SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 26
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
Artist and art dealer as a marketing channel* 
ROBERTO CELLINI and TIZIANA CUCCIA 
University of Catania, Faculty of Economics 
Corso Italia, 55 – 95129 Catania (Italy) 
tel. +39-0957537728, fax +39-0957537710 
e-mail: cellini@unict.it, cucciati@unict.it 
Abstract: We study the relationship between artist and art dealer, interpreting them as 
the members of a marketing channel, as defined by the industrial organization and 
marketing science literature. The results for both parties depend on the individual efforts 
of each of them. Uncoordinated efforts lead to inefficient outcome. The efficiency of 
different institutional settings and agreements are studied. Different ways to reach 
efficient outcome are suggested and discussed, with specific reference to the case of 
visual arts. 
Keywords: Marketing channel, effort, mechanism design. 
JEL Codes: Z-10, L-83, L-13. 
RUNNING TITLE: 
Artist and art dealer as a marketing channel 
CORRESPONDING AUTHOR: 
Roberto Cellini 
University of Catania, Dept. of Economics and Business 
Corso Italia 55 – 95129 Catania – Italy; 
e-mail cellini@unict.it 
* We are indebt to Guido Candela, Isidoro Mazza, and Antonello E. Scorcu for helpful 
comments. The usual disclaimer applies. 
1 
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2016860
Artist and art dealer as a marketing channel 
In economics and marketing science literature, marketing channel denotes the 
set of actors, practices and activities, to transfer goods from the point of production to 
the point of consumption. In the simplest case, a particular product is made by a 
manufacturer, and delivered to a retailer who sells it in the final market. Manufacturer 
and retailer are the two members of the marketing channel. If they act uncoordinatedly, 
channel inefficiencies arise, in the sense that the outcomes of the channel members are 
lower than they could be under coordination. This inefficiency is due to strategic 
behaviour in the presence of interdependence between manufacturer and retailer. 
Available literature suggests different ways to overcome inefficiency, using tools of 
industrial organization and marketing practice. 
Here, we shall study the relations between artist and art dealer, interpreting them 
as the members of a marketing channel. Figurative artist and art gallery manager are our 
main reference example. Singer (or performing art company like theatre company or 
orchestra) and event organizer may represent different specific examples of marketing 
channel in artistic fields. All these cases in arts share some features with the case of a 
manufacturer and a retailer of industrial production: the success of artistic production 
depends on the artistic effort of the “creator” (the manufacturer), as well as on the 
promotion effort made by the art gallery manager or by the live event organizer (the 
retailer, or the dealer) –in perfect symmetry with the success of industrial production 
whose revenues depend on manufacturer’s and retailer’s course of actions. 
Usually, the behaviours of each member of a marketing channel affect the final 
sales, and hence the outcome for manufacturer and retailer. Industrial organization and 
marketing studies and practice analyse the outcome of different institutional 
arrangements between the channel members, and make suggestions of specific 
arrangements, to improve the results of the channel. In the real world, a variety of cases 
can be observed: marketing channel members can take their decisions simultaneously or 
sequentially, with different roles of leader and follower. Either of the channel members 
may take the role of leader (that is, the first-mover) and may set incentive schemes to 
2 
1. Introduction 
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2016860
lead the follower to specific actions. Under particular cases, peculiar objective function 
can be the true goal of the channel members, and sometimes altruistic behaviours are 
observed: a channel member may aim at the maximum joint-result rather than at the 
maximum individual profit. 
At the same time, the artistic production presents peculiarities with respect to 
industrial production. For instance, the production of arts provides the artist with utility 
per se, and artist enjoys welfare from her own fame, apart from the economic results. 
Even art dealers’ behaviours are sometimes characterized by art for art’s sake. 
Furthermore, competition takes place in arts’ market under peculiar forms, and the role 
of price competition or quantity competition needs to be specifically qualified as 
compared to “standard industrial goods”. More importantly, peculiar arrangements are 
observed between producer and retailer, in artistic fields: perhaps the most prominent 
one is that sales sharing is the rule, rather than profit sharing, as documented by a large 
body of evidence (see, e.g., Caves, 2000, specifically p. 41, or Velthius, 2011a,b). 
Again, mechanism designs typical for industrial goods, like quantity discounting 
schemes, are clearly inappropriate (if not impossible) in the case of arts. 
Our goal is to provide a formal model, consistent with peculiarities of arts, but 
inspired from industrial organization and marketing science literature, to show that the 
marketing channel inefficiency is a feature also in the case of the arts, and –more 
interestingly– to study the efficiency property of different arrangements, commonly 
observed in the real world of arts. Finally, we aim to suggest mechanisms to overcome 
the marketing channel inefficiency. We believe that the consideration of different 
approaches, developed by industrial organization and marketing science, applied to the 
study of the relation between artist and art dealer, may be fruitful, under both a 
perspective of description of observed actions, and a normative point of view. 
2. Insights from different research lines 
In this paper, we bring together two research lines. On the one side, we consider 
the marketing channel literature, developed by both marketing and economic literature. 
Jeuland and Shugan (1982) can be considered the seminal model, even if several 
3
previous contributions could be listed, containing similar ideas (e.g., Bucklin, 1966). 
The models within this research line consider the relation between a manufacturer of a 
specific brand, and a retailer. In the simplest version, only one manufacturer interacts 
with one retailer. A market demand function is assumed, depending on retail price, set 
by the retailer, and other characteristics of the good related to choices (and efforts) 
made by the manufacturer. Advertising can play some role. Thus, the choices of both 
manufacturer and retailer affect the outcome of both. Early models focus on pricing 
problems (Jeuland and Shugan, 1982, Moorthy, 1987). Subsequent contributions 
underline that non-price aspects are equally important (e.g., Bergen and John, 1997). In 
the absence of coordination, inefficiency arises, due to opportunistic behaviours. 
Coordination hardly may emerge endogenously, because the best reply of each channel 
member to the cooperative choice of the counterpart is not the cooperative choice: a 
typical prisoner dilemma occurs. It is true that, in the presence of repeated transactions, 
cooperation could emerge tacitly, along the lines of the Folk-Theorem story, but the real 
world documents that explicit contracts are often signed, introducing explicit 
mechanisms that clearly aim to mitigate inefficiency. A number of mechanisms can be 
observed, and studied under a theoretical point of view: we may mention a variety of 
pricing schemes, including quantity discounts, quantity surcharges, two-part tariffs; 
specific rules of profit sharing among the channel members; advertising allowances, or 
subsidies to promotion costs. Jorgensen and Zaccour (1999, 2002) deal with the 
dynamic optimal problem of a marketing channel, and present some models taking a 
differential game perspective. Dynamic mechanism designs are proposed, based on 
incentive schemes regarding price setting or advertising efforts (see also Jorgensen, 
Sigue and Zaccour, 2000, 2001; Jorgensen, Taboubi and Zaccour, 2006). It is worth 
mentioning that the marketing channel can be also interpreted as a particular case of 
team production (à la Alchian and Demsetz, 1972), in which there is no firm owner, but 
the team members share the joint result deriving from their personal skills and efforts: 
Levin and Tadelis (2005) and Kaya and Vereshchagina (2009) study how the properties 
of the productive process determine the optimal contract design, and the optimal sorting 
patterns among many agents. The conclusions of these lines of research can be 
summarised, by stating that a number of price- and non-price mechanisms are available 
4
to channel members, to overcome inefficient outcomes due to opportunistic behaviours, 
both in static and in dynamic framework. 
On the other hand, cultural economics shows that artistic production shares a lot 
of aspects with standard industrial production, but presents at the same time important 
peculiarities, so that the results developed by industrial economics can be extended to 
cultural sectors with caution. Production and distribution channels are clearly present in 
many artistic sectors: artists, managers, representative agents, gatekeepers and retailers 
play important roles: Caves (2000), Sacco (1998), Throsbe (1994a), just to mention a 
few, have studied the relations among the subjects in production and distribution 
channel of artistic productions; Velthuis (2011a) reviews the specific literature on art 
dealers. 
Here, it is particularly important what Caves (2000, Ch. 2) or Velthius (2011b) 
report: they describe the main aspects of the relationship between artists and dealers, 
with particular reference to the visual arts sector.1 Common features of observed 
contracts or arrangements in arts’ marketing channels are: 
- Artist and dealer typically make informal agreements concerning their “efforts”; 
formal contracts are generally avoided (even if formal contract are more and more 
frequent in recent times); 
- Artist’s effort can hardly be defined, but number and type of works proposed are 
objects of the agreements, and can be interpreted as proxy variables for artistic 
effort; dealer’s efforts mean advertising and information campaigns, organisation of 
meetings or events, and other possible forms of promotion of artistic production; 
- In agreements or contracts between artist and dealer, the rule is the gross revenue 
5 
sharing, rather than the profit sharing; 
- Sometimes artists are called to participate to the financial efforts for promotion 
campaign; 
- Fixed payments from dealer to artist are rarely observed (such cases were more 
frequent in past times and for well-known artists). 
All these points will be ingredients of the model we are going to present. As far 
as we know, a formal model borrowing from the marketing channel literature has not jet 
proposed, with specific reference to the arts, and we aim at filling this gap.
It is worth noticing that the focus on the channel of creation and distribution of 
artistic goods leads us to disregard the secondary or resale markets of arts, and the 
dynamics of price in such market segments. Hutter et al. (2007) or Shonfeld and 
Reinstaller (2007), among many others, stress that the determinants of prices in 
secondary markets are different, as compared to primary markets. However, the 
research line on the evolution of prices in secondary markets is immaterial to our 
present study, even if -admittedly- expected future prices of artistic goods are relevant 
on current demand, so that a cautionary note has to be posed, as long as there is no role 
for expectations on future prices, in our present model. 
6 
3. The basics of the model 
We present a model, where an artist produces a good, that is sold to final consumers by 
an art dealer. 
The artist (A) chooses her artistic effort a; her fame, g, is a positive function of 
the artistic effort, and some exogenous variable, z0, according to the simple linear 
function , 0. 0 g = z +αa α > Artistic efforts entail a cost for the artist, assumed to be 
quadratic: = 2 , > 0. A A A c u a u 
The retailer (P), that is, the art dealer in this specific case (let us think of an art 
gallery manager, for instance), makes a promotional effort, p, to promote the sales of the 
artistic production manufactured by A. Promotion efforts entail a quadratic cost for the 
retailer, = 2 , > 0. P P p c u p u 
The final sales (S) of the artistic production depend on the retailer’s efforts, and 
the artist’s fame, according to a function like S =θ + β ⋅ p ⋅ g , withθ ≥ 0, β > 0 . (This 
formulation is clearly inspired by Jorgensen, Tabouti and, Zaccour, 2006). We assume 
that the fraction π (with 0 ≤π ≤ 1) of the revenues from the sales goes to the artist, and 
the fraction (1−π ) goes to the dealer. Clearly, the larger is π , the larger the share of 
sales accruing to the artist. At the moment, π is an exogenous parameter; in the real 
world, π is a contracted variable, depending on the relative fame of artist and dealer. 
Note also that the hypothesis that sale-share are contracted, rather than profit-share is
typical to the arts sector (see Caves, 2000). We finally assume that the art dealer cares 
only on his net result, R (1 )S u p2 P P = −π − , while the artist cares also on his fame, and 
her net result is: R S u a g A A =π − 2 +δ ; the positive parameter δ describes the 
importance that her own fame plays into the net result perceived by artist: the presence 
of such a term in the utility function of artist is common in cultural economics models, 
consistent with the fact that artists care not only on the monetary outcome of their 
activity, but also on non-monetary, intangible recognition, like fame (Frey, 1997; see 
also Throsby, 1994a, 1994b and, more recent, the formal model of Cuccia and Cellini, 
2009). 
Without loss of generality, and for the sake of simplicity, we will develop the 
model under the following parameter assumptions: = 0, = = 1/ 2, = = 1/ 2 A P θ α β u u , 
so that the model can be summarised by the following equations: 
2 a R gp g a p z a A −  
1 1 
2 
=π ⋅ +δ − =  π ⋅ +δ 
 
R g p p 2 1 p z 1 
a − p P 2 
7 
1 
[1] g z a 
2 
0 = + 
1 
[2] S = ⋅ g ⋅ p 
2 
[3] 
1 
2 2 
2 
2 2 
 
 +  
0 
 
 
(1 ) 1 
[4] ( ) 
2 2 
1 
2 2 
2 
0 
 
= −π ⋅ ⋅ − = −π  + 
Artist aims at maximising [3], setting her choice variable a, while the art dealer aims at 
maximising [4], setting his choice variable p. However, the result of each player (i.e., 
marketing channel member) depends also on the choice of the other player, so that a 
strategic interdependence situation is operative. The specific choices of players will 
depend on the “institutional framework” at work. For instance, we could imagine that 
the choices will be set simultaneously and independently by artist and dealer, or we 
could imagine that the choices are independent but sequential, with the possibility that 
the first-mover is the artist or the dealer. Again, we could imagine that artist and dealer 
agree on their choices, aiming at the joint result maximization. All these different 
settings will be analysed in what follows. From the point of view of the realism of
different settings, we note that it would be too easy (and hence false) to say that in the 
real world, firstly the artist sets her efforts, and then the dealer sets his promotion 
efforts: this situation clearly may happen, and perhaps it is the rule in most cases, but it 
is far from true that this arrangement covers all cases: in some cases –for instance, in 
the performing art shows– advertising campaign for a show starts before (or during) the 
show is under construction. The different institutional settings provide different 
ordering of individual and aggregate results for the channel members. 
8 
4. Results 
4.1. The simultaneous game 
Let us imagine that artist and dealer set their decision simultaneously. We denote this 
setting as the “Cournot setting”, borrowing the label from the oligopoly theory. The 
artist maximizes objective function [3], with respect to a, and derives the following 
optimal rule, which represents her reaction function: 
[5] 
+ ⋅ 
a 2 p 
4 
= 
δ π 
The dealer maximizes function [4], with respect to p, and derives the following reaction 
function: 
[6] 
2(1 ) (1 ) 0 z a 
4 
p 
− + − ⋅ 
= 
π π 
The optimal effort of the artist depends positively on the promotional effort of the 
dealer, and the promotional effort of the dealer is a positive function of the artistic effort 
of the artist: the reaction functions are positively sloped, so that the choice variables are 
strategic complements, in the terminology of oligopoly theory. The Nash equilibrium is:
δ z π π a COU 
2[ 4 + (1 − 
)] 
δ z π π δ z π π R COU 
A 
2[4 + (1 − )][4 + ( − + 
32] 
9 
[7] 
16 
2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
[8] 
z δ π 
2(4 )(1 ) 
16 
0 
− + 
2 
+ − 
= 
π π 
pCOU 
where the superscript COU stays for “Cournot”, i.e., simultaneous choice setting; note 
that both variables in equilibrium are positive, and increasing in δ and z0; 
correspondingly, the maximum outcomes reached by artist and dealer, in equilibrium, 
are respectively: 
[9] 2 2 
2 
0 0 
( − + 
16) 
= 
π π 
π z δ R COU 
P 
2(1 − ) (4 + 
) 
[10] 2 2 
2 
0 
2 
( − + 
16) 
= 
π π 
The result obtained by the dealer is strictly decreasing inπ (the higher the revenue share 
for the artist, the lower the equilibrium result for the dealer), while the result obtained 
by the artist is increasing in π for 0<π <½ , reaches its maximum in π =½ and is then 
decreasing over ½<π <1: for high levels of π , further increases of this share parameter 
lead the dealer to lower his effort to such an extent, that the artist’s result decreases. 
4.2. The sequential games 
We firstly consider the case in which the dealer sets his promotional effort after having 
observed the artistic effort chosen by the artist: in this case we are in a sequential game, 
à la Stackelberg, where the artist is the first-mover (or leader) and the dealer is the 
second-mover (follower). The leader can anticipate the choice of the follower, and can 
insert such a reaction function into her objective function: this amounts to saying that 
the artist-leader maximizes her objective function [3], considering the constraint 
represented by the reaction function of the dealer-follower [6]. The solution of the 
leader’s problem provides:
z π − π + δz + 
δ 
10 
[11] 
δ z π π 
2[2 + (1 − 
)] 
8 
2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
aSTAL 
. 
(where the superscript STAL stays for “Stackelberg, with artist leading”), and the choice 
of the dealer-follower is: 
[12] 
π z δ 
(1 − )(4 + 
) 
8 
2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
pSTAL 
The efforts exerted by both the artist and the dealer are larger than the respective efforts 
in the simultaneous choice case. Thus, it is not surprising that the individual results 
obtained in equilibrium by both parties are larger in this Stackelberg case, as compared 
to the Cournot equilibrium. Equilibrium results, when the artist is the first-mover, are: 
[13] 
8 
2 (1 ) 8 
2 
2 
0 
2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
R STAL 
A 
π z δ R STAL 
P 
(1 − ) (4 + 
) 
[14] 2 2 
2 
0 
2 
2( − + 
8) 
= 
π π 
The opposite case of sequential moving, in which the dealer is the first-mover, and the 
artist follows, is conceivable as well. In some cases, the promotion campaigns for shows 
or specific events start before the preparation of the show is finished, so that it is true 
that the artistic effort is set after the promotion effort is made. In such a case, the dealer 
is the leader, and he can anticipate the choice of the artist-follower. Analytically, the 
dealer-leader maximizes his objective function [4] under the constraint represented by 
the reaction function of the artist [5]. The optimal choice of the dealer turns out to be: 
[15] 
π z δ 
(1 − )(4 + 
) 
8 
2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
pSTAF
where superscript STAF stays for “Stackelberg with artist following”, and the reaction 
of the artist, in equilibrium is 
δ π π z π π aSTAF 
( − + 16) + 4 (1 − 
) 
0 
z π π δ π π δ π π z π π R STAF 
A 
[4 (3 − 3 + 32) + ( − + 16)][ ( − + 16) + 4 (1 − 
)] 
11 
[16] 
2 
4( 8) 
2 
− + 
= 
π π 
The artist is led to make an effort, as second-mover, larger than the effort set as a first-mover. 
As far as the art dealer is concerned, his effort, as the leader of the Stackelberg 
game, is equal to the effort made as the follower of the Stackelberg game. 
By straight substitutions into the objective functions, we obtain the results of 
both parts in equilibrium, when the dealer leads and the artist follows: 
[17] 
2 
32( 8) 
0 
2 2 2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
π z δ R STAF 
P 
(1 − ) (4 + 
) 
[18] 2 2 
2 
0 
2 
16( − + 
8) 
= 
π π 
By simple comparisons, we can state that, for any π (with 0 <π < 1, that is excluding 
the limit cases),2 the following relations hold: 
; 
; 
; 
; 
COU STAL STAF 
a < a < 
a 
COU STAL STAF 
STAl 
P 
p < p = 
p 
R < R < 
R 
STAF 
P 
COU 
P 
STAF 
A 
STAL 
A 
COU 
A 
R < R < 
R 
This means that each player prefers any sequential settings to the simultaneous choice 
setting, and –in the sequential settings– each of the players prefers to be the follower 
rather than the leader. This ordering of individual outcomes is consistent with analogous 
results obtained in games in which choice variables are strategic complements.
4.3. The cooperative setting (joint result) 
If channel members aim at the maximum joint result, they face the following problem: 
[ 2 2 ] 
Max R R R 1 z a p a p A P 
(2 )(2 ) 2 2 
4 
, 0 
12 
JOINT 
a p 
= + = + δ + − − 
We could label this setting as the coordinated setting (or the cartel setting, borrowing 
from oligopoly theory). From the first order conditions we obtain: 
[19] 
2(4 ) 0 z 
p JOINT + 
15 
= 
δ 
[20] 
2( 4 ) 0 z 
a JOINT + 
15 
= 
δ 
Some comments are in order. First, the efforts of each part are the highest, with 
respect to all considered settings. This means that the maximum joint result requires the 
highest efforts by both parts. Second, both the Cournot setting and the Stackelberg 
settings provide the players with individual equilibrium results whose sum is smaller as 
compared to the sum of results they can obtain in the coordinated setting. In other 
words, strategic interaction leads to inefficient outcomes; this result is well known by 
marketing channel literature. Third, parameter π disappears from the problem of the 
coordinated setting, consistently with the fact that π captures an aspect related to the 
division of a common result, that is immaterial to the maximum of the common result in 
itself. 
Of course, the problem of the division of the common result remains open, after 
the coordinated choices are set. As far as the division of result is concerned, we assume 
that the artist obtains the share π of the sales, and the dealer obtains the complement 
share 1−π , while the term δa goes entirely to the artist; needless to say, this is only one 
–rather obvious– assumption concerning the division of the “cartel result”. Under the 
above mentioned rule of sharing, the dealer and the artist obtain the following 
individual results:
[21] 2 [ (32 1) (7 )(16 2 2 
)] 
2 
0 R JOINT = z π − + +π δz + δ 
A 
R JOINT = 2 − π z +δ 
P 
13 
225 
0 
[22] 2 
0 (1 2 )(4 ) 
225 
and hence, under the above mentioned rule of sharing, the cartel situation provides the 
artist a higher result with respect to the Cournot situation for any π >0.1350, and 
provides the dealer with a higher result as compared to the Cournot situation for any 
π <0.24085. Similar comparisons can be readily made with respect to the Stackelberg 
settings. In any case, apart from the cartel situation, any other setting is Pareto-inefficient 
– in the sense that a different situation can be found, with appropriate sharing 
of the result, where each player can be better off. 
As is well-known, the choices associated with the efficient outcome do not 
represent a Nash equilibrium, at least in the one-shot game. This amounts to saying that 
informal or non-binding agreements concerning socially efficient levels of individual 
efforts are not self-enforcing. In Section 5 we study how it is possible to replicate the 
efficient outcome, on the basis of more-complex self-enforcing agreements. Eventually, 
we will discuss the degree of efficiency of different types agreements, observed in the 
real world of arts’ markets. Remember that formal binding contracts (ideally replicating 
the efficient outcome) are rarely observed in the filed of arts, also because their 
enforcement is difficult, due to the fact that relevant key variables (like the artistic 
efforts) are hardly definable and measurable. 
5. Replication of efficient outcome 
The available literature on marketing channel has suggested several contract designs, 
able to lead the parts to replicate the choices associated to the efficient outcome. In the 
cases of industrial goods, for instance, specific profit share designs, advertising 
allowances, quantity discount schemes, are possible solutions: it is a well-established
result that a multiplicity of effective solutions exist, to overcome the inefficiency of 
decentralised decisions in marketing channel situations. In order to make such 
arrangements self-enforcing, it is necessary to assure that each part obtains a larger 
result, as compared to the individual result obtained in uncoordinated setting. 
Here we focus on the case at hand and we limit to propose two different 
solutions: the first one has a theoretical interest, but it is hardly implementable in the 
real world; it is appropriate for the context in which choices are set simultaneously. The 
second one is appropriate when the artist set her artistic efforts firstly, and the dealer 
follows –a situation more frequently observed in the real world; for this reason we will 
spend more attention on it. 
The relevant question can be posed specifically as follows: How is it possible to 
lead the artist to set her effort at the efficient level given by [20], and the dealer to set 
his effort at the efficient level [19]? 
5.1. Linear subsidies in the simultaneous choice setting 
Consider the case in which artist and art dealer set their choices simultaneously. 
Assume that artist has to pay a subsidy ψ to the dealer for each unit of promotional 
effort he makes; at the same time, the dealer has to pay a subsidy ω to the artist for 
each unit of artistic effort she makes. The problems of artist and dealer can be written, 
respectively, as follows 
1 2 
[23] Max R =  ⋅ p + 
 
z 1 
a a p a a A 
π  
δ  +  
− − ψ + ω 1  
2 
14 
 
 
2 2 
2 
0 
[24] Max R ( )p z a p p a p P 
1 1 
2 
= −  + 
ω ψ π − + −  
 
2 2 
0 
From the first order conditions, the following reaction functions can be easily derived: 
π ⋅ + 2δ + 4ω 
[25] 
4 
a = p
(1 ) 2 (1 ) 4 0 −π ⋅ + −π + ψ 
= a z 
p 
πψ δ ω π π z 
2[2( + 2 + 4 ) + (1 − 
) ] 
z δ π ψ ω π 
2[(4 + )(1 − ) + 2(4 + (1 − 
))] 
15 
[26] 
4 
The corresponding equilibrium efforts are: 
[27] 
16 
2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
a 
[28] 
16 
2 
0 
− + 
= 
π π 
p 
Appropriate levels of ψ and ω can be computed, to render the effort levels [27] and 
[28] equal to the efficient levels [20] and [19], respectively; the solution is: 
[29] 
2 (4 ) 0 π δ 
15 
ψ 
+ 
= z 
[30] 
= z 
(1 )(4 ) 0 π δ 
30 
ω 
− + 
The subsidy levels given by [29] and [30] lead each member of the channel to set the 
individual choice that replicates the efficient outcome of the maximum joint result. Note 
that the higher is the share for the artist, the higher the amount of unit subsidy that she 
has to give to the dealer. By appropriate substitutions, it is possible to compute the 
individual results obtained by channel members under such arrangement, and to 
compare them with the result obtained in the uncoordinated Cournot setting. It is 
immediate to verify that only over a limited range of parameter configuration, each 
member receives a larger outcome as compared to the uncoordinated setting; outside 
that range, appropriate transfer are necessary to make the socially efficient arrangement 
convenient even for each members under a strictly individualistic point of view. 
It is also interesting to note that: (a) in the limiting case where π = 0 , the 
efficient levels of unit subsidies become ψ = 0 and (4 ) / 30 0 ω = z +δ : this arrangement 
describes a situation in which all revenues from sales go to the dealer, but he commits to 
give the artist a subsidy for her artistic effort; (b) in the limiting case where π = 1, the
efficient outcome is reproduced by the subsidy scheme ω = 0 , 2(4 ) /15 0 ψ = z +δ , 
which means that all revenues from sales go to the artist, but she commits to give the 
dealer appropriate subsidy for each unit of promotional effort of his. Also in these 
limiting cases, the efficient solution is reproduced, but appropriate lump-sum transfer is 
necessary to make the arrangement dominant for each member also from a strictly 
individualistic point of view. 
The real implementation of the subsidy design in this simultaneous moving 
setting, however, should require that artistic efforts are definable and measurable – a 
hardly tenable assumption. One could also observe that if this mechanism design is 
implementable in the real world, no reason exists why a formal contract concerning 
directly the efficient levels of efforts is not implementable. The substantial obstacle to 
contract enforcement in the case of arts rest on the possibility of defining and measuring 
artistic efforts. Such obstacles can be avoided in the sequential setting, if artist set her 
efforts firstly. 
5.2. Quadratic subsidy in the Stackelberg setting, with artist leader. 
Consider the case that the artist sets her artistic effort firstly, and then the art dealer sets 
the promotional effort; equilibrium levels of efforts in the uncoordinated setting are 
given by [11] and [12], which represent an inefficient allocation from a marketing 
channel point of view. 
Imagine that the artist commits herself to give a subsidy (σ p) to the dealer 
(with σ ≥ 0 ), for each unit of promotional effort of his, so that the total subsidy from 
artist to dealer is σ p2 . The net result of artist and dealer, under such an agreement are 
respectively: 
R  
 
=  1 π ⋅ p + 
δ  
 z + 1 
a − a − σ p A [31] 2 
2 
R 1 p z a p p P σ π + −  
16 
2 
0 2 2 
2 
 
 
 
1 1 
2 
 
= −  + 
[32] ( ) 2 
0 2 2 
 
It is immediate to find the reaction function of the dealer:
π z a p 
1 2 0 < 
, 1 
for SQS 
(3 π − 1) / 2(1 + π ) 1/ 3 < π 
≤ 
1 
= 
0 0 1/ 3 
z for 
= RSQS z z 
A 
2[ (1 + ) + 32 + 
4 ] 
π δ δ 
− − 
17 
[33] 
( )( ) 
2 
− + 
= σ 
4(1 − 
2 σ 
) 
This reaction function has to be inserted in the in the leader’s problem, and 
different cases could be taken into account. 
Case I (Digression). The artist aims at her own maximum, and sets σ and a 
accordingly. We denote this case as the case of a selfish artist. It is easy to check that 
the maximum private result for the artist requires 
[34] 
   
≤ π 
≤ 
σ 
for 
2[ (1 ) 16 ] 
 
+ + 
π δ 
[35] ; 
0 1/ 3 
1/ 3 1 
63 2 
2 
2 
0 
 
 
≤ ≤ 
< ≤ 
− − 
= 
π 
π 
π π 
a for 
a 
STAL 
SQS 
(superscript SQS stays for “selfish quadratic subsidy”). This means that the artist finds 
it convenient to give a positive subsidy to the dealer only for sufficiently high levels of 
π . Clearly, for 0 ≤π ≤ 1/ 3, that is, in the situation of the corner solution corresponding 
to nil subsidy, optimal choices replicate the simple situation à la Stackelberg (without 
subsidy) with the artist as the leader, and individual results coincide with [13] and [14]. 
For 1/ 3 <π ≤ 1, subsidy is positive, and individual results are: 
[36] 2 
2 
0 
2 2 
0 
63 2 
π π 
= RSQS z 
P 
16(1 − )(4 + 
) 
π δ 
− − 
[37] 2 2 
2 
0 
2 
(63 2 π π 
) 
whose sum is smaller than the cartel outcome. It is interesting to note that, for high 
levels of π , it is in the interest of a selfish artist to provide the dealer with a subsidy for
SQS turns out to be larger than RA 
2 2 
2 
0 RCQS = z π − + δz π + +δ π + 
A , 
0 RCQS = −π z +δ 
π π π z δ R RSTAL 
(2 + 26 − 12 − 1)(4 + 
) 
CQS 
A is positive only for 
18 
the promotional effort: RA 
STAL for any π included in the 
range (1/3,1]. 
Case II. The artist sets σ in order to lead the follower to replicate pJOINT, and 
sets a=aJOINT. This case can be denoted as the case of a cartel-oriented artist (or 
benevolent artist, in the sense that he takes care of the whole marketing channel). From 
the dealer’s reaction function [33], it is immediate to find that p= pJOINT requires: 
[38] σ =π / 2 
with 0<π <1 and hence 0<σ <1/2. Correspondingly, the channel members’ net results 
are: 
[39] [ (16 1) 8 ( 14) ( 14)] 
225 
0 
2 
[40] [(1 )(4 )] 
225 
P 
where superscript CQS stays for “cartel quadratic subsidy”. Of course, the sum of the 
results given by [39] and [40] coincides with the efficient joint result. However, from an 
individualist point of view, each channel member is ready to implement this agreement, 
only if it provides a larger individual result as compared to decentralised decisions. 
From the dealer’s point of view, result [40] is higher than results [14] or [37], for 
any 0<π <1. This means (quite obviously) that the dealer prefers the situation in which 
the artist is cartel-oriented rather than selfish. 
From the artist’s point of view, we have to distinguish, according to π be larger 
or smaller than 1/3. 
(i) If 0 ≤π ≤1/ 3 , the result [39] is higher than result [13] only for levels of π 
higher than a threshold level. More precisely, 
2 
225( 8) 
2 
0 
3 2 
− + 
− = 
π π 
A
( ) 2 3 26 2 12 1 0 
1 f π ≡ π + π − π − > , that is, 0.07 1 π ≥π ≈ . This means that for 
1/ 3 1 π ≤π ≤ , it is in the interest of a selfish artist to implement the cartel allocation. 
The result that a manufacturer, under given parameter conditions, may find it 
convenient to pursue the maximum of the channel is not a novelty in the marketing 
channel literature (see, in a different framework, Jorgenson et al., 2006, Section 4). For 
1 0 ≤π <π , in order to make the cartel choice convenient for the artist, a further lump-sum 
transfer from the dealer to the artist must be required. Let τ denote such a transfer 
from the dealer to the artist. If we compare the outcomes (under the quadratic subsidy 
and transfer) with the case of nil subsidy, in order to make the arrangement self-enforcing, 
we have to fix τ in a way such that: STAL 
τ τ τ 
< < 
( − 2 π − 26 π + 12 π + 1)(4 + 
δ 
) 
(1 − π )(4 π − 8 π + 68 π + 161 π + 31)(4 + 
δ 
) 
CQS 
A R +η > R and SQS 
P 
, 
η η η 
< < 
2( π + 16 π − 35 π + 18)(4 + 
δ 
) 
225(63 2 ) 
2(1 − π )( π + 4 π − 122 π − 2052 π + 2169)(4 + 
δ 
) 
19 
R CQS 
+τ > R STAL 
and R CQS 
−τ > R , 
A A 
P 
P 
which means: 
[41] 
2 2 
2 
0 
4 3 2 
1 2 
2 
2 
2 
0 
3 2 
1 
450( 8) 
, 
225( 8) 
; 
− + 
= 
− + 
= 
π π 
τ 
π π 
τ 
z 
z 
(note that 1 τ is positive for any level of 0.07 1 π <π ≈ ). 
(ii) For π included in the interval [1/3, 1], it can be easily checked that 
SQS>RA 
RA 
CQS, and (RA 
SQS+RP 
SQS)<(RA 
CQS+RP 
CQS). Thus, a transfer (from the dealer to the 
artist) has to be designed, to lead the artist (who sets σ and a) to behave in the interest 
of the channel. Specifically, a lump-sum transfer η > 0 can be found, from dealer to 
artist, such that SQS 
A 
CQS 
P R −η > R . Simple computations permit to 
find that the two conditions correspond to 
[42] 
2 2 
2 
0 
4 3 2 
1 2 
2 
2 
2 
0 
3 2 
1 
225(63 2 ) 
; 
π π 
η 
π π 
η 
− − 
= 
− − 
= 
z 
z
One can interpret η as the price that the dealer has to pay to the artist, in order to lead 
the artist to behave in the interest of the channel, instead of in a selfish way. In words, 
the story can be told as follows. If the artist is the leader of the marketing channel, an 
arrangement can be identified, which leads to the efficient outcome, and which is self-enforcing 
in the sense that it is impossible to find alternative outcomes in which both 
members are better off (i.e., no room for convenient deviation does exist); the 
arrangement is as follows: (i) the sales are divided according to the positive fractions π 
and 1−π , for artist and dealer respectively, with π >1/3; (ii) the artist gives the dealer 
the subsidy σp2 = (π / 2) p2 , linked to the promotional efforts of his; (iii) the dealer 
gives the artist the fixed sum 1 2 η <η <η , conditional on the fact that the artist set 
a=aJOINT. Under such conditions, the artist finds it optimal to set the efficient effort 
a=aJOINT, and the best reply of the dealer is p=pJOINT. 
In sum, we have found that for some parameter values ( 1/ 3 1 π ≤π ≤ ), it is in the 
(individualistic) interest of the artist, to behave in the interest of the cartel; outside such 
a parameter range, a self-enforcing mechanism is found, able to replicate the efficient 
outcome. In such a mechanism: (i) sales are shared among artist and art dealer, (ii) the 
artist receives an additional fixed amount from the dealer; (iii) the artist pays the dealer 
for his promotional effort. The mechanism is efficient because each member replicates 
the choice associated with the joint-maximization case, and the mechanism is self-enforcing, 
because each channel member has no incentive to deviate from the efficient 
20 
choices. 
6. Comments and concluding remarks 
Here we have pointed out that artists and art dealers constitute a marketing channel, in 
the sense defined by economics and marketing science literature: in several cases, for 
industrial goods, a good is manufactured by a firm, and sold to a retailer which sells it in 
the final market; the result for both subjects –producer and retailer, that is, the channel 
members– depend on the efforts made by each of them. Like in the more general case of 
team production, strategic interdependence and incomplete information generate room
for inefficient results, if subjects act in a uncoordinated manner, and each actor is 
oriented to his/her individual maximum result. The situation in the arts’ markets is very 
similar. Artist and art dealer benefit from results which depend on the efforts of both. 
We have shown that the theoretical results obtained by industrial organization and 
marketing science hold, by and large, for the arts markets as well. In the arts markets, 
however, specific characteristics are worth taking into account. 
History and the current real world document a variety of agreements between art 
makers and art dealers, in different arts’ markets (visual arts, performing arts, and so 
on).3 For instance, employment, direct acquisition and consignments are alternative, 
possible forms of agreements in the case of visual arts; however, in current day 
experience, the consignment is the most frequent form of agreement. Caves (2000, 
especially Chs. 2 and 3) and Velthius (2011a,b), with particular reference to the case of 
visual arts, provide a list of “typical” behaviors in the to-day relations between artists 
and art dealers. These characteristics have shaped the specific model we have presented 
in this paper. 
First, formal contracts between artists and art dealers (especially in the cases of 
painter and art gallery) are generally avoided, in real world: informal deals (and moral 
obligations) are more common forms of agreements. The reasons why formal contracts 
are rare can be easily understood: complete terms are difficultly stated in a contract; 
monitoring activities are difficult to be conducted; litigations are expensive and 
financial compensation from successful litigations nearly impossible to be obtained. 
Nevertheless, in recent years, a larger use of written contracts is claimed (especially by 
artists) and observed (Vinick, 1997). The absence of a large body of detailed contracts 
makes a robust analysis of contracts impossible, and the comment have to focus on 
episodic or anecdotic evidence. 
Second, the typical agreement has the form of ‘consignment contract’: the artist 
consigns her artworks to the dealer (who exhibits them), in order to be sold. The 
agreement could prescribe number and type of artworks to be delivered. The dealer 
receive a share of the revenues, as a counterpart of his activity of promotion. Pay in 
advance and/or regular wage are very uncommon.4 
Third, as a matter of fact, the role of the art dealer is more complex than just 
selling the artistic items: an art dealer acts as an agent (both for the artist, and for 
21
institutional buyers like museums or private collectors): for this reason, the assumption 
that the dealer makes efforts to promote the artistic production is meaningful, in the case 
of the arts, and the promotion actions in the hands of an art dealer are wider and 
potentially more effective as compared to the typical actions available to a retailer in the 
case of industrial goods. An art dealer is expected: to provide information to critics, 
certifiers, art writers, museum curators, and media; to organize exhibitions; to provide 
items for temporary exhibitions; to compose books and further editorial catalogs; to 
make (traditional) advertising campaigns in journals and specialized reviews; to spend 
time with prospective clients articulating the artist’s intent (Caves, 2000, p. 38): all 
these activities define the dealer’s efforts. Especially in contemporary arts, we can say 
the efforts of the dealer contribute to the definition of the characteristics of artistic 
product. 
Fourth, it is worth stressing, once again, that revenue share, rather than profit 
share, is the rule. This aspect is of particular importance, since it entails that the channel 
members are not reimbursed for specific expenses. Documented exceptions are rather 
limited: in the case of visual arts, for instance, one can seldom observe a participation of 
artist in expenses of dealer, e.g. for advertising, catalogues and framework. 
Fifth, it is difficult (if not impossible) that dealer can participate to the artistic 
effort exerted by the artist. Artist’s effort is hardy observable, and the observable result 
of her are weakly linked to the effort (whatever “effort” could mean in artistic fields). In 
observed agreements, efforts are at generally linked to the number of pieces that the 
artist commits to deliver to the dealer, in a time interval. 
Sixth, artists typically complain about the limited efforts of dealers, and dealers 
complain about the limited efforts of artists. In the specialized newspaper Art World 
News we can read: “An artist fails to deliver quality works in sufficient number. A dealer fails 
to promote an artists' work. These are only two types of claims that have recently led to disputes 
between artists and dealers” (Vinick,1997, p. 1). 
The perceptions of each member of the marketing channel that the other member 
does not exert a sufficient level of effort are really very common. The fact that these 
perceptions may be well founded is supported by our present theoretical model. The 
above mentioned characteristics of typical agreements between artist and dealer lead to 
a situation in which each part exerts a lower amount of effort as compared to the 
22
efficient level: this is due to the strategic interdependence. Possible agreements 
concerning socially-efficient levels of individual efforts are not self-enforcing, as long 
as each actor has an incentive to free-riding. Thus, in our interpretation, the true root of 
inefficiency does not rest on asymmetric information (which in any case, does exist, and 
explains why it is nearly impossible to sign formal binding contracts), nor in agency-type, 
i.e., principal-agent relationship (which in any case could be appropriate for 
describing some aspects of the relations), but simply in the team-type production 
process which is relevant for artistic items, as they are sold in today markets, where 
marketing channels are really relevant. 
We have shown that specific designs for contracts would be able to overcome 
inefficiency. Many efficient contracts are in principle possible. Reciprocal cross-subsidies 
have been shown to met the efficiency condition, in a situation in which artist 
and art dealer exert their efforts simultaneously. A further example has been provided, 
for the case in which artist and art dealer take their decisions sequentially (with the artist 
leading), and in which artist and art dealer split the revenues from sales: in such a case, 
the artist may be required to participate to the promotional efforts of dealer (according 
to a quadratic subsidy), and receives a lump-sum transfer; the amount of the lump-sum 
transfer has to be linked to the values of the agreed revenue-share, and to the amount of 
the subsidy to promotional efforts. Interestingly enough, in accordance with available 
results in marketing channel literature, we have found that –under certain parameter 
configuration, and specifically under given values of share according to which revenues 
are split– there is no conflict between individual and collective incentive, in the sense 
that it can be in the egoistic interest of a member of the channel to act in the interest of 
the whole channel. 
As far as we know, this type of contracts are not used in to-day arts’ market, at 
least in the case of visual arts. Under this perspective, our paper may provide useful 
suggestions to artists and dealers. 
23
REFERENCES 
Alchian A. – Demsetz H. (1972) “Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization”, 
American Economic Review, vol. 62, pp. 777-95. 
Alper N.O. – Wassall G.H. (2006), “Artists' Careers and Their Labor Markets”, in V. A. 
Ginsburgh – D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, North Holland, 
Amsterdam, pp. 813-64. 
Bergen M. – John G (1997), “Understanding cooperative advertising participation rates in 
conventional channels”, Journal of Marketing Research, vol. 34, pp. 357-69. 
Caves R. E. (2000), Creative Industries. Contracts between Art and Commerce, Harvard 
University Press, Cambridge, Ma, Us. 
Cuccia T. – Cellini R. (2009), “Workers’ Enterprises and The Taste for Production: The Arts, 
Sport and Other Cases”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 56, pp. 123-37. 
De Marchi N. – Van Miegroet H.J. (2006), “The History of Art Markets”, in V. A. Ginsburgh – 
D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, North Holland, Amsterdam, 
pp. 69-122. 
Frey B. S. (1997), Not Just for the Money, Edward Edgar, Cheltenham. 
Hutter M. – Knebel C. – Pietzner G. – Schafer M. (2007), “Two Games in Town: A 
Comparison of Dealer and Auction Prices in Contemporary Visual Arts Markets”, Journal of 
Cultural Economics, vol. 31, pp. 247-61. 
Jeuland A. P – Shugan S. M. (1983), “Managing Channel Profits”, Marketing Science, vol. 2, 
pp. 239-72. 
Jorgensen S. – Zaccour G., (2003), “Channel Coordination over Time: Incentive Equilibria and 
Credibility” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 27, pp. 801-27. 
Kaya A. – Vereshchagina G. (2009), “Moral Hazard and Sorting in a Market for Partnership”, 
Mimeo, Arizona State University. 
Levine J. – Tadelis S. (2005), “Profit Sharing and the Role of Professional Partenership”, 
Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 120, pp. 131-71. 
Menger P.M. (2006), “Artistic Labor Markets”, in , in V. A. Ginsburgh – D. Throsby (Eds.), 
Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 765-811. 
Moorthy K. S. (1987), “Managing Channel Profits: Comment”, Marketing Science, vol. 6, pp. 
375-79. 
Sacco P. (1998), “La selezione dei giovani artisti nei mercati delle arti visive”, in: W Santagata 
(Ed.), Economia dell’Arte, UTET, Torino. 
Schonfeld S. – Reinstaller A. (2007), “The Effects of Gallery and Artist Reputation on Prices in 
the Primary Market for Art: A Note”, Journal of Cultural Economics, vol. 31, pp. 143-53. 
Tamperi T. (2006), La vendita di opere d’arte fra tutela e mercato, Clueb, Bologna. 
24
Throsby D. (1994a), "The Production and Consumption of the Arts: A View of Cultural 
Economics", Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1-29. 
Throsby D. (1994b), "A Work-Preference Model of Artist Behaviour", in A. Peacock - I. Rizzo 
(eds.), Cultural Economics and Cultural Policies, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, pp. 
69-80. 
Velthuis O. (2011a), “Art dealers” in Towse R. (ed.), A Handbook of Cultural Economics, 
Second Edition, Edward Elgar Cheltenham. 
Velthuis O. (2011b), “Visual Arts” in Towse R. (ed.), A Handbook of Cultural Economics, 
Second Edition, Edward Elgar Cheltenham. 
Vinick P. A. (1997) “Art Dealers Need Written Contracts Specifying All Aspects of Dealer- 
Artist Agreements”, ArtWorldNews, February (also downloadable from the website 
http://www.fphlcc.ca/downloads/art dealers-need-written-contracts.pdf, Dec. 2011). 
25
26 
NOTES 
1 Caves (2000), in a different chapter, considers also the cases of writers (editorial industry) and 
singers (disco industry), which we overlook in the present paper. 
2 Relations in the limiting cases are trivial. For π = 0 , aCOU = aSTAL = aSTAF = δ / 2 , and 
(4 ) / 8 0 pCOU = pSTAL = pSTAF = z +δ , so that the individual results coincide across the 
different settings; for π =1, aCOU = aSTAL = aSTAF = δ / 2 , and pCOU = pSTAL = pSTAF = 0 , so 
that also in this case individual results are the same across the considered regimes. 
3 A short history of the relations between artists and dealers can be found in De Marchi and Van 
Miegroet (2006, Section 4). The variety of employment status and careers of artists are dealt 
with by, e.g., Menger (2006) and Alper and Wassall (2006). 
4 Velthius (2011b), lists three main possible forms of agreements between artist and art dealers, 
in the case of visual arts: (1) employment with stipend, (2) direct acquisition, and (3) 
consignment. However, employment is not common today (exceptions are the low-tail of the 
market where artists copy standardized artworks for mass markets); famous cases of 
employment with fixed wage concern artists in past times: for instance, art dealer D. H. 
Kahnweiler paid (young) Picasso on a regular stipend, believing him as potential well-gifted 
artist; similar contracts were used by dealers Russo for Giorgio De Chirico (at the beginning of 
XX century) and by L. Castelli for promising young pop-artists in New York around 1960. 
Under such an agreement (also known as contrat-mecenat –see Tamperi, 2006), the artist 
commits to deliver a certain number of pieces in a given period of time, and receives a fixed 
salary, e.g., on monthly base; the art dealer usually keeps all the revenues from artworks’ sale. 
Alternatively, under direct acquisition contract, the dealer buys artworks from the artist and 
then decides when and at what price to sell them; such a system (also refereed as ‘the French 
system’, since it was common in the late XIX century in France) requires large (capital and 
financial) resources from the dealers, since they have to buy the artworks, and implies that the 
dealer runs the risk that the economic value will be never realized; it is rare in the today world. 
The largest part of today agreements base on consignment: the artist consigns her pieces to the 
dealer (who exhibit them); if and when a piece is sold, artist and dealer split the revenues, on a 
previously agreed terms. We have thought of this kind of agreement, in building the present 
model.

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Andere mochten auch

The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...Asliza Hamzah
 
Cyber law assignment
Cyber law assignmentCyber law assignment
Cyber law assignmentRini Mahade
 
La1 Malaysia Cyber Laws
La1 Malaysia Cyber LawsLa1 Malaysia Cyber Laws
La1 Malaysia Cyber LawsCma Mohd
 
Cyber Law from Malaysia Perspective
Cyber Law from Malaysia PerspectiveCyber Law from Malaysia Perspective
Cyber Law from Malaysia PerspectiveRurouni Khairul
 
Online defamation through social media an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...
Online defamation through social media  an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...Online defamation through social media  an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...
Online defamation through social media an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...International Islamic University Malaysia
 
Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203
Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203
Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203Faridah Husin
 
Introduction to Intellectual Property Rights
Introduction to Intellectual Property RightsIntroduction to Intellectual Property Rights
Introduction to Intellectual Property RightsJamil AlKhatib
 
Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights
Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights
Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights JRA & Associates
 
Intellectual Property Rights
Intellectual Property RightsIntellectual Property Rights
Intellectual Property Rightsharshhanu
 

Andere mochten auch (19)

The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
 
Patent Law 101
Patent Law 101Patent Law 101
Patent Law 101
 
Cyber law assignment
Cyber law assignmentCyber law assignment
Cyber law assignment
 
La1 Malaysia Cyber Laws
La1 Malaysia Cyber LawsLa1 Malaysia Cyber Laws
La1 Malaysia Cyber Laws
 
01 Cyber Safe Malaysia Website Fundamentals
01 Cyber Safe Malaysia Website Fundamentals 01 Cyber Safe Malaysia Website Fundamentals
01 Cyber Safe Malaysia Website Fundamentals
 
IP in Malaysia
IP in MalaysiaIP in Malaysia
IP in Malaysia
 
Cyber Law
Cyber LawCyber Law
Cyber Law
 
Cyberlaw
CyberlawCyberlaw
Cyberlaw
 
Introduction to intellectual property law
Introduction to intellectual property lawIntroduction to intellectual property law
Introduction to intellectual property law
 
Cyber Law from Malaysia Perspective
Cyber Law from Malaysia PerspectiveCyber Law from Malaysia Perspective
Cyber Law from Malaysia Perspective
 
Air-Space Law
Air-Space LawAir-Space Law
Air-Space Law
 
Online defamation through social media an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...
Online defamation through social media  an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...Online defamation through social media  an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...
Online defamation through social media an attempt to reconcile conflicts bet...
 
Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203
Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203
Assignment of cyber crimes for oumh1203
 
Malaysia's National Cyber Security Policy
Malaysia's National Cyber Security PolicyMalaysia's National Cyber Security Policy
Malaysia's National Cyber Security Policy
 
Cyber Law
Cyber  LawCyber  Law
Cyber Law
 
Introduction to Intellectual Property Rights
Introduction to Intellectual Property RightsIntroduction to Intellectual Property Rights
Introduction to Intellectual Property Rights
 
Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights
Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights
Intellectual Property Rights In India: Patents Trademarks And Copyrights
 
Cyber law
Cyber lawCyber law
Cyber law
 
Intellectual Property Rights
Intellectual Property RightsIntellectual Property Rights
Intellectual Property Rights
 

Ähnlich wie ARTIST AND ART DEALER AS A MARKETING CHANNEL

Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...
Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...
Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...Vincent Lagarde
 
Strategic analysis through general electric
Strategic analysis through general electricStrategic analysis through general electric
Strategic analysis through general electricHenok Fasil
 
Toursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdf
Toursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdfToursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdf
Toursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdfAmitangshu Datta
 
PUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTH
PUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTHPUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTH
PUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTHAditiJain307041
 
Strategic Marketing
Strategic MarketingStrategic Marketing
Strategic Marketingvameyer
 
Microeconomics
Microeconomics   Microeconomics
Microeconomics Elif Bedir
 
Trend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy Market
Trend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy MarketTrend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy Market
Trend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy MarketSteven843Summers
 
Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...
Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...
Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...Business, Management and Economics Research
 
363-wcms_366005.pdf
363-wcms_366005.pdf363-wcms_366005.pdf
363-wcms_366005.pdfMideksa1
 
Market structure of bangladesh
Market structure of bangladeshMarket structure of bangladesh
Market structure of bangladeshMuwas Mia
 
Monopolistic Competition Economics Assignment Help
Monopolistic Competition Economics Assignment HelpMonopolistic Competition Economics Assignment Help
Monopolistic Competition Economics Assignment HelpSample Assignment
 
Price elasticity is a crucial concept in economics
Price elasticity is a crucial concept in economicsPrice elasticity is a crucial concept in economics
Price elasticity is a crucial concept in economicsSAINATHYADAV11
 
Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3
Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3
Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3Santiago Guillen
 
Criteria for Investing In the Market of Visual Arts
Criteria for Investing In the Market of Visual ArtsCriteria for Investing In the Market of Visual Arts
Criteria for Investing In the Market of Visual Artsinventionjournals
 

Ähnlich wie ARTIST AND ART DEALER AS A MARKETING CHANNEL (20)

Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...
Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...
Setting the boundaries for social LCA in comparison with environmental LCA, E...
 
Strategic analysis through general electric
Strategic analysis through general electricStrategic analysis through general electric
Strategic analysis through general electric
 
Art Mix
Art MixArt Mix
Art Mix
 
Eae 408
Eae 408Eae 408
Eae 408
 
Toursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdf
Toursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdfToursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdf
Toursim+Marketing+F23+Block+1.pdf
 
PUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTH
PUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTHPUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTH
PUBLIC_HEALTH_MARKETING AND STRATEGIES IN HEALTH
 
Strategic Marketing
Strategic MarketingStrategic Marketing
Strategic Marketing
 
ME U9.pdf
ME U9.pdfME U9.pdf
ME U9.pdf
 
Microeconomics
Microeconomics   Microeconomics
Microeconomics
 
market and nationa income
market and nationa incomemarket and nationa income
market and nationa income
 
Trend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy Market
Trend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy MarketTrend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy Market
Trend-Setting Market Segmentation - A New Wave In The German Born Energy Market
 
Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...
Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...
Automotive Cluster and Territorial Development: Comparative Cases between Ger...
 
363-wcms_366005.pdf
363-wcms_366005.pdf363-wcms_366005.pdf
363-wcms_366005.pdf
 
Market structure of bangladesh
Market structure of bangladeshMarket structure of bangladesh
Market structure of bangladesh
 
Monopolistic Competition Economics Assignment Help
Monopolistic Competition Economics Assignment HelpMonopolistic Competition Economics Assignment Help
Monopolistic Competition Economics Assignment Help
 
Price elasticity is a crucial concept in economics
Price elasticity is a crucial concept in economicsPrice elasticity is a crucial concept in economics
Price elasticity is a crucial concept in economics
 
Basic Economics.pdf
Basic Economics.pdfBasic Economics.pdf
Basic Economics.pdf
 
Basic Economics.pdf
Basic Economics.pdfBasic Economics.pdf
Basic Economics.pdf
 
Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3
Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3
Creative clash mapping_2013_grzelec_prata3
 
Criteria for Investing In the Market of Visual Arts
Criteria for Investing In the Market of Visual ArtsCriteria for Investing In the Market of Visual Arts
Criteria for Investing In the Market of Visual Arts
 

Mehr von Asliza Hamzah

My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...
My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...
My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...Asliza Hamzah
 
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...Asliza Hamzah
 
Traditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in MalaysiaTraditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in MalaysiaAsliza Hamzah
 
Traditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in MalaysiaTraditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in MalaysiaAsliza Hamzah
 
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerInteractive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerAsliza Hamzah
 
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerInteractive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerAsliza Hamzah
 
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerInteractive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerAsliza Hamzah
 
Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...
Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...
Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...Asliza Hamzah
 
Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...
Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...
Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...Asliza Hamzah
 
Effectiveness of multimedia elements
Effectiveness of multimedia elementsEffectiveness of multimedia elements
Effectiveness of multimedia elementsAsliza Hamzah
 
Graphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layout
Graphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layoutGraphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layout
Graphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layoutAsliza Hamzah
 
Connected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphics
Connected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphicsConnected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphics
Connected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphicsAsliza Hamzah
 
Visual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challenges
Visual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challengesVisual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challenges
Visual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challengesAsliza Hamzah
 
Developments in measuring the “creative” workforce
Developments in measuring the “creative” workforceDevelopments in measuring the “creative” workforce
Developments in measuring the “creative” workforceAsliza Hamzah
 
Artworks at work: the impacts of workplace art
Artworks at work: the impacts of workplace artArtworks at work: the impacts of workplace art
Artworks at work: the impacts of workplace artAsliza Hamzah
 
VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...
VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...
VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...Asliza Hamzah
 

Mehr von Asliza Hamzah (19)

My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...
My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...
My Research Proposal : The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the...
 
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
The impact of Multimedia technology in influencing the extinction of traditio...
 
Traditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in MalaysiaTraditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in Malaysia
 
Traditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in MalaysiaTraditional Games in Malaysia
Traditional Games in Malaysia
 
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerInteractive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
 
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerInteractive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
 
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumerInteractive media usage among millennial consumer
Interactive media usage among millennial consumer
 
Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...
Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...
Generation Y, learner autonomy and the potential of Web 2.0 tools for languag...
 
Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...
Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...
Digital technologies and traditional Cultural Expressions: A Positive Look at...
 
Effectiveness of multimedia elements
Effectiveness of multimedia elementsEffectiveness of multimedia elements
Effectiveness of multimedia elements
 
Data communication
Data communicationData communication
Data communication
 
The i mpact of
The i mpact ofThe i mpact of
The i mpact of
 
Graphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layout
Graphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layoutGraphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layout
Graphic literacies for a digital age the survival of layout
 
Connected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphics
Connected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphicsConnected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphics
Connected charts explicit visualization of relationship between data graphics
 
Visual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challenges
Visual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challengesVisual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challenges
Visual analysis of large graphs state of the art and future research challenges
 
Developments in measuring the “creative” workforce
Developments in measuring the “creative” workforceDevelopments in measuring the “creative” workforce
Developments in measuring the “creative” workforce
 
Artworks at work: the impacts of workplace art
Artworks at work: the impacts of workplace artArtworks at work: the impacts of workplace art
Artworks at work: the impacts of workplace art
 
VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...
VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...
VISUAL ARTISTS RIGHTS ACT (“VARA”) AND THE PROTECTION OF DIGITAL WORKS OF “PH...
 
Art and Money
Art and Money Art and Money
Art and Money
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen

Uncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 Reports
Uncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 ReportsUncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 Reports
Uncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 ReportsVWO
 
Unraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptx
Unraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptxUnraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptx
Unraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptxelizabethella096
 
Google 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best Strategies
Google 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best StrategiesGoogle 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best Strategies
Google 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best StrategiesSearch Engine Journal
 
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceEnjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceDelhi Call girls
 
Kraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentation
Kraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentationKraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentation
Kraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentationtbatkhuu1
 
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service Online
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service OnlineCALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service Online
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service Onlineanilsa9823
 
April 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting Group
April 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting GroupApril 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting Group
April 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting GroupVbout.com
 
Labour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptx
Labour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptxLabour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptx
Labour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptxelizabethella096
 
What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?
What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?
What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?riteshhsociall
 
Branding strategies of new company .pptx
Branding strategies of new company .pptxBranding strategies of new company .pptx
Branding strategies of new company .pptxVikasTiwari846641
 
Brand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdf
Brand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdfBrand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdf
Brand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdftbatkhuu1
 
Cost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surges
Cost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surgesCost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surges
Cost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surgesPushON Ltd
 
Social Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdf
Social Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdfSocial Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdf
Social Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdfSocial Samosa
 
How to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail Success
How to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail SuccessHow to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail Success
How to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail SuccessAggregage
 
Social Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid media
Social Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid mediaSocial Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid media
Social Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid mediaadityabelde2
 
Situation Analysis | Management Company.
Situation Analysis | Management Company.Situation Analysis | Management Company.
Situation Analysis | Management Company.DanielaQuiroz63
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen (20)

Uncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 Reports
Uncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 ReportsUncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 Reports
Uncover Insightful User Journey Secrets Using GA4 Reports
 
Turn Digital Reputation Threats into Offense Tactics - Daniel Lemin
Turn Digital Reputation Threats into Offense Tactics - Daniel LeminTurn Digital Reputation Threats into Offense Tactics - Daniel Lemin
Turn Digital Reputation Threats into Offense Tactics - Daniel Lemin
 
Unraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptx
Unraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptxUnraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptx
Unraveling the Mystery of The Circleville Letters.pptx
 
Digital Strategy Master Class - Andrew Rupert
Digital Strategy Master Class - Andrew RupertDigital Strategy Master Class - Andrew Rupert
Digital Strategy Master Class - Andrew Rupert
 
Google 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best Strategies
Google 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best StrategiesGoogle 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best Strategies
Google 3rd-Party Cookie Deprecation [Update] + 5 Best Strategies
 
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort ServiceEnjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
Enjoy Night⚡Call Girls Dlf City Phase 4 Gurgaon >༒8448380779 Escort Service
 
Kraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentation
Kraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentationKraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentation
Kraft Mac and Cheese campaign presentation
 
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service Online
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service OnlineCALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service Online
CALL ON ➥8923113531 🔝Call Girls Hazratganj Lucknow best sexual service Online
 
April 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting Group
April 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting GroupApril 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting Group
April 2024 - VBOUT Partners Meeting Group
 
Labour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptx
Labour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptxLabour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptx
Labour Day Celebrating Workers and Their Contributions.pptx
 
What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?
What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?
What is Google Search Console and What is it provide?
 
Branding strategies of new company .pptx
Branding strategies of new company .pptxBranding strategies of new company .pptx
Branding strategies of new company .pptx
 
Brand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdf
Brand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdfBrand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdf
Brand experience Dream Center Peoria Presentation.pdf
 
Cost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surges
Cost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surgesCost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surges
Cost-effective tactics for navigating CPC surges
 
The Future of Brands on LinkedIn - Alison Kaltman
The Future of Brands on LinkedIn - Alison KaltmanThe Future of Brands on LinkedIn - Alison Kaltman
The Future of Brands on LinkedIn - Alison Kaltman
 
Social Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdf
Social Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdfSocial Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdf
Social Samosa Guidebook for SAMMIES 2024.pdf
 
Top 5 Breakthrough AI Innovations Elevating Content Creation and Personalizat...
Top 5 Breakthrough AI Innovations Elevating Content Creation and Personalizat...Top 5 Breakthrough AI Innovations Elevating Content Creation and Personalizat...
Top 5 Breakthrough AI Innovations Elevating Content Creation and Personalizat...
 
How to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail Success
How to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail SuccessHow to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail Success
How to Leverage Behavioral Science Insights for Direct Mail Success
 
Social Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid media
Social Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid mediaSocial Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid media
Social Media Marketing PPT-Includes Paid media
 
Situation Analysis | Management Company.
Situation Analysis | Management Company.Situation Analysis | Management Company.
Situation Analysis | Management Company.
 

ARTIST AND ART DEALER AS A MARKETING CHANNEL

  • 1. Artist and art dealer as a marketing channel* ROBERTO CELLINI and TIZIANA CUCCIA University of Catania, Faculty of Economics Corso Italia, 55 – 95129 Catania (Italy) tel. +39-0957537728, fax +39-0957537710 e-mail: cellini@unict.it, cucciati@unict.it Abstract: We study the relationship between artist and art dealer, interpreting them as the members of a marketing channel, as defined by the industrial organization and marketing science literature. The results for both parties depend on the individual efforts of each of them. Uncoordinated efforts lead to inefficient outcome. The efficiency of different institutional settings and agreements are studied. Different ways to reach efficient outcome are suggested and discussed, with specific reference to the case of visual arts. Keywords: Marketing channel, effort, mechanism design. JEL Codes: Z-10, L-83, L-13. RUNNING TITLE: Artist and art dealer as a marketing channel CORRESPONDING AUTHOR: Roberto Cellini University of Catania, Dept. of Economics and Business Corso Italia 55 – 95129 Catania – Italy; e-mail cellini@unict.it * We are indebt to Guido Candela, Isidoro Mazza, and Antonello E. Scorcu for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. 1 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2016860
  • 2. Artist and art dealer as a marketing channel In economics and marketing science literature, marketing channel denotes the set of actors, practices and activities, to transfer goods from the point of production to the point of consumption. In the simplest case, a particular product is made by a manufacturer, and delivered to a retailer who sells it in the final market. Manufacturer and retailer are the two members of the marketing channel. If they act uncoordinatedly, channel inefficiencies arise, in the sense that the outcomes of the channel members are lower than they could be under coordination. This inefficiency is due to strategic behaviour in the presence of interdependence between manufacturer and retailer. Available literature suggests different ways to overcome inefficiency, using tools of industrial organization and marketing practice. Here, we shall study the relations between artist and art dealer, interpreting them as the members of a marketing channel. Figurative artist and art gallery manager are our main reference example. Singer (or performing art company like theatre company or orchestra) and event organizer may represent different specific examples of marketing channel in artistic fields. All these cases in arts share some features with the case of a manufacturer and a retailer of industrial production: the success of artistic production depends on the artistic effort of the “creator” (the manufacturer), as well as on the promotion effort made by the art gallery manager or by the live event organizer (the retailer, or the dealer) –in perfect symmetry with the success of industrial production whose revenues depend on manufacturer’s and retailer’s course of actions. Usually, the behaviours of each member of a marketing channel affect the final sales, and hence the outcome for manufacturer and retailer. Industrial organization and marketing studies and practice analyse the outcome of different institutional arrangements between the channel members, and make suggestions of specific arrangements, to improve the results of the channel. In the real world, a variety of cases can be observed: marketing channel members can take their decisions simultaneously or sequentially, with different roles of leader and follower. Either of the channel members may take the role of leader (that is, the first-mover) and may set incentive schemes to 2 1. Introduction Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2016860
  • 3. lead the follower to specific actions. Under particular cases, peculiar objective function can be the true goal of the channel members, and sometimes altruistic behaviours are observed: a channel member may aim at the maximum joint-result rather than at the maximum individual profit. At the same time, the artistic production presents peculiarities with respect to industrial production. For instance, the production of arts provides the artist with utility per se, and artist enjoys welfare from her own fame, apart from the economic results. Even art dealers’ behaviours are sometimes characterized by art for art’s sake. Furthermore, competition takes place in arts’ market under peculiar forms, and the role of price competition or quantity competition needs to be specifically qualified as compared to “standard industrial goods”. More importantly, peculiar arrangements are observed between producer and retailer, in artistic fields: perhaps the most prominent one is that sales sharing is the rule, rather than profit sharing, as documented by a large body of evidence (see, e.g., Caves, 2000, specifically p. 41, or Velthius, 2011a,b). Again, mechanism designs typical for industrial goods, like quantity discounting schemes, are clearly inappropriate (if not impossible) in the case of arts. Our goal is to provide a formal model, consistent with peculiarities of arts, but inspired from industrial organization and marketing science literature, to show that the marketing channel inefficiency is a feature also in the case of the arts, and –more interestingly– to study the efficiency property of different arrangements, commonly observed in the real world of arts. Finally, we aim to suggest mechanisms to overcome the marketing channel inefficiency. We believe that the consideration of different approaches, developed by industrial organization and marketing science, applied to the study of the relation between artist and art dealer, may be fruitful, under both a perspective of description of observed actions, and a normative point of view. 2. Insights from different research lines In this paper, we bring together two research lines. On the one side, we consider the marketing channel literature, developed by both marketing and economic literature. Jeuland and Shugan (1982) can be considered the seminal model, even if several 3
  • 4. previous contributions could be listed, containing similar ideas (e.g., Bucklin, 1966). The models within this research line consider the relation between a manufacturer of a specific brand, and a retailer. In the simplest version, only one manufacturer interacts with one retailer. A market demand function is assumed, depending on retail price, set by the retailer, and other characteristics of the good related to choices (and efforts) made by the manufacturer. Advertising can play some role. Thus, the choices of both manufacturer and retailer affect the outcome of both. Early models focus on pricing problems (Jeuland and Shugan, 1982, Moorthy, 1987). Subsequent contributions underline that non-price aspects are equally important (e.g., Bergen and John, 1997). In the absence of coordination, inefficiency arises, due to opportunistic behaviours. Coordination hardly may emerge endogenously, because the best reply of each channel member to the cooperative choice of the counterpart is not the cooperative choice: a typical prisoner dilemma occurs. It is true that, in the presence of repeated transactions, cooperation could emerge tacitly, along the lines of the Folk-Theorem story, but the real world documents that explicit contracts are often signed, introducing explicit mechanisms that clearly aim to mitigate inefficiency. A number of mechanisms can be observed, and studied under a theoretical point of view: we may mention a variety of pricing schemes, including quantity discounts, quantity surcharges, two-part tariffs; specific rules of profit sharing among the channel members; advertising allowances, or subsidies to promotion costs. Jorgensen and Zaccour (1999, 2002) deal with the dynamic optimal problem of a marketing channel, and present some models taking a differential game perspective. Dynamic mechanism designs are proposed, based on incentive schemes regarding price setting or advertising efforts (see also Jorgensen, Sigue and Zaccour, 2000, 2001; Jorgensen, Taboubi and Zaccour, 2006). It is worth mentioning that the marketing channel can be also interpreted as a particular case of team production (à la Alchian and Demsetz, 1972), in which there is no firm owner, but the team members share the joint result deriving from their personal skills and efforts: Levin and Tadelis (2005) and Kaya and Vereshchagina (2009) study how the properties of the productive process determine the optimal contract design, and the optimal sorting patterns among many agents. The conclusions of these lines of research can be summarised, by stating that a number of price- and non-price mechanisms are available 4
  • 5. to channel members, to overcome inefficient outcomes due to opportunistic behaviours, both in static and in dynamic framework. On the other hand, cultural economics shows that artistic production shares a lot of aspects with standard industrial production, but presents at the same time important peculiarities, so that the results developed by industrial economics can be extended to cultural sectors with caution. Production and distribution channels are clearly present in many artistic sectors: artists, managers, representative agents, gatekeepers and retailers play important roles: Caves (2000), Sacco (1998), Throsbe (1994a), just to mention a few, have studied the relations among the subjects in production and distribution channel of artistic productions; Velthuis (2011a) reviews the specific literature on art dealers. Here, it is particularly important what Caves (2000, Ch. 2) or Velthius (2011b) report: they describe the main aspects of the relationship between artists and dealers, with particular reference to the visual arts sector.1 Common features of observed contracts or arrangements in arts’ marketing channels are: - Artist and dealer typically make informal agreements concerning their “efforts”; formal contracts are generally avoided (even if formal contract are more and more frequent in recent times); - Artist’s effort can hardly be defined, but number and type of works proposed are objects of the agreements, and can be interpreted as proxy variables for artistic effort; dealer’s efforts mean advertising and information campaigns, organisation of meetings or events, and other possible forms of promotion of artistic production; - In agreements or contracts between artist and dealer, the rule is the gross revenue 5 sharing, rather than the profit sharing; - Sometimes artists are called to participate to the financial efforts for promotion campaign; - Fixed payments from dealer to artist are rarely observed (such cases were more frequent in past times and for well-known artists). All these points will be ingredients of the model we are going to present. As far as we know, a formal model borrowing from the marketing channel literature has not jet proposed, with specific reference to the arts, and we aim at filling this gap.
  • 6. It is worth noticing that the focus on the channel of creation and distribution of artistic goods leads us to disregard the secondary or resale markets of arts, and the dynamics of price in such market segments. Hutter et al. (2007) or Shonfeld and Reinstaller (2007), among many others, stress that the determinants of prices in secondary markets are different, as compared to primary markets. However, the research line on the evolution of prices in secondary markets is immaterial to our present study, even if -admittedly- expected future prices of artistic goods are relevant on current demand, so that a cautionary note has to be posed, as long as there is no role for expectations on future prices, in our present model. 6 3. The basics of the model We present a model, where an artist produces a good, that is sold to final consumers by an art dealer. The artist (A) chooses her artistic effort a; her fame, g, is a positive function of the artistic effort, and some exogenous variable, z0, according to the simple linear function , 0. 0 g = z +αa α > Artistic efforts entail a cost for the artist, assumed to be quadratic: = 2 , > 0. A A A c u a u The retailer (P), that is, the art dealer in this specific case (let us think of an art gallery manager, for instance), makes a promotional effort, p, to promote the sales of the artistic production manufactured by A. Promotion efforts entail a quadratic cost for the retailer, = 2 , > 0. P P p c u p u The final sales (S) of the artistic production depend on the retailer’s efforts, and the artist’s fame, according to a function like S =θ + β ⋅ p ⋅ g , withθ ≥ 0, β > 0 . (This formulation is clearly inspired by Jorgensen, Tabouti and, Zaccour, 2006). We assume that the fraction π (with 0 ≤π ≤ 1) of the revenues from the sales goes to the artist, and the fraction (1−π ) goes to the dealer. Clearly, the larger is π , the larger the share of sales accruing to the artist. At the moment, π is an exogenous parameter; in the real world, π is a contracted variable, depending on the relative fame of artist and dealer. Note also that the hypothesis that sale-share are contracted, rather than profit-share is
  • 7. typical to the arts sector (see Caves, 2000). We finally assume that the art dealer cares only on his net result, R (1 )S u p2 P P = −π − , while the artist cares also on his fame, and her net result is: R S u a g A A =π − 2 +δ ; the positive parameter δ describes the importance that her own fame plays into the net result perceived by artist: the presence of such a term in the utility function of artist is common in cultural economics models, consistent with the fact that artists care not only on the monetary outcome of their activity, but also on non-monetary, intangible recognition, like fame (Frey, 1997; see also Throsby, 1994a, 1994b and, more recent, the formal model of Cuccia and Cellini, 2009). Without loss of generality, and for the sake of simplicity, we will develop the model under the following parameter assumptions: = 0, = = 1/ 2, = = 1/ 2 A P θ α β u u , so that the model can be summarised by the following equations: 2 a R gp g a p z a A −  1 1 2 =π ⋅ +δ − =  π ⋅ +δ  R g p p 2 1 p z 1 a − p P 2 7 1 [1] g z a 2 0 = + 1 [2] S = ⋅ g ⋅ p 2 [3] 1 2 2 2 2 2   +  0   (1 ) 1 [4] ( ) 2 2 1 2 2 2 0  = −π ⋅ ⋅ − = −π  + Artist aims at maximising [3], setting her choice variable a, while the art dealer aims at maximising [4], setting his choice variable p. However, the result of each player (i.e., marketing channel member) depends also on the choice of the other player, so that a strategic interdependence situation is operative. The specific choices of players will depend on the “institutional framework” at work. For instance, we could imagine that the choices will be set simultaneously and independently by artist and dealer, or we could imagine that the choices are independent but sequential, with the possibility that the first-mover is the artist or the dealer. Again, we could imagine that artist and dealer agree on their choices, aiming at the joint result maximization. All these different settings will be analysed in what follows. From the point of view of the realism of
  • 8. different settings, we note that it would be too easy (and hence false) to say that in the real world, firstly the artist sets her efforts, and then the dealer sets his promotion efforts: this situation clearly may happen, and perhaps it is the rule in most cases, but it is far from true that this arrangement covers all cases: in some cases –for instance, in the performing art shows– advertising campaign for a show starts before (or during) the show is under construction. The different institutional settings provide different ordering of individual and aggregate results for the channel members. 8 4. Results 4.1. The simultaneous game Let us imagine that artist and dealer set their decision simultaneously. We denote this setting as the “Cournot setting”, borrowing the label from the oligopoly theory. The artist maximizes objective function [3], with respect to a, and derives the following optimal rule, which represents her reaction function: [5] + ⋅ a 2 p 4 = δ π The dealer maximizes function [4], with respect to p, and derives the following reaction function: [6] 2(1 ) (1 ) 0 z a 4 p − + − ⋅ = π π The optimal effort of the artist depends positively on the promotional effort of the dealer, and the promotional effort of the dealer is a positive function of the artistic effort of the artist: the reaction functions are positively sloped, so that the choice variables are strategic complements, in the terminology of oligopoly theory. The Nash equilibrium is:
  • 9. δ z π π a COU 2[ 4 + (1 − )] δ z π π δ z π π R COU A 2[4 + (1 − )][4 + ( − + 32] 9 [7] 16 2 0 − + = π π [8] z δ π 2(4 )(1 ) 16 0 − + 2 + − = π π pCOU where the superscript COU stays for “Cournot”, i.e., simultaneous choice setting; note that both variables in equilibrium are positive, and increasing in δ and z0; correspondingly, the maximum outcomes reached by artist and dealer, in equilibrium, are respectively: [9] 2 2 2 0 0 ( − + 16) = π π π z δ R COU P 2(1 − ) (4 + ) [10] 2 2 2 0 2 ( − + 16) = π π The result obtained by the dealer is strictly decreasing inπ (the higher the revenue share for the artist, the lower the equilibrium result for the dealer), while the result obtained by the artist is increasing in π for 0<π <½ , reaches its maximum in π =½ and is then decreasing over ½<π <1: for high levels of π , further increases of this share parameter lead the dealer to lower his effort to such an extent, that the artist’s result decreases. 4.2. The sequential games We firstly consider the case in which the dealer sets his promotional effort after having observed the artistic effort chosen by the artist: in this case we are in a sequential game, à la Stackelberg, where the artist is the first-mover (or leader) and the dealer is the second-mover (follower). The leader can anticipate the choice of the follower, and can insert such a reaction function into her objective function: this amounts to saying that the artist-leader maximizes her objective function [3], considering the constraint represented by the reaction function of the dealer-follower [6]. The solution of the leader’s problem provides:
  • 10. z π − π + δz + δ 10 [11] δ z π π 2[2 + (1 − )] 8 2 0 − + = π π aSTAL . (where the superscript STAL stays for “Stackelberg, with artist leading”), and the choice of the dealer-follower is: [12] π z δ (1 − )(4 + ) 8 2 0 − + = π π pSTAL The efforts exerted by both the artist and the dealer are larger than the respective efforts in the simultaneous choice case. Thus, it is not surprising that the individual results obtained in equilibrium by both parties are larger in this Stackelberg case, as compared to the Cournot equilibrium. Equilibrium results, when the artist is the first-mover, are: [13] 8 2 (1 ) 8 2 2 0 2 0 − + = π π R STAL A π z δ R STAL P (1 − ) (4 + ) [14] 2 2 2 0 2 2( − + 8) = π π The opposite case of sequential moving, in which the dealer is the first-mover, and the artist follows, is conceivable as well. In some cases, the promotion campaigns for shows or specific events start before the preparation of the show is finished, so that it is true that the artistic effort is set after the promotion effort is made. In such a case, the dealer is the leader, and he can anticipate the choice of the artist-follower. Analytically, the dealer-leader maximizes his objective function [4] under the constraint represented by the reaction function of the artist [5]. The optimal choice of the dealer turns out to be: [15] π z δ (1 − )(4 + ) 8 2 0 − + = π π pSTAF
  • 11. where superscript STAF stays for “Stackelberg with artist following”, and the reaction of the artist, in equilibrium is δ π π z π π aSTAF ( − + 16) + 4 (1 − ) 0 z π π δ π π δ π π z π π R STAF A [4 (3 − 3 + 32) + ( − + 16)][ ( − + 16) + 4 (1 − )] 11 [16] 2 4( 8) 2 − + = π π The artist is led to make an effort, as second-mover, larger than the effort set as a first-mover. As far as the art dealer is concerned, his effort, as the leader of the Stackelberg game, is equal to the effort made as the follower of the Stackelberg game. By straight substitutions into the objective functions, we obtain the results of both parts in equilibrium, when the dealer leads and the artist follows: [17] 2 32( 8) 0 2 2 2 0 − + = π π π z δ R STAF P (1 − ) (4 + ) [18] 2 2 2 0 2 16( − + 8) = π π By simple comparisons, we can state that, for any π (with 0 <π < 1, that is excluding the limit cases),2 the following relations hold: ; ; ; ; COU STAL STAF a < a < a COU STAL STAF STAl P p < p = p R < R < R STAF P COU P STAF A STAL A COU A R < R < R This means that each player prefers any sequential settings to the simultaneous choice setting, and –in the sequential settings– each of the players prefers to be the follower rather than the leader. This ordering of individual outcomes is consistent with analogous results obtained in games in which choice variables are strategic complements.
  • 12. 4.3. The cooperative setting (joint result) If channel members aim at the maximum joint result, they face the following problem: [ 2 2 ] Max R R R 1 z a p a p A P (2 )(2 ) 2 2 4 , 0 12 JOINT a p = + = + δ + − − We could label this setting as the coordinated setting (or the cartel setting, borrowing from oligopoly theory). From the first order conditions we obtain: [19] 2(4 ) 0 z p JOINT + 15 = δ [20] 2( 4 ) 0 z a JOINT + 15 = δ Some comments are in order. First, the efforts of each part are the highest, with respect to all considered settings. This means that the maximum joint result requires the highest efforts by both parts. Second, both the Cournot setting and the Stackelberg settings provide the players with individual equilibrium results whose sum is smaller as compared to the sum of results they can obtain in the coordinated setting. In other words, strategic interaction leads to inefficient outcomes; this result is well known by marketing channel literature. Third, parameter π disappears from the problem of the coordinated setting, consistently with the fact that π captures an aspect related to the division of a common result, that is immaterial to the maximum of the common result in itself. Of course, the problem of the division of the common result remains open, after the coordinated choices are set. As far as the division of result is concerned, we assume that the artist obtains the share π of the sales, and the dealer obtains the complement share 1−π , while the term δa goes entirely to the artist; needless to say, this is only one –rather obvious– assumption concerning the division of the “cartel result”. Under the above mentioned rule of sharing, the dealer and the artist obtain the following individual results:
  • 13. [21] 2 [ (32 1) (7 )(16 2 2 )] 2 0 R JOINT = z π − + +π δz + δ A R JOINT = 2 − π z +δ P 13 225 0 [22] 2 0 (1 2 )(4 ) 225 and hence, under the above mentioned rule of sharing, the cartel situation provides the artist a higher result with respect to the Cournot situation for any π >0.1350, and provides the dealer with a higher result as compared to the Cournot situation for any π <0.24085. Similar comparisons can be readily made with respect to the Stackelberg settings. In any case, apart from the cartel situation, any other setting is Pareto-inefficient – in the sense that a different situation can be found, with appropriate sharing of the result, where each player can be better off. As is well-known, the choices associated with the efficient outcome do not represent a Nash equilibrium, at least in the one-shot game. This amounts to saying that informal or non-binding agreements concerning socially efficient levels of individual efforts are not self-enforcing. In Section 5 we study how it is possible to replicate the efficient outcome, on the basis of more-complex self-enforcing agreements. Eventually, we will discuss the degree of efficiency of different types agreements, observed in the real world of arts’ markets. Remember that formal binding contracts (ideally replicating the efficient outcome) are rarely observed in the filed of arts, also because their enforcement is difficult, due to the fact that relevant key variables (like the artistic efforts) are hardly definable and measurable. 5. Replication of efficient outcome The available literature on marketing channel has suggested several contract designs, able to lead the parts to replicate the choices associated to the efficient outcome. In the cases of industrial goods, for instance, specific profit share designs, advertising allowances, quantity discount schemes, are possible solutions: it is a well-established
  • 14. result that a multiplicity of effective solutions exist, to overcome the inefficiency of decentralised decisions in marketing channel situations. In order to make such arrangements self-enforcing, it is necessary to assure that each part obtains a larger result, as compared to the individual result obtained in uncoordinated setting. Here we focus on the case at hand and we limit to propose two different solutions: the first one has a theoretical interest, but it is hardly implementable in the real world; it is appropriate for the context in which choices are set simultaneously. The second one is appropriate when the artist set her artistic efforts firstly, and the dealer follows –a situation more frequently observed in the real world; for this reason we will spend more attention on it. The relevant question can be posed specifically as follows: How is it possible to lead the artist to set her effort at the efficient level given by [20], and the dealer to set his effort at the efficient level [19]? 5.1. Linear subsidies in the simultaneous choice setting Consider the case in which artist and art dealer set their choices simultaneously. Assume that artist has to pay a subsidy ψ to the dealer for each unit of promotional effort he makes; at the same time, the dealer has to pay a subsidy ω to the artist for each unit of artistic effort she makes. The problems of artist and dealer can be written, respectively, as follows 1 2 [23] Max R =  ⋅ p +  z 1 a a p a a A π  δ  +  − − ψ + ω 1  2 14   2 2 2 0 [24] Max R ( )p z a p p a p P 1 1 2 = −  + ω ψ π − + −   2 2 0 From the first order conditions, the following reaction functions can be easily derived: π ⋅ + 2δ + 4ω [25] 4 a = p
  • 15. (1 ) 2 (1 ) 4 0 −π ⋅ + −π + ψ = a z p πψ δ ω π π z 2[2( + 2 + 4 ) + (1 − ) ] z δ π ψ ω π 2[(4 + )(1 − ) + 2(4 + (1 − ))] 15 [26] 4 The corresponding equilibrium efforts are: [27] 16 2 0 − + = π π a [28] 16 2 0 − + = π π p Appropriate levels of ψ and ω can be computed, to render the effort levels [27] and [28] equal to the efficient levels [20] and [19], respectively; the solution is: [29] 2 (4 ) 0 π δ 15 ψ + = z [30] = z (1 )(4 ) 0 π δ 30 ω − + The subsidy levels given by [29] and [30] lead each member of the channel to set the individual choice that replicates the efficient outcome of the maximum joint result. Note that the higher is the share for the artist, the higher the amount of unit subsidy that she has to give to the dealer. By appropriate substitutions, it is possible to compute the individual results obtained by channel members under such arrangement, and to compare them with the result obtained in the uncoordinated Cournot setting. It is immediate to verify that only over a limited range of parameter configuration, each member receives a larger outcome as compared to the uncoordinated setting; outside that range, appropriate transfer are necessary to make the socially efficient arrangement convenient even for each members under a strictly individualistic point of view. It is also interesting to note that: (a) in the limiting case where π = 0 , the efficient levels of unit subsidies become ψ = 0 and (4 ) / 30 0 ω = z +δ : this arrangement describes a situation in which all revenues from sales go to the dealer, but he commits to give the artist a subsidy for her artistic effort; (b) in the limiting case where π = 1, the
  • 16. efficient outcome is reproduced by the subsidy scheme ω = 0 , 2(4 ) /15 0 ψ = z +δ , which means that all revenues from sales go to the artist, but she commits to give the dealer appropriate subsidy for each unit of promotional effort of his. Also in these limiting cases, the efficient solution is reproduced, but appropriate lump-sum transfer is necessary to make the arrangement dominant for each member also from a strictly individualistic point of view. The real implementation of the subsidy design in this simultaneous moving setting, however, should require that artistic efforts are definable and measurable – a hardly tenable assumption. One could also observe that if this mechanism design is implementable in the real world, no reason exists why a formal contract concerning directly the efficient levels of efforts is not implementable. The substantial obstacle to contract enforcement in the case of arts rest on the possibility of defining and measuring artistic efforts. Such obstacles can be avoided in the sequential setting, if artist set her efforts firstly. 5.2. Quadratic subsidy in the Stackelberg setting, with artist leader. Consider the case that the artist sets her artistic effort firstly, and then the art dealer sets the promotional effort; equilibrium levels of efforts in the uncoordinated setting are given by [11] and [12], which represent an inefficient allocation from a marketing channel point of view. Imagine that the artist commits herself to give a subsidy (σ p) to the dealer (with σ ≥ 0 ), for each unit of promotional effort of his, so that the total subsidy from artist to dealer is σ p2 . The net result of artist and dealer, under such an agreement are respectively: R   =  1 π ⋅ p + δ   z + 1 a − a − σ p A [31] 2 2 R 1 p z a p p P σ π + −  16 2 0 2 2 2    1 1 2  = −  + [32] ( ) 2 0 2 2  It is immediate to find the reaction function of the dealer:
  • 17. π z a p 1 2 0 < , 1 for SQS (3 π − 1) / 2(1 + π ) 1/ 3 < π ≤ 1 = 0 0 1/ 3 z for = RSQS z z A 2[ (1 + ) + 32 + 4 ] π δ δ − − 17 [33] ( )( ) 2 − + = σ 4(1 − 2 σ ) This reaction function has to be inserted in the in the leader’s problem, and different cases could be taken into account. Case I (Digression). The artist aims at her own maximum, and sets σ and a accordingly. We denote this case as the case of a selfish artist. It is easy to check that the maximum private result for the artist requires [34]    ≤ π ≤ σ for 2[ (1 ) 16 ]  + + π δ [35] ; 0 1/ 3 1/ 3 1 63 2 2 2 0   ≤ ≤ < ≤ − − = π π π π a for a STAL SQS (superscript SQS stays for “selfish quadratic subsidy”). This means that the artist finds it convenient to give a positive subsidy to the dealer only for sufficiently high levels of π . Clearly, for 0 ≤π ≤ 1/ 3, that is, in the situation of the corner solution corresponding to nil subsidy, optimal choices replicate the simple situation à la Stackelberg (without subsidy) with the artist as the leader, and individual results coincide with [13] and [14]. For 1/ 3 <π ≤ 1, subsidy is positive, and individual results are: [36] 2 2 0 2 2 0 63 2 π π = RSQS z P 16(1 − )(4 + ) π δ − − [37] 2 2 2 0 2 (63 2 π π ) whose sum is smaller than the cartel outcome. It is interesting to note that, for high levels of π , it is in the interest of a selfish artist to provide the dealer with a subsidy for
  • 18. SQS turns out to be larger than RA 2 2 2 0 RCQS = z π − + δz π + +δ π + A , 0 RCQS = −π z +δ π π π z δ R RSTAL (2 + 26 − 12 − 1)(4 + ) CQS A is positive only for 18 the promotional effort: RA STAL for any π included in the range (1/3,1]. Case II. The artist sets σ in order to lead the follower to replicate pJOINT, and sets a=aJOINT. This case can be denoted as the case of a cartel-oriented artist (or benevolent artist, in the sense that he takes care of the whole marketing channel). From the dealer’s reaction function [33], it is immediate to find that p= pJOINT requires: [38] σ =π / 2 with 0<π <1 and hence 0<σ <1/2. Correspondingly, the channel members’ net results are: [39] [ (16 1) 8 ( 14) ( 14)] 225 0 2 [40] [(1 )(4 )] 225 P where superscript CQS stays for “cartel quadratic subsidy”. Of course, the sum of the results given by [39] and [40] coincides with the efficient joint result. However, from an individualist point of view, each channel member is ready to implement this agreement, only if it provides a larger individual result as compared to decentralised decisions. From the dealer’s point of view, result [40] is higher than results [14] or [37], for any 0<π <1. This means (quite obviously) that the dealer prefers the situation in which the artist is cartel-oriented rather than selfish. From the artist’s point of view, we have to distinguish, according to π be larger or smaller than 1/3. (i) If 0 ≤π ≤1/ 3 , the result [39] is higher than result [13] only for levels of π higher than a threshold level. More precisely, 2 225( 8) 2 0 3 2 − + − = π π A
  • 19. ( ) 2 3 26 2 12 1 0 1 f π ≡ π + π − π − > , that is, 0.07 1 π ≥π ≈ . This means that for 1/ 3 1 π ≤π ≤ , it is in the interest of a selfish artist to implement the cartel allocation. The result that a manufacturer, under given parameter conditions, may find it convenient to pursue the maximum of the channel is not a novelty in the marketing channel literature (see, in a different framework, Jorgenson et al., 2006, Section 4). For 1 0 ≤π <π , in order to make the cartel choice convenient for the artist, a further lump-sum transfer from the dealer to the artist must be required. Let τ denote such a transfer from the dealer to the artist. If we compare the outcomes (under the quadratic subsidy and transfer) with the case of nil subsidy, in order to make the arrangement self-enforcing, we have to fix τ in a way such that: STAL τ τ τ < < ( − 2 π − 26 π + 12 π + 1)(4 + δ ) (1 − π )(4 π − 8 π + 68 π + 161 π + 31)(4 + δ ) CQS A R +η > R and SQS P , η η η < < 2( π + 16 π − 35 π + 18)(4 + δ ) 225(63 2 ) 2(1 − π )( π + 4 π − 122 π − 2052 π + 2169)(4 + δ ) 19 R CQS +τ > R STAL and R CQS −τ > R , A A P P which means: [41] 2 2 2 0 4 3 2 1 2 2 2 2 0 3 2 1 450( 8) , 225( 8) ; − + = − + = π π τ π π τ z z (note that 1 τ is positive for any level of 0.07 1 π <π ≈ ). (ii) For π included in the interval [1/3, 1], it can be easily checked that SQS>RA RA CQS, and (RA SQS+RP SQS)<(RA CQS+RP CQS). Thus, a transfer (from the dealer to the artist) has to be designed, to lead the artist (who sets σ and a) to behave in the interest of the channel. Specifically, a lump-sum transfer η > 0 can be found, from dealer to artist, such that SQS A CQS P R −η > R . Simple computations permit to find that the two conditions correspond to [42] 2 2 2 0 4 3 2 1 2 2 2 2 0 3 2 1 225(63 2 ) ; π π η π π η − − = − − = z z
  • 20. One can interpret η as the price that the dealer has to pay to the artist, in order to lead the artist to behave in the interest of the channel, instead of in a selfish way. In words, the story can be told as follows. If the artist is the leader of the marketing channel, an arrangement can be identified, which leads to the efficient outcome, and which is self-enforcing in the sense that it is impossible to find alternative outcomes in which both members are better off (i.e., no room for convenient deviation does exist); the arrangement is as follows: (i) the sales are divided according to the positive fractions π and 1−π , for artist and dealer respectively, with π >1/3; (ii) the artist gives the dealer the subsidy σp2 = (π / 2) p2 , linked to the promotional efforts of his; (iii) the dealer gives the artist the fixed sum 1 2 η <η <η , conditional on the fact that the artist set a=aJOINT. Under such conditions, the artist finds it optimal to set the efficient effort a=aJOINT, and the best reply of the dealer is p=pJOINT. In sum, we have found that for some parameter values ( 1/ 3 1 π ≤π ≤ ), it is in the (individualistic) interest of the artist, to behave in the interest of the cartel; outside such a parameter range, a self-enforcing mechanism is found, able to replicate the efficient outcome. In such a mechanism: (i) sales are shared among artist and art dealer, (ii) the artist receives an additional fixed amount from the dealer; (iii) the artist pays the dealer for his promotional effort. The mechanism is efficient because each member replicates the choice associated with the joint-maximization case, and the mechanism is self-enforcing, because each channel member has no incentive to deviate from the efficient 20 choices. 6. Comments and concluding remarks Here we have pointed out that artists and art dealers constitute a marketing channel, in the sense defined by economics and marketing science literature: in several cases, for industrial goods, a good is manufactured by a firm, and sold to a retailer which sells it in the final market; the result for both subjects –producer and retailer, that is, the channel members– depend on the efforts made by each of them. Like in the more general case of team production, strategic interdependence and incomplete information generate room
  • 21. for inefficient results, if subjects act in a uncoordinated manner, and each actor is oriented to his/her individual maximum result. The situation in the arts’ markets is very similar. Artist and art dealer benefit from results which depend on the efforts of both. We have shown that the theoretical results obtained by industrial organization and marketing science hold, by and large, for the arts markets as well. In the arts markets, however, specific characteristics are worth taking into account. History and the current real world document a variety of agreements between art makers and art dealers, in different arts’ markets (visual arts, performing arts, and so on).3 For instance, employment, direct acquisition and consignments are alternative, possible forms of agreements in the case of visual arts; however, in current day experience, the consignment is the most frequent form of agreement. Caves (2000, especially Chs. 2 and 3) and Velthius (2011a,b), with particular reference to the case of visual arts, provide a list of “typical” behaviors in the to-day relations between artists and art dealers. These characteristics have shaped the specific model we have presented in this paper. First, formal contracts between artists and art dealers (especially in the cases of painter and art gallery) are generally avoided, in real world: informal deals (and moral obligations) are more common forms of agreements. The reasons why formal contracts are rare can be easily understood: complete terms are difficultly stated in a contract; monitoring activities are difficult to be conducted; litigations are expensive and financial compensation from successful litigations nearly impossible to be obtained. Nevertheless, in recent years, a larger use of written contracts is claimed (especially by artists) and observed (Vinick, 1997). The absence of a large body of detailed contracts makes a robust analysis of contracts impossible, and the comment have to focus on episodic or anecdotic evidence. Second, the typical agreement has the form of ‘consignment contract’: the artist consigns her artworks to the dealer (who exhibits them), in order to be sold. The agreement could prescribe number and type of artworks to be delivered. The dealer receive a share of the revenues, as a counterpart of his activity of promotion. Pay in advance and/or regular wage are very uncommon.4 Third, as a matter of fact, the role of the art dealer is more complex than just selling the artistic items: an art dealer acts as an agent (both for the artist, and for 21
  • 22. institutional buyers like museums or private collectors): for this reason, the assumption that the dealer makes efforts to promote the artistic production is meaningful, in the case of the arts, and the promotion actions in the hands of an art dealer are wider and potentially more effective as compared to the typical actions available to a retailer in the case of industrial goods. An art dealer is expected: to provide information to critics, certifiers, art writers, museum curators, and media; to organize exhibitions; to provide items for temporary exhibitions; to compose books and further editorial catalogs; to make (traditional) advertising campaigns in journals and specialized reviews; to spend time with prospective clients articulating the artist’s intent (Caves, 2000, p. 38): all these activities define the dealer’s efforts. Especially in contemporary arts, we can say the efforts of the dealer contribute to the definition of the characteristics of artistic product. Fourth, it is worth stressing, once again, that revenue share, rather than profit share, is the rule. This aspect is of particular importance, since it entails that the channel members are not reimbursed for specific expenses. Documented exceptions are rather limited: in the case of visual arts, for instance, one can seldom observe a participation of artist in expenses of dealer, e.g. for advertising, catalogues and framework. Fifth, it is difficult (if not impossible) that dealer can participate to the artistic effort exerted by the artist. Artist’s effort is hardy observable, and the observable result of her are weakly linked to the effort (whatever “effort” could mean in artistic fields). In observed agreements, efforts are at generally linked to the number of pieces that the artist commits to deliver to the dealer, in a time interval. Sixth, artists typically complain about the limited efforts of dealers, and dealers complain about the limited efforts of artists. In the specialized newspaper Art World News we can read: “An artist fails to deliver quality works in sufficient number. A dealer fails to promote an artists' work. These are only two types of claims that have recently led to disputes between artists and dealers” (Vinick,1997, p. 1). The perceptions of each member of the marketing channel that the other member does not exert a sufficient level of effort are really very common. The fact that these perceptions may be well founded is supported by our present theoretical model. The above mentioned characteristics of typical agreements between artist and dealer lead to a situation in which each part exerts a lower amount of effort as compared to the 22
  • 23. efficient level: this is due to the strategic interdependence. Possible agreements concerning socially-efficient levels of individual efforts are not self-enforcing, as long as each actor has an incentive to free-riding. Thus, in our interpretation, the true root of inefficiency does not rest on asymmetric information (which in any case, does exist, and explains why it is nearly impossible to sign formal binding contracts), nor in agency-type, i.e., principal-agent relationship (which in any case could be appropriate for describing some aspects of the relations), but simply in the team-type production process which is relevant for artistic items, as they are sold in today markets, where marketing channels are really relevant. We have shown that specific designs for contracts would be able to overcome inefficiency. Many efficient contracts are in principle possible. Reciprocal cross-subsidies have been shown to met the efficiency condition, in a situation in which artist and art dealer exert their efforts simultaneously. A further example has been provided, for the case in which artist and art dealer take their decisions sequentially (with the artist leading), and in which artist and art dealer split the revenues from sales: in such a case, the artist may be required to participate to the promotional efforts of dealer (according to a quadratic subsidy), and receives a lump-sum transfer; the amount of the lump-sum transfer has to be linked to the values of the agreed revenue-share, and to the amount of the subsidy to promotional efforts. Interestingly enough, in accordance with available results in marketing channel literature, we have found that –under certain parameter configuration, and specifically under given values of share according to which revenues are split– there is no conflict between individual and collective incentive, in the sense that it can be in the egoistic interest of a member of the channel to act in the interest of the whole channel. As far as we know, this type of contracts are not used in to-day arts’ market, at least in the case of visual arts. Under this perspective, our paper may provide useful suggestions to artists and dealers. 23
  • 24. REFERENCES Alchian A. – Demsetz H. (1972) “Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization”, American Economic Review, vol. 62, pp. 777-95. Alper N.O. – Wassall G.H. (2006), “Artists' Careers and Their Labor Markets”, in V. A. Ginsburgh – D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 813-64. Bergen M. – John G (1997), “Understanding cooperative advertising participation rates in conventional channels”, Journal of Marketing Research, vol. 34, pp. 357-69. Caves R. E. (2000), Creative Industries. Contracts between Art and Commerce, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Ma, Us. Cuccia T. – Cellini R. (2009), “Workers’ Enterprises and The Taste for Production: The Arts, Sport and Other Cases”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 56, pp. 123-37. De Marchi N. – Van Miegroet H.J. (2006), “The History of Art Markets”, in V. A. Ginsburgh – D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 69-122. Frey B. S. (1997), Not Just for the Money, Edward Edgar, Cheltenham. Hutter M. – Knebel C. – Pietzner G. – Schafer M. (2007), “Two Games in Town: A Comparison of Dealer and Auction Prices in Contemporary Visual Arts Markets”, Journal of Cultural Economics, vol. 31, pp. 247-61. Jeuland A. P – Shugan S. M. (1983), “Managing Channel Profits”, Marketing Science, vol. 2, pp. 239-72. Jorgensen S. – Zaccour G., (2003), “Channel Coordination over Time: Incentive Equilibria and Credibility” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 27, pp. 801-27. Kaya A. – Vereshchagina G. (2009), “Moral Hazard and Sorting in a Market for Partnership”, Mimeo, Arizona State University. Levine J. – Tadelis S. (2005), “Profit Sharing and the Role of Professional Partenership”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 120, pp. 131-71. Menger P.M. (2006), “Artistic Labor Markets”, in , in V. A. Ginsburgh – D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 765-811. Moorthy K. S. (1987), “Managing Channel Profits: Comment”, Marketing Science, vol. 6, pp. 375-79. Sacco P. (1998), “La selezione dei giovani artisti nei mercati delle arti visive”, in: W Santagata (Ed.), Economia dell’Arte, UTET, Torino. Schonfeld S. – Reinstaller A. (2007), “The Effects of Gallery and Artist Reputation on Prices in the Primary Market for Art: A Note”, Journal of Cultural Economics, vol. 31, pp. 143-53. Tamperi T. (2006), La vendita di opere d’arte fra tutela e mercato, Clueb, Bologna. 24
  • 25. Throsby D. (1994a), "The Production and Consumption of the Arts: A View of Cultural Economics", Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1-29. Throsby D. (1994b), "A Work-Preference Model of Artist Behaviour", in A. Peacock - I. Rizzo (eds.), Cultural Economics and Cultural Policies, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, pp. 69-80. Velthuis O. (2011a), “Art dealers” in Towse R. (ed.), A Handbook of Cultural Economics, Second Edition, Edward Elgar Cheltenham. Velthuis O. (2011b), “Visual Arts” in Towse R. (ed.), A Handbook of Cultural Economics, Second Edition, Edward Elgar Cheltenham. Vinick P. A. (1997) “Art Dealers Need Written Contracts Specifying All Aspects of Dealer- Artist Agreements”, ArtWorldNews, February (also downloadable from the website http://www.fphlcc.ca/downloads/art dealers-need-written-contracts.pdf, Dec. 2011). 25
  • 26. 26 NOTES 1 Caves (2000), in a different chapter, considers also the cases of writers (editorial industry) and singers (disco industry), which we overlook in the present paper. 2 Relations in the limiting cases are trivial. For π = 0 , aCOU = aSTAL = aSTAF = δ / 2 , and (4 ) / 8 0 pCOU = pSTAL = pSTAF = z +δ , so that the individual results coincide across the different settings; for π =1, aCOU = aSTAL = aSTAF = δ / 2 , and pCOU = pSTAL = pSTAF = 0 , so that also in this case individual results are the same across the considered regimes. 3 A short history of the relations between artists and dealers can be found in De Marchi and Van Miegroet (2006, Section 4). The variety of employment status and careers of artists are dealt with by, e.g., Menger (2006) and Alper and Wassall (2006). 4 Velthius (2011b), lists three main possible forms of agreements between artist and art dealers, in the case of visual arts: (1) employment with stipend, (2) direct acquisition, and (3) consignment. However, employment is not common today (exceptions are the low-tail of the market where artists copy standardized artworks for mass markets); famous cases of employment with fixed wage concern artists in past times: for instance, art dealer D. H. Kahnweiler paid (young) Picasso on a regular stipend, believing him as potential well-gifted artist; similar contracts were used by dealers Russo for Giorgio De Chirico (at the beginning of XX century) and by L. Castelli for promising young pop-artists in New York around 1960. Under such an agreement (also known as contrat-mecenat –see Tamperi, 2006), the artist commits to deliver a certain number of pieces in a given period of time, and receives a fixed salary, e.g., on monthly base; the art dealer usually keeps all the revenues from artworks’ sale. Alternatively, under direct acquisition contract, the dealer buys artworks from the artist and then decides when and at what price to sell them; such a system (also refereed as ‘the French system’, since it was common in the late XIX century in France) requires large (capital and financial) resources from the dealers, since they have to buy the artworks, and implies that the dealer runs the risk that the economic value will be never realized; it is rare in the today world. The largest part of today agreements base on consignment: the artist consigns her pieces to the dealer (who exhibit them); if and when a piece is sold, artist and dealer split the revenues, on a previously agreed terms. We have thought of this kind of agreement, in building the present model.