounted for 61% of total number of non-cash transactions.15 Credit transfers and direct debits together accounted for 30% of non-cash transactions.16 The remainder of transactions consisted of checks, which continue to decline as a share of total transactions. Electronic payments generally consist of three basic steps: authorization, clearing, and finally settlement. The initiating step, authorization, consists of the transmission of data to the processor of the payment for the confirmation of the identity as well as the permission to facilitate the transaction. The second step, the clearing, involves the aggregating of the transaction. This is the transmission of the values requested for disbursement and the final "net amount" for the transaction. The final step, the settlement, is the electronic transfer of the funds to complete the transaction. It is the "hand shake" between the accounts of the buyer and seller. Shadow banks are providing similar services. Through the use of online services, shadow banks are able to complete the entire transaction and can even do so, sometimes, without the need for a traditional banks involvement. Some of these shadow bank payment companies have created "closed-loop payments" in which virtual online accounts for buyers and sellers within the online system are credited and debited without the involvement of traditional banks. Such entities and services are becoming increasingly popular around the world. In the United States alone, in 2012, there were over 2 billion of these sort of transaction.17 Not all shadow bank payment systems do by 13 (Borst, 2015) 14 (World Payment Reports, 2014) 15 Id. 16 Id. 17 (Federal Reserve Bank, 2014)
  • 18. 14 pass traditional banks, however. Many systems, such as PayPal, require account settlement with a bank account or credit card. This does still have an effect on the payment system. For example, several dozen purchases can be made on PayPal, but when the settlement between PayPal and a traditional bank occurs there is only one transaction for the total amount of all purchases executed using PayPal's payment service. One transaction which is the total of dozens of transactions. This results in lower revenues from transaction fees for the bank. There are currently a variety of other shadow bank payment services that are similar or identical to the model by which PayPal has come to function and become widely used and embraced around the world The growth of these shadow bank payment services helps fosters innovation as well as improve efficiency in the current market place for transactions. Traditional banks view these new alternatives as a challenge to their well-established structure of fees by which large sums of revenue are generated. Without absolute regulation, traditional banks will have to adopt in terms of technology as well as re-evaluating the manner and method by which fees are assessed for electronic transactions. b. P2P Lending As a result of banks restructuring and focus on conforming to new regulatory standards since the financial crisis new alternatives have percolated which also contributes to the shadow banking sector. These smaller shadow bank entities take the forms as payday lenders, pawnbrokers and even loan sharks as well as other similar "institutions". Nobody is too worried by competition to banks in their ancillary businesses: if, say, Google can help people manage their money more efficiently, that is to be welcomed.18 The most important and potentially revolutionizing for the 18 (The Economist, 2014)
  • 19. 15 financial sector is a form of "grassroots finance" known as peer-to-peer (P2P) lending. The worry is in the creation of credit intermediation, which P2P does not do. It is a good thing that lending outside the banking system is expanding. P2P Lending is a process by which any range of entities in search of funds are matched, generally by an online electronic intermediary, to entities which are seeking to lend. Lending entities earn a higher interest rate than what is currently possible on a deposit at a bank while the borrowers generally will pay less than they would have to pay for a loan from a bank. Peer-to-peer lending is developing around the world at a fast pace. Growth is seen in large volumes. In Britain, loan volumes are doubling every six months. They have just passed the £1 billion mark ($1.7 billion), though this is tiny against the country’s £1.2 trillion in retail deposits.19 In America, the two largest P2P lenders, Lending Club and Prosper, have 98% of the market.20 They issued $2.4 billion in loans in 2013, up from $871m in 2012.21 The scale of P2P is still modest in size. The two largest P2P lending firms in the United States have thus far lent only $5 billion combined.22 This is small in comparison to the total personal-loan market of $1.8 trillion in the United States.23 But the rate of growth is rapid. At the smaller of the two, Prosper, the value of new loans agreed in March totaled $77million, which was more than four times that a year earlier.24 Its lending has grown by 3,000% in eight years. Such exponential growth is a common theme in this sector.25 Another common theme, for now, is that default are low. 19 (The Economist, 2014) 20 Id. 21 Id. 22 (The Economist, 2014) 23 Id. 24 Id. 25 Id.
  • 20. 16 These P2P loans are generally an unsecured personal loan regardless if it is a business or a private individual. Some P2P intermediaries even allow the investor to decide the loans to which they ultimately underwrite. Additionally, P2P intermediaries can also bundle the loans for investors, or multiple investors, in a securitized fashion in order to give a dynamic return with inherent security. Regulators are also taking note of P2P lending. The new worry about P2P lending is that a poorly managed platform might collapse and take all of the investors’ money in the collapse. Funds placed with P2P lenders are not covered by the state-backed guarantees that protect retail deposits in banks. At a conference organized by the P2P Finance Association executives were worried about the risks of a “Bitcoin-style bust” that could rattle confidence in the new and fragile lending sector. New regulatory rules are likely to insist that P2P businesses create separate funds gathered from savers and coordinate for third parties to manage outstanding loans if they cease trading. Some platforms offer something of a substitute. Zopa and most other British companies have started “provision funds”, which aim (but do not promise) to make good on loans that sour.26 These smooth the risk for lenders, but blunt the original P2P concept. Purists fear such arrangements could recreate the moral hazard that has plagued conventional banking. The promising aspect to P2P intermediaries in the shadow banking sector is that in the event of a default on a loan the loss is passed directly to the lender. The reason why this is important is because it does not place traditional deposits at risk at a traditional bank nor does it place any burden on central bank deposit insurance. P2P intermediary lending allows for access to liquidity and assets in a manner in which that does not ultimately put any adverse risk to the tax payer. In addition, P2P lending also ends the worrisome and dangerous mismatches often seen in other areas of shadow banking between short-term deposits and long-term loans inherent in conventional 26 (The Economist, 2014)
  • 21. 17 banking but generally by locking lenders in for the loan’s duration.27 It is a system of "lender beware" which is in conformity to the new modern idea of investments and investing. c. Inter-connectedness Inter-connectedness between shadow banks and traditional banks poses a significant threat to the viability and sustainability of financial systems in specific countries and the greater global financial system. As what was discovered in the financial crisis, traditional banks and shadow banks were significantly inter-connected to such an extent that failures and runs that occurred outside of the traditional banking sector caused great stress and strain on traditional banks by a phenomenon known as contagion. Inter-connectedness takes two main forms. These forms are direct and indirect links. Direct links are established when shadow banks are either forming part of a traditional banks credit intermediation process, or are directly owned by a traditional bank, or are benefiting from direct support from a traditional bank. Indirect linkages are established when both shadow banks and traditional banks have invested in similar assets or are exposed to common entities. According to the FSB report on global shadow banking, interconnectedness has declined on a year over year basis.28 Traditional banks assets to OFI's(shadow bank entities) declined from $4.3 trillion at the end of 2012 to #$3.9 trillion at the end of 2013.29 Traditional banks liabilities to OFIs declined as well from $4.7 trillion to $4.4 trillion.30 Additionally, Australia and Chile experienced the most decrease in the exposure of their traditional banking system to shadow bank entities. Not all countries have experienced the same results. Spain as well as the Netherlands have seen increases of 27 Id. 28 (Financial Stability Board, 2014) 29 Id. 30 Id.
  • 22. 18 risk. In fact the funding risk for traditional banks, which is the extent to which traditional banks rely on shadow banks for funding, showed the greatest increases in Indonesia, India, Italy, and Spain. Modest increases were seen in the United Kingdom and Brazil. The countries with the highest growth all remain around 5% of banks total assets which is not a significantly alarming statistic in the aggregate. Yet, the United Kingdom and Brazil saw moderate increases when already they each maintain a very high level of bank asset percentage. Source: (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
  • 23. 19 III. Global reality of shadow banking Shadow banking is a global reality. Shadow banking has become the single greatest alternative to traditional banking activity. This is made apparent by the absolute enormity of the shadow banking sector. Using data from the Financial Stability Board's Global Shadow Banking Monitoring Report (GSBMR) an analysis of the global shadow banking sector as well as the shadow banking sectors in key financial jurisdictions and financial regions can help better understand the current state of the shadow banking sector and it's future. The total coverage of the monitoring report accounts for nearly 80% of global GDP as well as roughly 90% of the global financial system.31 Shadow banking is a complement and a valuable addition to traditional banking in that it expands access to credit as well as spreading risk and providing more liquidity to the markets. In developing economies finance companies and microcredit lenders often provide credit and investments to underbanked communities. In advanced economies, various types of financial intermediaries have been stepping in to provide long-term credit to the private sector while banks have been reorganizing their balance sheets in order to be compliant with new regulatory structures (see: April 2014 Global Financial Stability Report). Lending activities by shadow bank entities is a significant portion of total lending activity in the United States economy and is rising in many countries as well, notably in the European Union. Although there are many obvious and valuable benefits to the shadow banking sector, the global financial crisis exposed that without proper regulation shadow banking can put the stability of the financial system at a serious risk. In advanced economies, some shadow bank entities, like money 31 Id.
  • 24. 20 market funds and SPVs, were highly leveraged or had large holdings of illiquid assets leading up to the crisis. As a result they were fatally vulnerable to ensuing "runs" when investors withdrew massive quantities of assets with hardly any notice. This led to a fire sales of assets which in turn intensified the financial fallout by depressing the value of assets and resulted in traditional banks feeling the heat and stress of the collapse. Since the crisis, economies and government around the world have undergone regulatory reforms in cooperation with each other and the FSB. The FSB has been instrumental in these reforms because the FSB has recommended greater transparency on asset values, governance improvements, reforms on ownership of assets, stricter oversight and most importantly improved regulation of shadow banks. In advanced economies, shadow banking appears to be shifting to less-well-monitored activities in the wake of new regulations. Only investment funds, especially bond funds, country specific entities, and “other” entities continued to grow after 2008.32 The growth of the “other” entities signals a shift in risk to financial stability toward the newer and less understood activities and could perhaps suggests that these may comprise new forms of direct lending and over-the-counter derivatives trading. In emerging market economies, overall growth of shadow banking remains strong. Shadow banking assets as a proportion of GDP expanded from 6 percent to 35 percent between 2002 and 2012, while banking sector assets grew from 30 percent to 70 percent of GDP over the same period.33 This growth, however, can be characterized as a normal part of an emerging economy continuing to develop its financial markets. The growth of shadow banking has been led by the growth of activities and financial companies that operate financial instruments similar to that of MMFs. In some countries, including Brazil and South Africa, mutual funds have also been growing 32 (International Monetary Fund, October 2014) 33 Id.
  • 25. 21 strongly; in others, including Mexico and Turkey, real estate investment trusts have expanded especially fast (albeit from a low base). In dollar terms, China’s shadow banking sector became the fifth largest among FSB jurisdictions in 2012.34 a. Financial Stability Board Monitoring The focus of the monitoring is to look at all non-bank financial intermediation. There are two measures, broad and narrow, in which the GSBMR measures the shadow banking sector. The broad measure is referred to as the Monitoring Universe of Non-Bank Financial Intermediation (MUNFI).35 The data collected by MUNFI castes a wide net in collection of data that is relative to shadow banking. Thus, the data inherently captures elements that do not strictly meet all the characteristics that are embodied in shadow banking as it is currently understood. The narrow measure focusses on the subset of non-bank credit intermediation which does potentially pose systemic risk to the financial system. A set of criteria are applied to the data in order to narrow down and filter out entities that are not part of credit intermediation. The broad measure (MUNFI), thus, is measured by the global financial assets of other financial intermediates in a specific country or geographical region. Whereas, the narrow measure takes the data from the MUNFI and withdraws financial assets of non -bank financial entities not involved in bank-like credit intermediation, financial assets related to those non-bank financial entities that are prudentially consolidated into a banking group, financial entities whose activities do not exhibit risks associated with shadow banking including maturity and liquidity transformation or 34 Id. 35 It is important to note, however, that in regional analysis by FSB Regional Consultative Groups(RCG) may deviate from the standard process as outlined by the FSB. RCG's may exercise this discretion in order to better accommodate region or nation specific entities that perform shadow banking functions that might otherwise be left out by the standard FSB process. The goal of each assessment, either by the FSB or a RCG, is to ensure the capturing of data and statistics which most accurately outlines the various risk implications associated with shadow banking.
  • 26. 22 leverage. The broad measure as well as the narrow measure of shadow banking are both important indicators of the size, composition and growth trends of non-bank financial intermediaries. Source: (Financial Stability Board, 2014) FSB broad estimates shows an increase in shadow banking activity in the euro area, the United Kingdom, and the United States, while narrower gauges of shadow banking might suggest stagnation at first glance. After a mild drop around 2008, the FSB measures show varying degrees of recovery in the United States, the euro area, and the United Kingdom. In contrast, the flow of funds and noncore liabilities measures remain broadly constant, which reflects two opposing forces: the decline in the role of certain activities after the crisis, such as securitization and lending via repos and securities, and a concomitant rise in other activities, including those of country-specific entities. The pickup in the FSB measures can be partly explained by positive valuation effects from the growth in the investment fund industry. The large difference between broad and narrow measures reflects significant activity within the financial system that is not fully captured by other shadow banking measures. The goal of the new regulation is to replace a shadow banking system which was prone to failure due to excess with a shadow banking system that contribute to strong, sustainable balanced
  • 27. 23 growth in the global economy.36 The time is coming now where shadow banking is coming out of the “shadows” and is to become a sustainable and contributing market based financial competent of the greater financial sector in the world. b. Shadow Banking in the United States Shadow banking in the United States can trace its origins back to securitization in the 1970s, when Ginnie Mae, a Government Sponsored Enterprise(GSE), began to guarantee mortgage pass- through securities, as a way to foster the secondary mortgage market and promote homeownership.37 Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, both GSE's as well, followed shortly thereafter. From there securitization quickly spread to other areas and in the 1980s the first "asset backed security" was created. The growth in shadow bank activity continued to grow and in 1989 began to outpace the activity of traditional banks. Shadow banking has continued to do so through 2007.38 Despite the serious losses and new regulatory framework which is requiring banks in the US to reorganize, total shadow bank liabilities still measure in size nearly in equal amounts to traditional banks. Although the past five years of shadow banking activity in the United States has been on the decline, this trend is now seen to be reversing. As the American economy continues to grow and improve, so does the growth in demand for access to credit. The increase in regulatory requirements in the United States gives shadow banks a competitive advantage against their traditional counter parts. 36 (Carney, 2014) 37 (TD Bank Group, 2014) 38 Id.
  • 28. 24 Source: (Adrian & Ashcraft, Shadow Banking Regulation, 2014) The size of the financial assets/liabilities of the US shadow banking system was nearly USD 20 trillion in March 2008 and USD 15 trillion in the second quarter of 2011, larger than the traditional banking system.39 The shadow banking sector is not as big as the peak in 2008, but gross liabilities of shadow banking are just slightly below liability of traditional banks. Shadow liabilities increased by over $200 billion in 2013.40 This was roughly one-quarter of the lending that was done by traditional banks.41 In the second half of 2013, shadow bank liabilities increased by 60 cents for every dollar in traditional bank liabilities.42 The recent growth is captured in agency and GSE backed securities as well as MMFs.43 This indicates that “increased capital and liquidity standards for depository institutions and insurance companies are likely to increase the returns to shadow banking activity.” Although many indicators point to the continued growth in shadow banking activity in the 39 (Pozsar, Adrian, Ashcraft, & Boesky, 2010) 40 (TD Bank Group, 2014) 41 Id. 42 Id. 43 (Pozsar, Adrian, Ashcraft, & Boesky, 2010)
  • 29. 25 United States, regulators are keen to implement regulation on shadow banking as to strength the entirety of the financial sector to prevent previous errors and gaps in regulation in 2008. The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act substantially changed the nature of shadow banking in the United States, among many of its implementations throughout the financial sector. Dodd-Frank now requires issuers of ABS and ABCP to maintain a portion of the issuance on balance sheet. This makes issuance of such instruments more expensive and impacts the commercial viability of the products as well because of the new capital liquidity standards as established by Basel III. At the same time, these regulations have also fostered improved transparency of the instruments. Furthermore, the SEC has placed restrictions on the amount of maturity and the amount of liquidity transformation that may take place with a MMF. Even with the greater regulatory oversight, the growth in shadow banking remains significant. Continued innovation in the future of financial products creates new opportunities for substantial growth potential in a perpetually dynamic financial sector. Economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York expect “shadow banking to adapt to these new regulations” and “new forms of regulatory arbitrage and shadow banking to emerge.”44 Shadow banking declined significantly during the crisis and subsequent recession in the United States. The recovery has been slow. As stronger more resilient balance sheet for traditional banks has improved competition among traditional banks, the recovery and growth in the economy is fueling growth in shadow banking. The recovery in shadow banking will continue to garner much attention as investors are looking to see how a newly regulated shadow banking system will continue to enhance credit intermediation in the financial sector after its disastrous contribute to the financial crisis. 44 (Adrian & Ashcraft, Shadow Banking Regulation, 2014)
  • 30. 26 c. Shadow Banking in the European Union Shadow banking is also finding its place in the European Union. Although overall shadow banking in the EU is smaller than that of the activity in the United States, it is still significant. The shadow banking sector in the EU is roughly valued at €10.8 trillion in 2011. This accounts for around 38% of total bank activity in the euro area. The shadow banking sector in the EU also differs greatly from that of the United States. The sector is very stable in terms of growth and traditional banks continue to be the main source of credit intermediation in Europe. Roughly three times the amount of assets are intermediated by traditional banks than shadow banks in the euro area. It is worth noting that, in the second quarter of 2011, almost 70% of the assets of the “other intermediaries” grouping (€7.6 trillion) were held by miscellaneous financial institutions. A stock- taking exercise carried out by the European System of Central Banks (ESCB) in 2009 revealed that around 19% of the residual “other miscellaneous intermediaries” correspond to financial holding companies, captive institutions (i.e. those providing financial services to a limited group of companies) and money lenders.45 Moreover, 15% is constituted by non-deposit taking institutions engaging in lending (factoring, leasing and other forms) and 10% by securities and derivatives dealers.46 A remaining 52% is made up of unidentified miscellaneous financial institutions. An important part of the euro area financial sector remains therefore relatively unexplored by official statistics.47 Securitization is smaller in volume in the euro area than in the United States. However, the euro area is not a homogenous group—witness the strength of shadow banking in a country like the Netherlands where non-financial banking institutions (NFBI) have the largest percentage of total 45 (Bakk-Simon, Borgioli, & Giron, 2012) 46 Id. 47 Id.
  • 31. 27 assets (45%) compared to the US (35%), the euro area (30%), and the UK (25%)48 . In fact, euro area banks have increasingly been relying on funding from other financial institutions, including securitization vehicles.49 In order to identify the possible systemic relevance of shadow banking, it is important to understand the interconnections with the regulated banking system. Over the recent past, the interconnectedness between traditional banks and shadow banks has increased, which has also increased Europe's exposure to contagion from runs in the shadow banking sector. The British proportion of shadow banking operations relative to traditional banking is much greater than in continental Europe. This may be explained by the strong connections of British banks with the City. Another characteristic of British banks, but also of French and Spanish banks, is the development of their activities at the international level, much more so than most US banks. The move into the international financial area is largely due to the response to increased competition and increased globalized standards among traditional banks. Although the response is to new financial stimuli, this is not necessarily a new phenomenon. For the United Kingdom, France and Spain, the internationalization of banking activity is a compliment and parallel to those countries as colonial powers. Another factor which encouraged the expansion of banks abroad more recently was European integration. Due to the creation of the European area and the Eurozone, banks are much more internationalized and convene business on a scale that is unique to most of the world.50 Overall, shadow banking activities in Europe have the pedigree to become a serious threat to the economy. However, due to the current climate of the European economy and regulation already established, the majority of financial activity is currently taking place in the traditional banking sector. However, there is room for growth to be made in the shadow banking sector which can help 48 (Jeffers & Plihon, 2014) 49 Id. 50 Id.
  • 32. 28 grow the European economy as a whole similar to how the shadow banking sector is making improvements in the American economy. Despite the potential room for growth, regulators and bankers alike need to be keenly aware of the interconnectedness not only between traditional banks and shadow banks in Europe, but also between banks in the euro area and banks in the United States. Close interconnectedness is what helped spread the crisis in its infancy. Regulators need to take steps to curb this potential threat. d. Shadow Banking in China While shadow banking in the United States and European Union has seen somewhat of a decline or stagnation since the financial crisis, China's shadow banking sector continues to flourish and grow. Shadow banks, which barely existed before China’s credit surge in 2009, now have assets of at least 30 trillion yuan ($4.9 trillion), or more than 50% of GDP, according to estimates by ANZ Bank.51 This is alarming. This growth in the shadow banking sector of China has been fueled by concerns of traditional bank credit intermediation as well as concerns over growing inflation. The Chinese government, in 2010, established strategic restrictions on the traditional banking system through the implementation of increasing interest rates and increased reserve requirements.52 These new regulations slowed the growth rate of the credit intermediation that was of concern. Very quickly traditional banks found ways to keep originating credit by the use of off balance sheet entities. Now, the fastest growing source of credit origination comes from the shadow banking sector. Non-bank financial institutions accounted for nearly half of the growth in credit in China in 2013. Concerns now fall on one specific type of financial entity, trusts. 51 (The Economist, 2014) 52 (Adrian, Ashcraft, & Cetorelli, Shadow Bank Monitoring, 2013)
  • 33. 29 Trusts are created when bank loans are bought by trust companies. These trust companies then sell to retail depositors various wealth management products. Banks earn fees on the origination of loans and management of these products, but since they are off balance sheet, they do not have to hold capital against them.53 These product also lack any form of a guarantee, generally. More often than not, the perception is that these products carry an implicit official sector support via a state bank. Trusts have grown very quickly in part because the central bank has limited the traditional banks' ability to lend to economic sectors in which there is an observable overinvestment, for example coalmining and real property. Trusts raise money by offering an attractive returns that traditional banks could not and then lend to sectors that the regulator have prohibit traditional banks from lending. As a result, commercial businesses in these economic sector have few alternatives or options other than seeking funding from the shadow banking sector. Additionally, China's central bank has placed a cap on interest for deposits which reduces Chinese savers’ return on deposit. As a result, savings accounts produce a meager 0.35% a year and a one-year fixed deposit earns 3.3%, which is hardly incentivizing.54 That makes trust products attractive for investors. Much like other parts of the world, shadow banking is an opportunistic alternative of last resort for financial mobility and success. In addition to trust loans, there also exists entrusted loans. These are loans originated by non-banks which are cash-rich companies that desire to lend to other companies in order to put their capital to work. These non-bank loans are sold to trust companies and serviced by banks. Banks also use entrusted loans as a mechanism to continue originating loan to circumvent the loan quota restrictions, which funds the off balance sheet entity. Banks, as a result of these shadow 53 Id. 54 (The Economist, 2014)
  • 34. 30 activities, have increased their stake of ownership in various trust companies to better facilitate distribution channel. Source: (The Economist, 2014) Historically, Increases in a country’s debt on the scale of China’s have almost always ended in a financial crisis of some sort. In the event that a series of defaults occur in the trust sector, investors would lose faith in these high-yield investment products. That would result in short-term lending elements drying up, leaving many banks in a crippled position to continue financing. China’s trust sector resembles the pre-crisis activity of shadow banking in many western economies. Much of it looks like a blatant attempt by Chinese banks to get around the restrictions regulators have placed on them. Trust companies are essentially thinly veiled covering for banks. A conduit to allow the banks to sell the financial instrument that they otherwise could not due to regulatory restrictions. The rise of shadow banking in China appears to not be the result of financial innovation, but actually driven by the reaction of the tightly regulated economic sectors and the heightened restrictions to the traditional banking sector. Fortunately for China and the world, China has the financial capacity to absorb many non-performing loans which would prevent an ill-fated "run" on
  • 35. 31 the banks. Standard & Poor’s, a ratings agency, argues that reforms could lead to “a turbulent period in which funding could dry up as the domestic market struggles to re-price risk”.55 In addition, combined debts (shadow and traditional) in China are smaller in relation to China's GDP than many combined debts in western economies leading up to the financial crisis. e. Shadow Banking in Asia The Working Group on Shadow Banking of the FSB Regional Consultative Group for Asia (RCGA) conducted a study on shadow banking in Asia. The Working Group conducted a survey among RCGA members to examine the profile of non-bank financial intermediaries (NBFIs), the regulations governing these entities, the definition of shadow banking applied by members, the distinction between shadow banking and NBFIs, the potential risks emanating from NBFIs and the applicability of FSB’s recommendations on shadow banking to Asia. The RCGA is comprised of Australia, Cambodia, China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, New Zealand, Pakistan, Philippines, Singapore, Sri Lanka, Thailand and Vietnam.5657 Ten of the 16 members of this group are classified as emerging economies based on standard economic indicators.58 In the emerging economies, shadow banking provides commercial entities and individual’s access to credit where traditional banks could not or are absent from the local market.59 This has allowed for greater liquidity and economic inclusion to a larger audience who would otherwise be forgotten. Shadow banking activity in Asia is not a systemic threat nor does it account for a significant portion of total finance. In addition, the vast majority of the shadow 55 (The Economist, 2014) 56 (Financial Stability Board, February 2015) 57 Analysis for China is markedly different than the rest of the region due to the national specific entities in the shadow banking sector and due to the enormous size and growth of the Chinese economy. 58 (Financial Stability Board, 2014) 59 Id.
  • 36. 32 banking activity is domestic with minimal risk from cross-border transaction. The financial systems in the Asian economies remains "traditional bank" dominant.60 Shadow banking activities account for less than half of total assets in the financial system.61 However, the amount of shadow banking activity in each country does vary greatly. China and Japan have large and intricate shadow banking sectors. Total OFI assets in Japan comprise roughly half of all OFI assets in Asia.62 Furthermore, Hong Kong and Singapore are major financial centers in Asia and as a result have a large OFI asset amount in relation to the size of their economies. Asian markets should continue to move towards more innovative and sophisticated financial markets in order to ensure economic development by increasing the efficiency of the allocated savings available and the financial stability of the region.63 This is also important for the global economy to help alleviate the global imbalances and the associated reserves accumulated in the Asian region which is partly to blame for a lack of financial sophistication in the region.64 As a whole Asia is not at risk from shadow banking like other major economies, United States and European Union for example, due to the fact that the financial markets in Asia are not as wholly developed as their western counterparts nor are the products they offer at the same level of complexity like they are offered in America and Europe.65 Financial products originating from non- banks is just not complex nor enormous enough to pose a serious risk to the financial stability of Asia as a whole. This is a very positive statistic because it allows for the Asian economies to continue to grow and develop and use shadow banking in a manner that helps promote economic growth and financial stability. The future for Asia's financial sectors, both shadow and traditional, 60 Id. 61 NBFIs comprise 33%, OFIs comprise 15% 62 (Financial Stability Board, 2014) 63 (Hannoun, 2008) 64 Id. 65 (Financial Stability Board, 2014)
  • 37. 33 are very bright so long as shadow banking is use responsibly while traditional banks are regulated in accordance with the high quality international standard. f. Shadow Banking in Switzerland Switzerland has long been known as a majorly important financial, and more importantly, banking hub in the world. According to data collected by the MUNFI and after the implementation of the narrowing down criteria, Switzerland's shadow banking sector is roughly USD $502 billion (CHF 481 billion).6667 This corresponds to roughly 81% of Swiss GDP.68 When applying the shadow banking activities as defined by the FSB, Switzerland's shadow banking sector reduces to (CHF 315 billion) which accounts for 53% of Swiss GDP.69 Switzerland maintains a relatively low risk to financial stability issues related to shadow banking. This can be attributed to three reasons. First, the size of Switzerland's shadow banking sector is significantly smaller than its traditional banking sector unlike many other countries and regions. Second, the assets that are in existence in the shadow banking sector are believed to be of low to moderate bank-like systemic risk. This means that even in the event of a disruption in the shadow banking sector, the resulting issues would be minor and very well manageable. Third, bond funds are other investment funds, which make up 60% of shadow banking assets in Switzerland are supervised by the Swiss Financial Market Supervisory Authority (FINMA).70 66 (Financial Stability Board, 2014) 67 CHF1.00 = $1.017 USD, XE Currency Conversion 68 (Financial Stability Board, 2014) 69 Id. 70 Id.
  • 38. 34 IV. Financial Stability Board Policy and Regulations The FSB71 monitors and assesses vulnerabilities affecting the global financial system and proposes actions needed to address them. In addition, it monitors and advises on market and systemic developments, and their implications for regulatory policy.72 Transforming shadow banking into resilient market-based financing has been one of the core elements of the FSB’s regulatory reform agenda to address the fault lines that contributed to the global financial crisis and to build safer, more sustainable sources of financing for the real economy.73 Two major issues were made apparent in the aftermath of the financial crisis that were contributory to the crisis itself. These two issues centered on a heavy reliance of short-term wholesale funding, a variety of incentive problems in securitized and structured finance markets that weakened lending standards, and a general lack of transparency that hid growing amounts of leverage and maturity mismatch, as well as the ultimate bearer of the associated risks.74 As the prices dropped for securitized assets, the terms for collateralized financing constricted, which then triggered a fire sales particularly by investors who were significantly mismatched and leveraged. As the markets grinded up to a halt, several investment vehicles became insolvent and failed, MMMFs experienced quick panic runs, and the entire shadow banking system came to a screeching halt. The viability of the banking system was also threatened and the supply of credit to the real economy was drastically restricted. The FSB has adopted a two-pronged strategy to deal with these issues, which they call "fault lines." First, the FSB has created a system-wide monitoring framework to track developments in the shadow banking system with a view to identifying the build-up of systemic risks and initiating 71 The FSB was established in April 2009 as the successor to the Financial Stability Forum (FSF) 72 (Financial Stability Board, 2015) 73 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014) 74 Id.
  • 39. 35 corrective actions where necessary.75 Second, the FSB is coordinating and contributing to the development of policy measures in five areas where oversight and regulation needs to be strengthened to reduce excessive build-up of leverage, as well as maturity and liquidity mismatching in the system: (i) mitigating risks in banks’ interactions with shadow banking entities; (ii) reducing the susceptibility of MMFs to “runs”; (iii) improving transparency and aligning incentives in securitization; (iv) dampening pro-cyclicality and other financial stability risks in securities financing transactions such as repos and securities lending; and (v) assessing and mitigating financial stability risks posed by other shadow banking entities and activities.76 a. System wide monitoring The first prong of the approach to address the issues from the financial crisis as established by the FSB is the implementation of system wide monitoring. This monitoring assess sources of systemic risks. The FSB has thus begun conducting annual monitoring exercises to assess global trends and risks in the shadow banking system. These exercises have prompted an increasing number of national and regional authorities to regularly assess the risks of their own shadow banking sectors. The system wide monitoring now covers a total of 25 jurisdictions which represents 80% of global GDP and 90% of global financial system assets.77 In addition, the FSB’s Regional Consultative Groups (RCGs) of the Americas and Asia (which include non-FSB member authorities) have recently started to conduct their own monitoring based on the annual FSB monitoring exercises.78 75 Id. 76 Id. 77 Several jurisdictions (e.g. Australia, Canada, Germany and the Netherlands) and the European Central Bank (ECB) have also published analyses of their respective shadow banking system, leveraging on the FSB annual monitoring exercises. The International Monetary Fund has conducted some analysis using the data collected in the FSB annual monitoring exercise in their October 2014 Global Financial Stability Report (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2014/02/pdf/ c2.pdf). 78 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014)
  • 40. 36 The increase in monitoring on a national and regional scale better covers jurisdictions where shadow banking entities are often located which helps increase the understanding of their operations and the risks they might contain as well as the benefits to which are applied. As monitoring continues and improves it is expected that these exercises will continue to benefit from further improvements in collecting data by jurisdictions and rectify identified data gap inconsistencies. b. Improved oversight The second issue the FSB is addressing through its policy recommendations is the improvement of oversight.79 In coordinating and contributing to the development of policy measures, the FSB has addressed five areas where oversight and regulation needs to be strengthened to reduce excessive build-up of leverage, as well as maturity and liquidity mismatching in the system. i. Mitigating risk in banks’ interactions with shadow banking activities The financial crisis revealed that both the shadow banking sector and the traditional banking sector were both intertwined with each other leading to heavy risk exposures. The FSB requested the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) to develop the policy recommendations to ensure that future risk spill-over to traditional banks from shadow bank are mitigated. The BCBS put forth the following recommendations: (i) risk-sensitive capital requirements for banks’ investments in the equity of funds; and (ii) the supervisory framework for measuring and controlling banks’ large exposures.80 The first requirement establishes a more consistent and risk- sensitive approach for computing regulatory capital requirements for banks’ investments in equity of 79 Id. 80 Id.
  • 41. 37 funds, by appropriately reflecting both the risk of the fund’s underlying investments and its leverage. Implementation goes into effect on 1 January 2017. The supervisory framework for limiting banks’ large exposures to single counterparties seeks to protect the traditional banking sector from the risk of default of shadow bank entities. In order to meet the goal of this framework, the definition of a large exposure is now strengthened to limit carve outs and exemptions which shadow banks were previously able to take advantage of and to more clearly and consistently capture exposures to funds, securitization structures and other vehicles.81 Banks will also be subject to a hard limit on large exposures of 25% of Tier 1 capital (15% for global systemically important banks), which is more prudent than the 25% of total capital currently applied in most jurisdictions.82 The framework will be fully implemented by 1 January 2019. ii. Reducing the susceptibility of MMFs to “runs” During the financial crisis, MMFs proved wildly susceptible to contagion. The basis of the policy as implemented by the FSB originates from the IOSCO which provides the basis for common standards of regulation and the management of MMF worldwide. It also includes recommendations that regulators are to require a conversion of MMFs that have a stable Net Asset Value(NAV) to a floating Net Asset Value. National and regional authorities have since made progress in adjusting and implementing their regulatory frameworks for MMFs in conformity with these reforms. Notably, the world’s largest MMF market, the United States, adopted amendments to the rules which govern MMFs that specifically addressed risk of investor runs and maintained the benefits of MMFs.83 81 Id. 82 Id. 83 (Securities and Exchange Commission, 2014)
  • 42. 38 iii. Improving transparency and aligning incentives in securitization The IOSCO published a series of reforms that are embraced by the FSB in order to improve the transparency and alignment of incentives in securitization. These reforms improved transparency, created a high quality and standardized risk retention requirement, and established standardized disclosures.84 After review of the implementations on a national and regional level, the preliminary findings indicate good progress has been made in implementing the recommendations. A majority jurisdictions having adopted measures or taken some actions to implement the recommendations. The resumption of sound securitization is a goal of the wider financial reform program. iv. Dampening pro-cyclicality and other financial stability risks in securities financing transactions such as repos and securities lending Securities financing transactions, including lending through securities and repo agreements are central to financial intermediaries market making activities as well as to their various investment and risk management strategies. Such transaction, however, are used also by shadow banks to conduct their bank-like activities which carries obvious inherent risk from a maturity perspective as well as liquidity transformation and risks associated with leverage. Policy recommendations have now been put forth to reduce the risks associated with the dependence by shadow banks have so heavily relied for a source of their wholesale short term funding. The recommendations are standards and processes for data collection and aggregation at the global level to enhance transparency of securities financing markets; minimum standards on cash 84 (Deutsch, 2012)
  • 43. 39 collateral reinvestments; requirements on re-hypothecation85 ; minimum regulatory standards for collateral valuation and management; and policy recommendations related to structural aspects of the securities financing markets.86 These measures will help reduce excessive leverage and in turn dampen the pro-cyclicality in financial markets. The potential impact and unintended consequences are not yet fully understood. The FSB continues to measure and monitor the potential impact and is currently conducting a two stage quantitative impact assessment to ensure the goals are met by the most efficient manner. v. Assessing and mitigating systemic risks posed by other shadow banking entities and activities Recognizing that shadow banking entities and activities take a variety of forms and evolve over time, the FSB has developed a forward-looking high-level policy framework for adoption by authorities to detect and assess the sources of financial stability risks from shadow banking in the non-bank financial space, and apply appropriate policy measures where necessary to mitigate these risks.87 The framework comprises: (i) an assessment of non-bank financial entity types based on five economic functions88 ; (ii) the adoption of policy tools to mitigate financial stability risks where necessary; and (iii) information-sharing by FSB member authorities through the FSB process to maintain international consistency in applying the framework, minimize gaps in regulation and detect new adaptations.89 By focusing on economic functions (or activities) rather than legal forms, this framework is intended to allow authorities to capture innovations and adaptations. Furthermore, 85 The practice by banks and brokers of using, for their own purposes, assets that have been posted as collateral by their clients. Clients who permit re-hypothecation of their collateral may be compensated either through a lower cost of borrowing or a rebate on fees. (Rehypothecation, 2015) 86 (Financial Stability Board, 2013) 87 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014) 88 Each of the five economic functions involves non-bank credit intermediation that poses bank-like systemic risks (e.g. maturity/liquidity transformation and leverage). 89 Id.
  • 44. 40 it is expected that the framework will provide a structured process to further enhance the FSB’s annual monitoring exercise as well as for authorities to assess the need for extending the regulatory perimeter. In an active step the FSB has established an information-sharing exercise for the exchange of information on the status of national and regional authorities’ implementation of the FSB framework and to improve the detailed information-sharing methods for future uses. Thus far, the FSB has seen that most non-bank financial entities that authorities judged to be potentially involved in shadow banking activities have relevant authorities responsible for their oversight, and a range of policy tools is available to address the respective risks.90 These new regulations are draft in mind of various national reactions and needs across the global. The FSB sees the benefits as well as the risks that shadow banking and shadow entities pose to the financial stability of a nation or region. With that in mind, these recommendations are designed for various legislative bodies and securities authorities to implement in a globally standardized way to enhance the resilience of shadow banking for the next generation. V. Conclusion Shadow banks are proliferating because traditional banks are being stifled by regulations and continue their mandated reorganizing. Traditional banks have been plagued with losses incurred during the financial crisis, questionable higher capital requirements, and perpetual legal troubles coupled with outrageously expensive fines. The traditional banks are reshaping themselves as a result. Lending has been cut significantly. Shadow banks are filling these gaps. Shadow banking 90 (Financial Stability Board, November 2014)
  • 45. 41 encompasses a wide array of complex financial activities. Activities that regulators seek to either limit, like securitization, or P2P lending which regulators look to as the future of the banking system. Regulators are trying to manipulate the shadow banking sector in a good way. The shadow banking sector was a significant contributor, if not the origins of, the financial crisis of 2007-2008. Shadow banking became overly leveraged and the clear transparency quickly became opaque and then as its name implies, shadowy. The shadow banking sector can be very fragile and prone to instability just like the traditional banking model. In traditional banking this weakness comes from "runs" on the bank by depositors. This has happened several times throughout history in western banking. This gave rise to the Great Depression in the United States and then the contagion in which all other banks become at risk just due to the failure of one bank. Western countries created deposit insurance in order to mitigate this risk and give depositors the rational comfort that their deposits are safe even in the worst of financial climates. This is what regulators hope to avoid with the new plan for the shadow banking sector. The sector allows greater access to capital and assets without placing risk on the banks and in turn the tax payers. Now credit can be established by investors who carry the burden and the risk of default. This allows for greater transparency and an overall healthier financial sector around the world. Shadow banking is going to continue to be a financial reality. The lessons from 2007-2008 were bitter to swallow, but as the global economy continues its recovery, shadow banking will be leading the financial industry in giving various economies around the world the access to quick liquid capital that they need in order to sustain growth and continue to build a stronger, more resilient, financial market.
  • 46. 42 Bibliography Adrian, T., & Ashcraft, A. (2014). Shadow Banking Regulation. Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Adrian, T., Ashcraft, A., & Cetorelli, N. (2013). Shadow Bank Monitoring. Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Bakk-Simon, K., Borgioli, S., & Giron, C. (2012). Shadow Banking in the Euro Area: An Overview. European Central Bank. Borst, N. (2015, January). Non-Banks and Retail Payments: Innovations in China and the United States. Asia Focus. Carney, M. (2014, June 16). Taking shadow banking out of the shadows to create sustainable market-bsaed finance. Financial Times. Deutsch, T. (2012). Public Comment on Global Development in Securitization Regulation. International Organization of Securities Commissions. Federal Reserve Bank. (2014, July 1). The 2013 Federal Reserve Payments Study: Recent and Long- Term Trends in the United States: 2000–2012. Financial Stability Board. (2013). Strengthening Oversight and Regulation of Shadow Banking. Financial Stability Board. (2014). Global Shadow Banking Report. Financial Stability Board. (2015). What we do. Retrieved from http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/what-we-do/vulnerabilities-assessment/ Financial Stability Board. (February 2015). List of Members of the FSB Regional consultative group for Asia. Financial Stability Board. (November 2014). Transforming Shadow Banking into Resilient Market-based Financing. Hannoun, H. (2008). Financial deepening without financial excesses. Bank for International Settlements. International Monetary Fund. (October 2014). Global Financial Stability Report - Risk Taking, Liquidity, and Shadow Banking: Curbing Excess while promoting Growth. Washington. Jeffers, E., & Plihon, D. (2014). Universal Banking and Shadow Banking in Europe. Noeth, B. J., & Sengupta, R. (2011, October). Is Shadow Banking Really Banking? The Regional Economist. Pozsar, Z., Adrian, T., Ashcraft, A., & Boesky, H. (2010). Shadow Banking. Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Rehypothecation. (2015). Retrieved from Investopedia: http://www.investopedia.com/terms/r/rehypothecation.asp
  • 47. 43 Securities and Exchange Commission. (2014, July). Money Market Fund Reform, Amendments to Form PF. Smith, L. (2015). Off-Balance-Sheet Entities: An Introduction. Retrieved from Investopedia: http://www.investopedia.com/articles/analyst/022002.asp TD Bank Group. (2014, May 10). Shadow Banking in America: Bank in the Spotlight. TD Economics. The Economist. (2014, May 10). A quest of trust. The Economist. The Economist. (2014, May 1). Banking without banks. The Economist. The Economist. (2014, September 6). China's shadow banks: A moving target. The Economist. The Economist. (2014, May 10). Shadow banking in China: Battling the darkness. The Economist. (2014, May 10). The lure of shadow banking. The Economist. The Economist. (2014, May 10). We try harder. World Payment Reports. (2014). Developments in Global Payments Landscape.