SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 75
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
A Good Worker is Hard to
 Find: Skills Shortages in
      New Zealand Firms
  Penny Mok, Geoff Mason, Philip Stevens
                     and Jason Timmins




             Ministry of Economic Development
                         Occasional Paper 12/05



                                     April 2012


                ISBN: 978-0-478-38237-2 (PDF)
              ISBN: 978-0-478-38236-5 (online)
Ministry of Economic Development Occasional Paper 12/05

A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms



Date: April 2012



Author: Penny Mok        Treasury

        Geoff Mason      National Institute of Economic and Social Research, London

        Philip Stevens Ministry of Economic Development

        Jason Timmins Department of Labour



Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Belinda Buxton, Rosie Byford, Elizabeth Chisholm,
Hilary Devine, Sid Durbin, Richard Fabling, Bette Flagler, Julia Gretton, Hamish Hill,
Bill Kaye-Blake, Peter Nunns, Meighan Ragg, Lynda Sanderson, Steven Stillman,
Richard White and participants in the Industry Training Federation, the Labour,
Employment and Work, the New Zealand Association of Economists, and the New
Zealand Centre for SME Research conferences (and others whom we have
neglected to mention).     We acknowledge two lots of funding from the Cross-
Departmental Research Funding for the production of IBULDD (and thence the LBD)
and for the Impact of Skills on New Zealand Firms project.



Contact: Occasionalpapers@med.govt.nz



Disclaimer

The views, opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this
Occasional Paper are strictly those of the author(s). They do not necessarily reflect
the views of the Ministry of Economic Development or the Department of Labour,
Treasury or the National Institute of Economics and Social Research. The Ministry
takes no responsibility for any errors or omissions in, or for the correctness of, the
information contained in these occasional papers. The paper is presented not as
policy, but with a view to inform and stimulate wider debate.

Access to the data used in this paper was provided by Statistics NZ in accordance
with security and confidentiality provisions of the Statistics Act 1975. Only people
authorised by the Statistics Act 1975 are allowed to see data about a particular,
business or organisation. The results in this paper have been confidentialised to
protect individual businesses from identification.

The results are based in part on tax data supplied by Inland Revenue to Statistics NZ
under the Tax Administration Act 1994. This tax data must be used only for statistical
purposes, and no individual information is published or disclosed in any other form,
or provided back to Inland Revenue for administrative or regulatory purposes. Any
person who had access to the unit-record data has certified that they have been
shown, have read and have understood section 81 of the Tax Administration Act
1994, which relates to privacy and confidentiality. Any discussion of data limitations
or weaknesses is not related to the data's ability to support Inland Revenue's core
operational requirements.
Abstract
This paper examines the determinants of firms’ skill shortages, using a specially-
designed survey, the Business Strategy and Skills (BSS) module of the Business
Operations Survey. We combine the BSS module with additional data on firms in the
Statistics New Zealand’s prototype Longitudinal Business Database (LBD).            We
focus on vacancies that were hard-to-fill because the applicants lacked the
necessary skills, qualification or experience - which we define as skill-related reasons
(skill shortage vacancies). We also contrast these with vacancies that were hard-to-
fill for non-skill-related reasons.

JEL Classification:      J24, J31, L60

Keywords:       skill shortages, hard-to-fill vacancies, Business Operations Survey,
                Heckman Selection model




                                                                                    i
Executive Summary
Skills are an important determinant of the economic performance of people, firms,
industries and economies. Shortages of skilled labour directly constrain production
and prevent firms from meeting demand and using available inputs efficiently. They
inhibit innovation and the use of new technologies.            This may have longer-term
impacts on the way firms do business, in terms of their location, size, structure,
production methods and product strategy.

In this paper we have examined factors relating to firms’ skill shortages. Our focus
has been on vacancies that were hard-to-fill because the applicants lacked the
necessary skills, qualification or experience – what we have defined as ‘skill shortage
vacancies’ (SSVs). We have also contrasted these with vacancies that were hard-to-
fill for reasons other than the skills of applicants.

Worker turnover is a basic fact of economic life. In any given year one in eight
workers leaves their employer. Searching for new staff is, therefore, a position most
businesses find themselves in, regardless of their situation.                Almost half of
businesses find some of these vacancies hard-to-fill and more than a third
experience difficulties in finding workers with the required skills, qualifications or
experience they need.

We have examined patterns of skill shortage vacancies using an econometric
technique that allows us to account, in part, for the interrelationship between the
likelihood of a firm posting a vacancy and for those vacancies being hard-to-fill for
skill-related reasons.

Large firms are more likely to have vacancies – they have more workers and so the
chance of at least one of them leaving is consequently higher. However, larger firms
do not appear to find it more difficult to source workers with the required skills than
smaller firms, once we account for other characteristics. As we might expect, when
firms’ output grows, the need to seek additional staff also grows. However, this is
only in the years the firm is expanding. Expanding sales is not a good predictor of
future additional staff requirements.

Businesses can experience skill shortages internally or externally. A shortage in the
skills it requires can manifest itself: (a) in terms of the ability of its existing staff to do



                                                                                          ii
their job; or (b) in terms of its ability to find appropriately skilled workers through
recruitment.    We have found evidence that these two phenomena co-exist.
Businesses experiencing internal skill gaps are also more-likely to have skill shortage
vacancies. We also find evidence of persistence in this relationship; businesses
experiencing internal skill gaps are also more likely to have SSVs in the following
year.

Businesses have a ‘make or buy’ option when it comes to skills. If they cannot
source the skills internally or externally, they can up-skill existing or new workers
through training. Firms’ training choices are the subject of a companion paper to this
(Mason et al., 2012). In this paper, we find that firms who undertake training are
more likely to have vacancies, suggesting that their response to skill shortages is
likely to be a mixture of recruitment and up-skilling strategies.

Our results confirm earlier work that highlights the importance of two distinctions:
First, it is important to distinguish between firms’ general recruitment activity and it
having skill shortage vacancies.       Second, we must distinguish between firms
experiencing recruitment difficulties related to skills and those for other reasons (such
as the firm not offering good enough pay and conditions). Failing to account for this
may cause us to misdiagnose the problem and will therefore undermine the
appropriateness of any policy prescription.

In any market there will be a number of potential customers that cannot purchase all
they would wish because they are unwilling or unable to pay the market price. This
does not mean that the market is malfunctioning. There is an important question for
researchers and policymakers to ask before interpreting reports of unfilled vacancies
of any kind, and of SSVs in particular, as a ‘skills problem’. This question is: Why do
businesses that cannot fill a vacancy not simply raise the wages they are offering?

There a number of reason why firms may not be able to do so. First, it may be
because the firm cannot afford to pay any more. If this is the case, the problem is not
the labour market or the education system, but the firm’s own productivity. Firms that
that undertake activities associated with high productivity are likely to both have a
higher demand for skills and be more able to afford to pay skill premia.

Second, the supply of labour takes a long time to adjust. Because of the length of
time required to educate and train skilled workers, it takes a long time for changes in



                                                                                    iii
wages to influence changes in skill acquisition (particularly if we are relying on the
rather indirect mechanism of changes in relative wages influencing the choices of
students at school) and immigration is restrained by, among other things, legal
barriers and the costs of relocation.

We have found that the businesses that feel the applicants they are attracting do not
have the required skills, qualifications or experience are those that are paying higher
wages. The fact that businesses that pay higher wages than others in the same
industry and region are actually more likely to experience SSVs suggests that raising
wages is not sufficient to fill these vacancies.     In contrast, when we focus on
vacancies that are hard-to-fill for reasons other than skill, paying higher wages does
appear to be a successful policy to fill vacancies. Firms that pay higher relative
wages are less likely to have non-skill-related hard-to-fill vacancies. The implication
of this is that SSVs and NSRs are different phenomena.

One important issue researchers have to confront when undertaking analysis of this
type is that of causality.   It is one thing to establish a statistical regularity – a
correlation between firm characteristics, activities or environment and an outcome
such as external skill shortages. It is another thing to interpret this as a causal
relationship. In this paper, we have uncovered some clear statistical regularities.
These are consistent we with certain predictions we have discussed in this paper and
provide us with useful information to aid our understanding of how the landscape of
skills in New Zealand and, in particular, we done this from the perspective what
businesses are looking for, rather than what the education and training system has
provided.




                                                                                  iv
Table of Contents
Abstract ...................................................................................................................... i
Executive Summary ................................................................................................. ii
Table of Contents ..................................................................................................... v
List of Figures ......................................................................................................... vii
List of Tables .......................................................................................................... vii
1.      Introduction ....................................................................................................... 1
2.     Background – Skills and Economic Performance .......................................... 2
     2.1. Skills and Firm Performance ........................................................................ 2
     2.2. Labour Turnover and Vacancies .................................................................. 5
     2.3. Skill Shortages ............................................................................................. 6
     2.4. Skills and the Labour Market ........................................................................ 7
     2.5. Firm’s Responses to Skill Shortages ............................................................ 8
     2.6. Summary .................................................................................................... 10
3.     Data and Preliminary Analysis ....................................................................... 12
     3.1. Business Operations Survey (BOS) ........................................................... 12
     3.2. Vacancies ................................................................................................... 14
     3.3. Hard-to-fill vacancies .................................................................................. 16
     3.4. Skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies ............................................ 19
     3.5. Internal skill gaps........................................................................................ 20
4.     Method.............................................................................................................. 21
     4.1. Basic econometric model ........................................................................... 22
     4.2. Selection equation – The likelihood of vacancies ....................................... 23
     4.3. Probability of SSVs..................................................................................... 26
5.     Results ............................................................................................................. 30
     5.1. Using contemporaneous variables ............................................................. 30
     5.2. Using lagged variables ............................................................................... 35
     5.3. Skill and non-skill related hard-to-fill vacancies .......................................... 39
6.      Summary and Conclusions ............................................................................ 41
References .............................................................................................................. 45
Appendix A1. Data Appendix .............................................................................. 53
 A1.1 BOS Variables ............................................................................................ 53
   6.1.1. Module A (2005 – 2008) ....................................................................... 53
   6.1.2. Module B – Innovation (2007) ............................................................... 54
   6.1.3. Module C – Employment Practices (2006) ............................................ 55
   6.1.4. Module C – Business Strategy and Skills ............................................. 55
 A1.2 LEED/PAYE Data ....................................................................................... 58
 A1.3 Other LBD Data (AES, BAI, and IR10) ....................................................... 60


                                                                                                                          v
Appendix A2. Comparison of hard-to-fill vacancies in Module C with
recruitment difficulties in Module A ...................................................................... 62




                                                                                                        vi
List of Figures
Figure 1 Skill shortages and Hard-to-fill vacancies in Green et al. (1998) .................. 7
Figure 2 Vacancies, hard-to-fill and skill shortage vacancies ................................... 14



List of Tables
Table 1 Vacancies, hard-to-fill, skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies, % .... 15
Table 2 Businesses reporting vacancies, % ............................................................. 16
Table 3 Businesses reporting hard-to-fill vacancies, % ............................................ 17
Table 4 Year-to-year rank correlation between reported recruitment difficulties ....... 19
Table 5 Skill-related reasons for hard-to-fill vacancies, by size ................................ 20
Table 6 Existing staff with skills required to do their job ........................................... 21
Table 7 Principal component factor analysis of business strategy variables ............ 25
Table 8 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances ................................ 25
Table 9 Principal component factor analysis of 2007 business strategy ................... 26
Table 10 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances .............................. 26
Table 11 Principal component factor analysis of census variables ........................... 29
Table 12 Rotated factor analysis .............................................................................. 29
Table 13 Rotated factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances .................. 29
Table 14 Results - SSVs - Contemporaneous variables - Selection equation .......... 32
Table 15 Results – SSVs – Contemporaneous variables – Outcome equation ........ 34
Table 16 Results - SSVs - Lagged variables - Selection equation............................ 36
Table 17 Results - SSVs - Lagged variables - Outcome equation ............................ 38
Table 18 Results – Different definitions of dependent variable ................................. 40
Table 19 Staff occupation/role variables ................................................................... 58
Table 20 Weighted counts of firms reporting levels of difficulty recruiting new staff in
       Module A by Module C hard-to-fill vacancy response .................................. 63




                                                                                                           vii
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills
Shortages in New Zealand Firms

1. Introduction
Skills are an important determinant of the economic performance of people, firms,
industries and economies1. Shortages of skilled labour directly constrain production
and prevent firms from meeting demand and using available inputs efficiently (Haskel
and Martin, 1993a; Stevens, 2007). Indirectly, skill shortages inhibit innovation and
the use of new technologies. This may have longer-term impacts on the way firms
do business, in terms of their location, size, structure, production methods and
product strategy (Mason and Wilson, 2003; Durbin, 2004; Mason, 2005).

The success of policies to enable the emergence and performance of successful
businesses depends upon having a workforce with the appropriate skills. There are,
however, concerns that New Zealand is experiencing a shortage of workers with
particular skills2. If New Zealand is to raise productivity and improve its international
competitiveness, it is important to understand whether skill shortages do indeed exist,
how they manifest themselves and develop policies to address them.

In this paper we investigate skill shortages deriving from recruitment difficulties at
firm level. That is, vacancies that are hard-to-fill because applicants do not have the


1
  See Card (1999) or Dickson and Harmon (2011) for an overview of the results on the individual
returns to education and skills, Abowd, Kramarz, Margolis (1999) or Haskel, Hawkes and Periera
(2005) for evidence on the relationship between firm performance and skills, Kneller and Stevens
(2005) present international evidence for skills at the industry level in OECD economies and Stevens
and Weale (2004) or Madsen (2010) discuss evidence on the relationship between education levels
and growth.
2
  ‘Skills shortage hits agricultural science ‘, Dominion Post, 13/01/12, ‘Half of Kiwi companies facing
skill shortages’, NZ Herald, 30/11/11, ‘Academic warns of major skills shortage’, Waikato Times,
4/3/11


                                                                                                          1
skill, qualifications or experience the business requires. In order to carry out this
analysis, we make use of a specially-designed survey, the Business Strategy and
Skills (BSS) module of the Business Operations Survey (BOS) 2008. We combine
this with information from other sections of the current and previous years’ BOS and
data from the prototype Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). The LBD includes
information from tax and survey-based financial data, merchandise and services
trade data and a variety of sample surveys on business practices and outcomes.
This allows us to link the responses of the BSS module to a wealth of information on
firms to inform our analysis.

The rest of this paper is as follows. In section 2 we discuss some of the issues that
influence the interrelationship between the skills of the workforce and the
performance of businesses. In section 3 we describe our data and present some
descriptive information on New Zealand firms’ experiences of skills. We set out our
empirical model in section 4 and our results in section 5. Section 6 concludes.


2. Background – Skills and Economic Performance
Human capital (and education in particular) has been found to be an important
determinant of economic development and explanator of international differences in
aggregate economic growth or productivity (Barro and Sala-i-Martín, 1995; Stevens
and Weale, 2004; Kneller and Stevens, 2005; Madsen, 2010).            There is a large
literature examining the links between the availability of skills and the performance of
firms. These range from detailed case studies (see Keep, Mayhew and Corney,
2002, for a summary of those undertaken by the UK National Institute for Economic
and Social Research) to econometric analysis using firm-level data and industry level
measures of skill shortages (e.g. Haskell and Martin, 1993b, 2001; Haskel, Martin
and Periera, 2005; Stevens, 2007). In this section, we consider the importance of
skills for firms, how labour markets match the skills of workers to their uses in firms,
and how firms respond to skills shortages. We also consider what we mean by a
‘skill shortage’. Can such a thing exist in a well-functioning economy?

2.1. Skills and Firm Performance
There are essentially two elements to the link between skills and firm performance.
First, skills represent a basic input into the firm’s production technology. Individuals



                                                                                       2
with higher skills have more human capital and so produce greater output. There is a
large literature that consistently finds positive private and social returns to skill and
education in particular (Card, 1999; Psacharopoulos and Patrinos, 2004; McMahon,
2004).

Higher skill levels do not only increase firm productivity through the direct impact on
the worker’s own productivity.     They also create synergies with other productive
inputs, such as other workers, physical and knowledge capital, R&D or new
technologies.

An obvious example of how skills enhance the performance of other workers is the
skills of managers, who organise and shape production. The quality of management
in businesses is an important predictor of business performance across a number of
dimensions in many countries (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007, 2010; 2011), including
New Zealand (UTS, 2009).

Another way skilled labour increases the productivity of other workers is through what
are known as ‘knowledge spillovers’ (Arrow, 1962; Battu, Belfield and Sloane, 2004;
Audretsch and Feldman, 2004). Spillovers occur when other workers pick up these
skills through observation, interaction or tuition. These spillovers can occur within the
firm and across the boundaries of the firms through direct relationships (i.e. with
suppliers and customers) or through geographic proximity (Glaeser, Kallal,
Scheinkman and Shleifer, 1992; Audretsch and Feldman, 2004).

For a long time it has been suggested that skilled labour is more complementary with
capital than unskilled labour (Griliches, 1969; Duffy, Papageorgiou, and Perez-
Sebastian, 2004).    Many capital goods (e.g. computers) require skills to operate
(Autor, Katz and Krueger, 1998; Morrison-Paul and Siegel, 2001; Falk, 2004). Autor,
Levy and Murname (2003) found that over three decades, computer capital has
replaced workers undertaking routine or repetitive manual and cognitive tasks and
complemented those doing non-routine problem-solving and communications tasks.

As well as physical capital, higher skill levels enable a workforce to deal with the
current technology and, moreover, they enable the firm to better adapt to new
technology (Machin and Van Reenen, 1998). For economists, technology is taken
generally to include the means whereby inputs are brought together to produce
outputs, including organisational and product strategy. Mason (2005) found that the



                                                                                        3
ability of firms in a number of industries to execute ‘high value’ business strategies
was contingent on the skills of their workforce. Work such as Abowd, Haltiwanger,
Lane McKinney and Sandusky (2007) finds a strong positive empirical relationship
between advanced technology and skill. Skills are required not only for the creation
of new technology, but also both for its dispersion and implementation (Rosenberg,
1972; Lane and Lubatkin, 1998; Hall and Khan, 2003; Kneller and Stevens, 2006).

Investing in skills

Both workers and firms have an incentive to increase productivity through investing in
skills, but their incentives are different. Individuals have an incentive to invest in skill
formation because this enables them to function better in the economy and society.
Crucially, they provide the basis for them to earn an income. Firms also have an
incentive to increase the skills of their workforce because this enables them to
perform more tasks or increase the productiveness with which they perform existing
tasks. Because the skills embedded in workers can be increased by investing in
them, economists use the term ‘human capital’.

Firms do not have the incentive to invest in all types of human capital equally.
General human capital is of value to all employers, whereas specific human capital is
valuable only to specific firms or groups of firms (Becker, 1962, 1994; Stevens,
1994) 3 .   Firms will tend to under-provide training of all skills that have some
generality to them (i.e. they are of use to other firms) because of the risks of staff
leaving or being poached; there is a risk that they will pay the costs and other firms
will get the benefits. Because they may not reap all of the rewards – staff may move
elsewhere or be poached by other firms – firms may invest less in such training that
would be socially optimal4. The likelihood of staff using recently acquired human
capital by moving elsewhere will depend of the outside options they have, in
particular the wages on offer.




3
  The specificity of skills may in also be determined by the structure of the market. Acemoglu and
Pischke (1999) argue that certain skills might be potentially useful to other firms (i.e. general) may
become specific because of market imperfections. For example, if there were only one producer in a
sector a particular skill might only be of use to them, whereas if a number of firms were operating in
the same area they could be competing for the same labour.
4
  Both firms and individuals may under invest in skills and education if there are externalities. This
might include agglomeration benefits (such as knowledge dispersion), matching externalities, benefits
in terms of lower crime, higher levels of political engagement and health.


                                                                                                         4
This is where labour differs from other factors of production. It is not tied to the firm,
beyond the terms of its contractual relationship. It can decide to take its skill and use
them elsewhere.

2.2. Labour Turnover and Vacancies
Labour turnover is a basic fact of economic life (Davis, Halitwanger and Schuh, 1996;
Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger, 2006, 2010). For example, from the September
to the December quarter of 2010, total employment in New Zealand expanded from
1,777,110 to 1,810,580, an increase of 33,4705. This change was dwarfed by the
almost half a million workers either leaving or starting jobs from which it resulted.

Because of the dynamic nature of the labour market, we must be careful not to
equate vacancies with job creation. Firms can have positive values for both hires
and separations (Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger, 2006). In the December 2010
quarter, 12.7% of workers in New Zealand became separated from their jobs6. This
is not merely due to firms shrinking (what is called ‘job destruction’). The total job
destruction in the December 2010 quarter was 90,890 – barely two-fifths of the total
worker separations.

Firms will post vacancies for two reasons: First, to replace staff who have quit, retired
or been fired; Second, to fill new roles that have been created by the expansion of
the firm.    These two sources of vacancies are likely to have different causes.
Voluntary separations may be higher in good times (as the likelihood of alternative
employment increases), but involuntary separations may be lower (as firms seek to
reduce employment) (Pissarides, 2000). New roles are more likely to be created
when a firm is expanding7.

Given this discussion, we might reasonably expect the number of vacancies
generally increase with the number of employees. However, some work has found
vacancy rates to decline with firms size (e.g. Holtz, 1994).

Note that our discussion relates to vacancy rates. Our data is a binary variable
stating whether or not a firm posts a vacancy.                   We would generally expect
5
  Source: Statistics New Zealand Linked-Employer Employee Database. Data downloaded from:
http://www.stats.govt.nz/tools_and_services/tools/TableBuilder/leed-quarterly-tables.aspx
6
  Source: Authors’ calculations based on LEED data. This separation rate is calculated as ‘Worker
separations’ in the December 2010 quarter divided by the average of ‘Total filled jobs’ in the
December and September quarters.
7
  For a textbook description of the standard dynamic model of labour demand, see Nickell (1996).


                                                                                                    5
phenomena that increase the numbers or rate of vacancies to also increase the
probability of the firm reporting at least vacancy.

2.3. Skill Shortages
The primary focus of this paper is on difficulties firms face in filling roles for reasons
related to the qualifications or experience of applicants – what we call skill shortage
vacancies. However, this is not the only way in which skill shortages can manifest.

Much early work in this area did not distinguish between the types of skill shortage. It
focussed on ‘skill shortages’ as a whole and their impacts. This was driven in part by
the data that were available to researchers.                      For example, in the UK, the
Confederation of British Industry has collected information on whether firms output
was limited by shortages of skilled labour since the early 1970s8.

However, it has become clear that it is important to distinguish between shortages of
skills in existing workers and shortages of staff in the labour market with appropriate
skills (Green, Machin and Wilkinson, 1998; Mason and Wilson, 2003). These have
been called ‘internal skill gaps’ and ‘external skill gaps’, respectively (e.g. Forth and
Mason, 2004)9. The primary focus of this paper is on external skill gaps.

When examining external skill gaps, it is important to be clear what we are measuring.
As Green et al., (1998) point out, we must be careful not to simply equate them with
vacancies that are hard-to-fill.          As we shall see in section 3.3, there are many
reasons why vacancies may be hard-to-fill. These reasons range from the conditions
of work to the fact that firms are simply not paying the market wage; not all of them
are skill-related. Because of this, authors such as Mason and Stevens (2003) have
focussed on the subset of vacancies that are hard-to-fill for skill-related reasons;
specifically, by examining the reasons for vacancies being hard-to-fill and only
considering those that relate to a lack of qualifications and/or experience in
applicants. This is the approach that informed the design of the relevant sections of
the Business Strategy and Skills module of the BOS 2008, and one that underlies our
analysis in this paper.



8
  This data has been used as an industry-level measure of shortages of skilled workers by Haskel and
Martin (1993a), (1993b) and Stevens (2007).
9
  Although, others have called skills deficiencies relating to the external labour market ‘skills shortages’
and those applicable to a firm’s existing workforce ‘skills gaps’ (Schwalje, 2011).


                                                                                                           6
We summarise the thinking on the various skill shortage concepts in Figure 1. Skill
shortages can be internal to the firm, what we call internal skill gaps (ISG), or
external, what we call skill shortage vacancies (SSV)10. As well as SSVs, vacancies
can be hard-to-fill for other reasons, what we call non-skill related vacancies (NSR).



Figure 1 Skill shortages and Hard-to-fill vacancies in Green et al. (1998)

     Skill shortages                      Hard-to-fill vacancies




               ISG               SSV                 NSR




    ISG = Internal Skill Gap; SSV = Skill Shortage Vacancy; NSR = Non-Skill-Related vacancy



In order to understand why firms might find it difficult to source skilled labour, we
need to consider the wider labour market. We turn our attention to this next.

2.4. Skills and the Labour Market
Modern theories of labour markets are based around the ability of the market to
match individuals to jobs (Pissarides, 2000; Petrongolo, and Pissarides, 2001;
Mortensen, 2005). Trading in the labour market is not without cost. It takes time and
money for businesses to advertise for and assess potential employees. It takes time
and money for workers to search and apply for potential employment. We call these
‘search costs’. Furthermore, costs are incurred when incoming workers start in a
new role; workers need to learn the specific tasks involved in the role and the




10
  Of course some external skill gaps may not manifest themselves as SSVs because the firm may not
bother to post vacancies they know they cannot fill.


                                                                                                7
employer has to learn about the specific abilities of their new employee11. Another
cost is the time a worker or a firm stays in a state awaiting a ‘good’ match. Workers
stay in less-preferable jobs or quit to unemployment while they wait for a better offer
to come along. Firms either allocate a worker who is less aptly skilled to a role, or
hold it open until the ‘right’ worker comes along. We call these ‘mismatch costs’.

Average search costs and mismatch costs are likely to be lower in larger labour
markets; the more jobs and workers there are, the more likely it is that a good match
will exist. Thus, businesses and workers operating in big cities, for example, will
benefit from lower search costs, ceteris paribus. In part because of this, they are less
likely to be stuck in ‘bad’ worker-job matches (as the cost of exiting a low productivity
match is much lower). These ‘thick labour market agglomeration benefits’ can also
come from co-location of economic activity with similar demand for skills; whilst there
is more competition between firms for skilled labour, there will also be a greater
supply (as workers with the appropriate skills are attracted to the area).                   Larger
markets will be driven less by market frictions and more by the fundamental
economic determinants of the productivity of the match (i.e. those that determine the
productivity of the firm, the productivity of the worker and their complementarity).

Firms’ ability to recruit and retain skilled staff will depend on local labour market
conditions. These are typically summarised using the local unemployment rates or
proportions of the population with particular qualifications (e.g. Mason and Stevens,
2003). The firm’s ability to recruit new staff will also be affected by the ‘outside wage’.
The opportunity cost of taking up a job at the firm for the worker is the value of the
next best potential offer foregone.        This will depend on the distribution of job offers
and associated wages. These can be measured by average wage in similar jobs –
for example other jobs in that industry and/or region.

2.5. Firm’s Responses to Skill Shortages
How firms respond to labour market conditions will affect their performance. This is
part of how firms compete. The obvious question to ask if a business cannot fill a
vacancy is: ‘why don’t they just pay more?’ Here we discuss two reasons why this
may not be possible. First, it may be because the firm cannot afford to pay any more.


11
  For more on the training of incoming staff by New Zealand firms, see the companion paper to this
(Timmins, et al., 2012).


                                                                                                     8
In this case, the problem is not the labour market, but the firm’s own productivity.
Firms that that undertake activities associated with high productivity may well both
have a higher demand for skills but also be more able to afford to pay skill premia.
Firms with some degree of market power may not be more productive, but will be
able to compete more aggressively for scarce inputs such as skilled staff.

Second, the supply of labour takes a long time to adjust; it takes a long time for
changes in wages to influence changes in skill acquisition (particularly if we are
relying on the rather indirect mechanism of changes in relative wages influencing the
choices of students at school) and immigration is restrained by, among other things,
legal barriers and the costs of relocation.

In an early study of apparent shortages of engineers and scientists,          Arrow and
Capron (1959) defined a skill shortage as ‘a situation in which there are unfilled
vacancies in positions where salaries are the same as those currently being paid in
others of the same type and quality’ (1959: 301). Although they recognised that
excess demand for skills in competitive labour markets should put upward pressure
on salaries, Arrow and Capron suggested that, even in a competitive labour market,
a steady increase in demand over time for skilled workers could produce a ‘dynamic
shortage’ if there were factors impeding rapid salary increases by employers such as
delays in accepting the needs for such increases, the further time needed to
implement them and a reluctance to incur increased salary costs for existing high-
skilled employees as well as new ones. At the same time supply responses to any
salary improvements could be slowed down by the length of time required to educate
and train skilled workers, as shown by Freeman (1971, 1976) in the case of
engineers and scientists.

Later studies have recognised that firms have a range of potential non-salary
responses and ‘coping mechanisms’ available to them when confronted by shortfalls
in skills – such as asking existing employees to work longer hours, making increased
use of subcontractors or retraining existing staff to develop the skills in shortage. In a
study based on data from the 1984 Workplace Industrial Relations Survey in the UK,
Haskel and Martin (1993b) found no evidence of firms setting higher wages in
response to difficulties in recruiting skilled workers. Indeed, they cited other UK
survey evidence to suggest that salary responses were much less important than
other means of addressing skilled recruitment difficulties.


                                                                                         9
Increased training provision is a potentially important non-salary response to external
skill shortages which, like salary increases, should help alleviate the shortages in
question rather than just help firms to cope with them12. However, just as some firms
may elect to ‘live with’ external skill shortages for periods of time rather than incur the
costs of raising salaries for new recruits with knock-on effects on existing salary
differentials, some may also be reluctant to respond immediately to skill shortages by
increasing training provision for existing workers. Such reluctance could reflect
imperfect information about the costs and benefits of training versus other potential
responses to skill shortages.

But economic theory also points to other possible explanations for variation between
firms in the extent and speed of training responses to different kinds of skill shortage.
For example, Stevens (2007) suggests that the speed of firms’ adjustment behaviour
is likely to vary inversely with the degree of competition in their particular labour
markets for skills specific to their industries.             More generally, resource- and
knowledge-based theories of the firm suggest that heterogeneity of firms’ training
responses to external skill shortages is to be expected. This is because the ability of
any firm to provide training will be strongly conditioned by the specific resources and
capabilities (such as management skills and training capacity) which it has
accumulated over time (Teece, Pisano and Shuen, 1997; Eisenhardt and Martin,
2001; Teece, 2007).

2.6. Summary
This brief overview of the literature suggests a number of avenues for us to pursue in
our analysis.     First, we need to differentiate between firms’ general recruitment
activity and it having skill shortage vacancies. Labour turnover is a basic fact of
economic life.      Fast-growing and large firms will be more likely to be seeking
additional staff.     Second, we need to distinguish between firms experiencing
recruitment difficulties because of the availability of labour with the appropriate skills
and those for other reasons, such as the firm merely not offering good enough pay
and conditions. Failing to account for this may cause us to misdiagnose the problem
and will therefore undermine the appropriateness of any policy prescription. In any


12
  We examine the relationship between training and skill shortages in more detail in Mason, Mok,
Stevens and Timmins, (2012).


                                                                                                   10
market there will be a number of potential customers that cannot purchase all they
would wish because they are unwilling or unable to pay the market price.

Our quick survey of the literature suggests a number of patterns we might expect to
see, or hypotheses we might test:

Firms are more likely to suffer SSVs the greater the proportion of higher skilled staff
they are looking for. Firms operating in tighter local labour markets will find it more
difficult to fill roles. Firms with high-productivity strategies will have a higher demand
for skills, but will be more able to pay skill premia. Firms with a degree of market
power are likely to be more able to pay skill premia relative to their competitors.

From a policy perspective, we wish to know whether these skill shortages are ‘real’ or
not. In any market, there will always be potential buyers who would wish to buy more,
but are unwilling to do so at the current price. We know that labour markets do
adjust supply to meet demand instantaneously; in the short run, the labour supply
curve is likely to be almost vertical13. Thus, a positive shock to demand (caused, for
example, by a firm getting a large export order) is not likely to create an
instantaneous increase in the supply of labour. In the short run, the effect may only
be to increase wage inflation, as the firm outbids its competitors. In some cases the
firm may source skilled workers internationally, but this takes time and resources.

This suggests two alternative hypotheses, one for a labour market with some slack
and one where the supply of labour is tight. If the market is working satisfactorily,
firms that offer higher wages will be less likely to experience SSVs. If there are
shortages of skilled labour and the firms with the highest demand for skills are those
that are the most productive, it may be the firms that pay the highest wages that have
SSVs.

As we shall see below, because we only have a cross-section of data relating to
SSVs, it is likely to be difficult to distinguish some of these phenomena.
Nevertheless, we shall examine both the contemporaneous relationship and that
between current SSVs and previous years’ firm characteristics.




13
  there may of course be some economically inactive workers that are on the margins of entering the
labour market, such as single parents for whom the costs of childcare may raise the reservation wage
higher than their contemporaries


                                                                                                   11
3. Data and Preliminary Analysis
The data come from Statistics New Zealand’s prototype Longitudinal Business
Database (LBD). The LBD is built around the Longitudinal Business Frame (LBF), to
which are attached, among other things, Goods and Services Tax (GST) returns,
financial accounts (IR10) and aggregated Pay-As-You-Earn (PAYE) returns, all
provided by the Inland Revenue Department (IRD). The full LBD is described in
more detail in Fabling, Grimes, Sanderson and Stevens (2008) and Fabling (2009).
The survey data considered in this chapter relate to the Business Operations Survey
(BOS).

The administrative data we use have four sources: the Linked Employer Employee
Database (LEED), the Business Activity Indicator (BAI) dataset of GST returns, the
Annual Enterprise Survey (AES) and IR10 forms. These are described in more detail
in the Data Appendix.

3.1. Business Operations Survey (BOS)
The Business Operation Survey (BOS) is an annual three part modular survey, which
began in 2005. The first module is focussed on firm characteristics and performance.
The second module alternates between biennial innovation and business use of ICT
collections. The third module is a contestable module that enables specific policy-
relevant data to be collected on an ad hoc basis14. The BOS is conducted using two-
way stratified sampling, with stratification on rolling-mean-employment (RME) and
two-digit industry according to the ANZSIC system15. The survey excludes firms with
fewer than six RME and firms in the following industries: M81 Government
Administration, M82 Defence, P92 Libraries, Museums and the Arts, Q95 Personal
Services, Q96 Other Services, and Q97 Private Households Employing Staff. The
2008 survey achieved an 81.1% response rate (after adjusting for ceases), a total of
5,543 usable responses, representing a population of 36,075 firms.

The BOS is something approaching best practice in such surveys internationally. It
has removed replication of surveys16 – and thus reduces respondent load and makes

14
   In 2005 and 2009 this was a ‘Business Practices Module’ and in 2006 an ‘Employment Practices
Survey’. The 2007 module was on ‘International Engagement’.
15
   Note that there was some minor additional stratification conducted at the three-digit level.
16
   Prior to the BOS, surveys tended to occur on a fairly ad hoc basis – one assumes when policy-
makers were considering a particular issue. Thus there was a Business Practices Survey in 2001, an


                                                                                                 12
sampling simpler.        It is explicitly designed with a panel element; enabling more
sophisticated analysis to be undertaken allowing us to better understand issues of
causality and – as the panel element increases – dynamic issues17.

We do not use SNZ-imputed values in cases of item non-response where it is
impossible to obtain them by simple edit rules (e.g. more than one expenditure
categories are missing).

When we discuss questions from the BOS, we shall denote the question by their
module followed by their question number. So, for example, question 15 of Module C
is denoted C15.         When there are multiple categories of response in the same
question (e.g. the different occupational groups in question C18, we use the code
included on the form (e.g. C1801). Question numbers will relate to the 2008 BOS,
unless otherwise specified.

The ‘Business Strategy and Skills’ (BSS) Module

The Business Strategy and Skills (BSS) module of the 2008 Business Operations
Survey was produced as part of the ‘Impact of Skills on New Zealand Firms’ project.
This project involved the Ministry of Economic Development, the Department of
Labour, New Zealand Treasury and the Ministry of Research, Science and
Technology and was partly funded by the Cross Departmental Research Pool. The
module was designed by the project team in conjunction with Statistics New Zealand
and Geoff Mason, from the National Institute of Economic and Social Research in
London.

In this section we consider all firms that report vacancies of any kind and focus in on
hard-to-fill vacancies and what we call skill shortage vacancies (SSV). The skill
shortage vacancies are defined as vacancies that were hard-to-fill because the
applicants lacked the necessary skills, qualification or experience, which is a subset
of hard-to-fill vacancies. As there are other reasons for having hard-to-fill vacancies,
this allows us to distinguish the non-skill-related vacancies from the skill shortage
vacancies.

Innovation Survey in 2003 and a Business Finance Survey in (2004). Elements of each of these are
considered either every year as part of the Business Performance Module (Module A) or every two or
more years (i.e. the Innovation Module is run every other year and the Business Practices Module was
run in 2005 and is scheduled to repeat in 2009).
17
   The panel element is in fact larger than it first seems as there is considerable overlap with previous
surveys, such as the 2001 Business Practices Survey (Fabling, 2007).


                                                                                                       13
The overall percentages of firms reporting each type of vacancy are depicted as
concentric circles in Figure 2. More detail on the construction and patterns of our
measures of vacancies, skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies are set out in
the following sections.



Figure 2 Vacancies, hard-to-fill and skill shortage vacancies




                                               Skill shortage
                                              vacancies (36%)




                                                  Hard-to-fill
                                               vacancies (49%)


                                               Vacancies (77%)



   Figure shows the percentage of firms that report each type of vacancy
   Figures based in sample strata and weights
   Note that figures for the percentage of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the
    tables in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample
    and (b) we do not use imputed values




3.2. Vacancies
Respondents were asked: ‘During the last financial year, has this business had any
vacancies?’ (C14). The first row of Table 1 summarises these data. We shall return
to this table when we discuss hard-to-fill and skill shortage vacancies below.

Overall, 76.6% of firms reported that they had posted a vacancy. As one might
expect (given the greater number of employees), the likelihood of posting a vacancy
increases with firm size.




                                                                                                                14
Table 1 Vacancies, hard-to-fill, skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies, %
                                                       Business size
                                                                                               Overall
                                     E <20*      20≤E<50         50≤E<100         E≥100
Vacancies                             71.8          89.5            93.6           95.2          76.6
Hard-to-fill Vacancies                44.2          58.8            65.2           73.4          48.7
Skill Shortage Vacancies              32.1          43.1            48.6           58.6          35.7
    Table shows percentage of firms reporting each type of vacancy
    Figures based in sample strata and weights
    Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.
    Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business population
     with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data Appendix.
    Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables
     in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we
     do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year,
     rather than 2007.



We can break the reporting of vacancies down by occupation. Respondents that
reported they had posted vacancies in the last year were asked a follow-up question:
‘During the last financial year, how many vacancies has this business had for the
following roles?’ (C15). The responses to this question are set out in Table 2.

It is for ‘clerical, sales and services workers’ that the greatest proportion of firms had
vacancies, followed by ‘labourers, production, transport or other workers’.                                    This
reflects the greater number of staff in these occupations 18. This is not quite true
across all firm sizes. ‘Managers’ is the second most popular category for firms with
more than one hundred employees (and also, marginally, for those with between 50
and 99 employees).




18
     See Figure 6 of Stevens (2012)


                                                                                                                  15
Table 2 Businesses reporting vacancies, %
                                                              Business size
                                                                                                     Overall
                                              E<20*      20≤E<50        50≤E<100         E≥100
Managers                                       10.2         23.2            40.1          62.4         15.8
Professionals                                  11.5         19.1            29.1          42.6         14.8
Technicians and associate profs                 8.7         19.3            25.7          38.5         12.4
Tradespersons and rel. workers                 20.4         25.5            27.5          36.3         22.1
Clerical sales and service workers             28.6         45.2            58.7          72.8         34.5
Labourers, production, transport or
                                               26.2         41.1            47.3          53.3         30.7
other workers
All occupations                                68.5         86.1            89.4          88.0         73.1
   Table presents data from questions C14: ‘During the last financial year, has this business had any vacancies?’
    and C15: ‘During the last financial year, how many vacancies has this business had for the following roles?’
   Table shows percentage of firms reporting each type of vacancy
   Figure for ‘all occupations’ does not match that for Table 1 because some firms do not report the occupations
    of their vacancies
   Figures based in sample strata and weights
   Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.
   * Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business
    population with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data
    Appendix.
   Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables
    in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we
    do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year,
    rather than 2007.




3.3. Hard-to-fill vacancies
Respondents were asked: ‘During the last financial year, was this business easily
able to fill all vacancies with suitable applicants?’ (C16). Those who answered ‘no’ to
this question were classified as having a hard-to-fill vacancy. The second row of
Table 1 (repeated at the bottom of Table 3) summarises these data. Well over half of
the firms that have vacancies find them hard-to-fill (47.9% compared to 76.6%).
Again, the probability of having a hard-to-fill vacancy increases with firm size, with
almost three-quarters of firms with rolling mean employment of one hundred or more
having hard-to-fill vacancies.




                                                                                                               16
Table 3 Businesses reporting hard-to-fill vacancies, %
                                                                  Business size
                                                                                                           Overall
                                                E<20*        20≤E<50        50≤E<100          E≥100
Managers                                          4.9          10.1           16.7             29.4          7.2
Professionals                                     7.1          11.6           16.1             24.8          9.0
Technicians and associate profs                   4.6          8.4            11.3             19.4          6.1
Tradespersons and related workers                13.7          16.3           15.1             19.8          14.4
Clerical sales and service workers               10.2          14.2           18.1             24.6          11.8
Labourers, production, transport or
other workers                                     12.3          17.6            19.9           22.9          13.9
All occupations                                   44.2          58.8            65.4           73.6          48.7
   Table presents data from questions C16 ‘During this last financial year, was this business easily able to fill all
    vacancies with suitable applicants?’ and C18: ‘Mark all that apply/ for this business, which roles were hard-to-
    fill?’
   Table shows percentage of firms reporting each type of vacancy
   Figure for ‘all occupations’ does not match that for Table 1 because some firms do not report the occupations
    of their hard-to-fill vacancies
   Figures based in sample strata and weights
   Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.
   Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business population
    with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data Appendix.
   Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables
    in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we
    do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year,
    rather than 2007.



Respondents that reported that they found some vacancies hard-to-fill were asked:
‘For this business, which roles were hard-to-fill?’ (C18). ‘Tradespersons and related
workers’ were the occupations with which most businesses had recruitment
difficulties (Table 3). This reflects a more even spread of hard-to-fill vacancies by
firm size and hence the influence of the greater number of small (6-19 employees)
firms.

‘Managers’ were the role for which most large (100+) firms found difficult to fill
vacancies. Given that managers represent a relatively small proportion of total staff,
and one that has an important impact on firm performance (Bloom and Van Reenen,
2007, 2010; UTS, 2010), this is a worrying result.

Comparison with Recruitment Difficulties in Module A

In order to place these figures in context, it is useful to compare these results with the
responses to a similar question that is asked in Module A.                                    In a section on
employment, firms are asked ‘Over the last financial year, to what extent did this
business experience difficulty in recruiting new staff for any of the following



                                                                                                                    17
occupational groups?’ (A33). The different language used in module C (vacancy plus
hard-to-fill vacancy) and Module A (‘difficulty in recruitment’), differences in the
response categories and the influence of previous questions mean that these are not
identical19. The results of such a comparison are presented in Appendix A2. In
summary, there is a high degree of correlation between the two measures, but that
this is not total. The majority of respondents that said they had a severe difficulty in
recruiting each type of staff in Module A said that vacancies were hard-to-fill in
Module C.

The Persistence of Recruitment Difficulties

Notwithstanding the differences between the Module A recruitment difficulties
variables and the Module C hard-to-fill vacancies variable, we can use the Module A
question to consider the persistence of recruitment difficulties. In order to prevent us
becoming overwhelmed with tables, we focus on the year-to-year rank correlations
between the responses to the recruitment difficulty question (A33) for the 2005, 2006,
2007 and 2008 surveys.

As we can see from Table 4, the correlations are both high and significant.
Interestingly, whilst the correlation does decline over time, this decline is not very
steep. There may be a number of reasons for this. One might be that firms with
recruitment difficulties are more likely to have had them in the past, but not
necessarily every year. Another may be a function of the attrition in the survey, as
firms enter and leave.

Whatever the reasons for the particular pattern, there is clearly considerable
persistence in the existence of recruitment difficulties.              We shall consider the
predictive power of previous recruitment difficulties for the probability of the firm
posting a vacancy in our econometric analysis in the following section.




19
  For more on the subject of how respondents interpret and answer questions in business surveys,
with particular reference to the BOS, see Fabling, Grimes and Stevens (2008, 2012).


                                                                                                   18
Table 4 Year-to-year rank correlation between reported recruitment difficulties
                2005          2006           2007       2008              2005       2006       2007      2008

Managers and professionals                                           Tradesmen and related occupations
2006    0.5836***     1                                              0.4827***   1
               (0.0000)                                                  (0.0000)
2007          0.4522*** 0.5402***              1                     0.4506*** 0.4592***          1
               (0.0000)      (0.0000)                                    (0.0000)   (0.0000)
2008          0.5151*** 0.5225*** 0.5450***                1         0.3668*** 0.4462*** 0.6254***         1
               (0.0000)      (0.0000)      (0.0000)                      (0.0000)   (0.0000)   (0.0000)

Technicians and assistant professionals                              Other occupations
                       ***
2006          0.4534             1                                   0.3357***         1
               (0.0000)                                                  (0.0000)
2007          0.4225*** 0.5687***              1                     0.3105*** 0.3874***          1
               (0.0000)      (0.0000)                                    (0.0000)   (0.0000)
2008          0.4161*** 0.4183*** 0.6455***                1         0.3011*** 0.3362*** 0.4067***         1
               (0.0000)      (0.0000)      (0.0000)                      (0.0000)   (0.0000)   (0.0000)
    p value in parenthesis
    * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%




3.4. Skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies
Respondents that had hard-to-fill vacancies were asked ‘For which of the following
reasons did this business find it hard-to-fill vacancies?’ (question C17). They were
given twelve categories, from which they could choose as many as they wished.
Those that replied ‘applicants lack the work experience the business demands’ or
‘applicants lack the qualifications or skills the business demands’ were defined as
having skill shortage vacancies (SSVs) 20 .                          Around the same numbers of firms
reported each of these reasons across all firm sizes (Table 5). However, only around
half of businesses that reported that applicants lacked appropriate experience also
reported that they lacked the appropriate qualifications or skills (and vice versa).
Thus, we should be careful as considering these two explanations as synonymous.
Table 5 shows that there are attributes workers obtain through their on-the-job
experience that businesses value over and above qualifications and, in particular,
separate from the things that they call ‘skills’. It may be that experience connotes a
depth of skill rather than merely its presence.




20
     For the full list of responses, see SNZ (2008).


                                                                                                                 19
Table 5 Skill-related reasons for hard-to-fill vacancies, by size
                                                                     Business Size
                                                     RME        20 ≤ RME        50 ≤ RME         100+
                                                                                                             Total
                                                     <20           <50            <100           RME
Applicants lack work experience the                   25.4         34.7            37.9          48.1        28.4
business demands
Applicants lack qualifications or skills
                                                      25.1         35.2            38.3          47.5        28.2
the business demands
Lack either qualifications or work
                                                      13.7         16.2            20.9          21.8        14.7
experience
Lack both qualifications and work
                                                      18.4         26.8            27.7          36.8        20.9
experience
   Table presents data from questions C17 ‘For which of the following reasons did this business find it hard-to-fill
    vacancies?’
   Table shows percentage of firms reporting each response
   Figures based in sample strata and weights
   Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.
   Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business population
    with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data Appendix.
   Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables
    in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we
    do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year,
    rather than 2007.



Firms that replied having other reasons besides ‘applicants lack the work experience
the business demands’ or ‘applicants lack the qualifications or skills the business
demands’ were defined as having non-skill-related shortage vacancies (NSR). We
shall use this information allows us to better understand what is unique about skill-
shortage vacancies than other recruitment difficulties that would have different
implications for policy.

3.5. Internal skill gaps
In this section, we explore the internal skill gaps from the BOS 2008 and skill
improvement needs obtained from the computer-aided telephone interview (CATI).
From the BOS, respondents were asked ‘How many of this business’s existing staff
have the skills required to do their job?’ for 6 given occupation groups of managers;
professionals; technicians and associate professionals; tradespersons and related
workers; clerical, sales and service workers; and labourer, production, transport or
other workers. Respondents were further asked the reasons for their staff not having
the skills required. Table 6 shows that more than half of the firms have all their
managers and clerical, sales and service workers with skills required. Internal skill




                                                                                                                  20
gaps are more prominent for less skilled workers, such as clerical, sales and service
workers and labourers, production, transport and other workers.



Table 6 Existing staff with skills required to do their job
                                                              Proportion of staff with skills (%)
Occupation                                                 Less than half       Half or more        All staff
Managers                                                         9.8                 11.7            78.5
Professionals                                                    4.4                 7.3             37.7
Technicians and associate professionals                          3.3                 9.0             33.0
Tradespersons and related workers                                4.4                 16.1            32.4
Clerical, sales and service workers                              4.4                 20.3            60.6
Labourers, production, transport and others                      4.2                 19.0            36.6
    Table presents data from questions C20 ‘How many of this business’s existing staff have the skills required to
     do their job?’
    Source: SNZ (2009)
    Note that the percentages in this table are taken from ‘SNZ (2009) and are not exactly comparable with the
     Table 1 and Table 2 and Figure 2. For more on this, see the footnotes to Table 1 and Table 2.




4. Method
In this section we outline our empirical strategy.                          First we set out our basic
econometric model. This is a two stage, ‘Heckman selection’ model, where we allow
for the interrelationship between the firm’s decision to look for staff externally and
post a vacancy and the probability that these vacancies prove to be hard-to-fill for
skill-related reasons.21

In the following two sections we consider the variables included in each stage of the
model. One of the key issues we face is that we only have one year of information
on our dependent variable, so our model is essentially a cross-sectional model. This
makes interpreting coefficients as causal relationships, rather than merely uncovering
statistically significant correlations, difficult. This is a problem faced by many studies
of this nature (e.g. Mason and Stevens, 2003). We seek to overcome (or at least
mitigate) this by using the fact that the Business Operations Survey is embedded in
the prototype Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). We use additional data from



21
   An earlier version of this paper (Mason et al., 2010), shows the importance of accounting for the
relationship between in this way. In unpublished work we also considered using multinomial logit and
bivariate probit models, but concluded that these were not appropriate also.


                                                                                                                21
previous years’ BOS and information on the firm we have from other sources,
specifically tax and survey data.

Another important issue to bear in mind is the fact that the unit of observation in our
empirical analysis is the firm (in LBD parlance, the enterprise).         Thus, when we
estimate the probability of a skill shortage vacancy, we are estimating the probability
of a firm with a vacancy having at least one that is hard-to-fill for skill-related reasons.
We are not estimating the probability of a particular vacancy being hard-to-fill for skill
related reasons. For this we would need vacancy-level information. Our focus is on
the impact on firms rather than on individual vacancies.

Finally, in order to aid interpretation, we also supplement our analysis of SSVs by
considering different specifications of our dependent variable (whether the firm has
an SSV): we investigate specifications where the outcome is restricted to firms that
have SSV only (i.e. not for other reasons)

4.1. Basic econometric model
The primary model we estimate is the probability of reporting skill shortage vacancies
accounting for sample selection. We model the first stage (the selection equation) as
being the probability of reporting having posted a vacancy. The second stage is the
probability that a firm with vacancies finds at least one of them hard-to-fill for reasons
of skill. We also investigate different outcomes in the second stage equations (i.e.
non-skill-related hard-to-fill vacancies and various variations on the SSV/NSR theme).
The discussion of method that follows, however, focuses on the model for SSVs, to
keep the exposition clear.

We suppose that the propensity of firm i to post a skill shortage vacancy can be
expressed as

(1)                          SSVi   X i    1i
                                                  

where SSV* is the propensity to have a skill shortage vacancy, Xi is a (1×k) vector of k
explanatory variables,  is a (k×1) vector of parameters to be estimated and  i an
error term. We do not observe the SSV* terms, but the binary realisation of them.
Therefore we assume:




                                                                                          22
SSVi  0 if       SSVi   0
(2)
                                   SSVi  1 if      SSVi   0

This variable SSVi takes one of three values. If the firm reports a skill shortage, SSV
takes the value of 1. It takes the value zero if the firm does not have a skill shortage
vacancy, but does have a vacancy. It takes a missing value when the firm does not
have any vacancies.

The dependent variable in (2) for observation i is observed if:

(3)                                Vaci  Z i   2i  0

where

                                           1 ~ N 0,1
(4)                                         2 ~ N 0,1
                                           corr 1 ,  2   

When  ≠ 0, standard probit techniques applied to (2) yield biased results. The
selection model provides consistent, asymptotically efficient estimates for all the
parameters in the model. For the model to be identified, we should have at least one
variable in the selection equation (3) that is not in the outcome equation.

4.2. Selection equation – The likelihood of vacancies
In our selection equation (the probability of reporting a vacancy), we include the
following variables in the X vector22. Scale will be an important issue; clearly the
more employees a firm has, the more likely it is to have lost one and need to
advertise for a replacement. We measure firm size by the (natural) logarithm of
rolling mean employment plus a count of working proprietors (from the Linked
Employer-Employee Database or LEED), ln(E).                       This highlights an important link
between the workers in a firm and the vacancies it posts. The more workers that quit
or are fired from a firm, the more it must replace. We include a direct measure of this
with the separation rates (the total number of employees that leave a firm in a year
divided by the number of employees, again from the LEED), SepRate.

It may be the case that occupations differ in their likelihood of quitting (because they
have different outside options, for example). Therefore we include variables for the

22
     For more information on the variables see the Data Appendix to this paper.


                                                                                                 23
proportions of staff that are ‘managers’, ‘professionals’, ‘associate professionals or
technicians’ or ‘tradespersons’, Propman to Proptrade.

Firms that are already experiencing internal skill gaps may be more likely to attempt
to fill these via external recruitment. Therefore, we include a variable that indicates
whether the firm feels that their staff lack the skills to perform their roles, ISG.

We consider the firms productivity levels using both (the natural logarithm of) their
labour productivity, ln(LP), and multifactor productivity, MFP. The latter is generated
as the residual from a series of industry-level production functions estimated by OLS.

Relative wages

Workers choose to accept a job offer contingent on their knowledge of all alternative
offers. However, if their wages slip behind other alternatives (because wages in the
firm grow more slowly or wages in similar firms grow more rapidly), workers may
leave23. We therefore include the change in wages paid by the firm relative to other
firms in the same industry, j, in the same region, r, (we discuss the calculation of this
in more detail in section 4.3 below), [ln(Wi) – ln(Wijr)].

It may be the case that firms with market power in their product market have greater
scope to compete for scarce skilled labour (their supernormal profits are, in effect,
shared between the owners of capital and labour). Because of this, we also include
a dummy variable to indicate whether the firm is effectively a monopoly (Monopoly).

Business Strategy

To investigate the relationship between he firms’ business strategy and the demand
for skills, we include a set of variables to indicate the business strategy of the firm.
The variables we consider are: whether it was able to obtain a higher price than its
competitors for its goods and services (Price_Leader); whether it developed or
introduced any new or significantly improved goods or services, operational
processes, organisational/ managerial processes or marketing methods (Innovate);
whether it undertook research and development (R&D); whether its primary market
was international, rather than local or national (Mark_Inter); whether it provided
customised goods or services (Customise); whether it exported (Export); or whether it
undertook outward foreign direct investment (ODI).

23
     For a discussion on the influences on individual’s decisions to quit, see Stevens (2005).


                                                                                                 24
There are a number of factors that make it difficult to include the whole suite of
potential business strategy variables from the BOS in our analysis. First, we only
have a single cross-section of information on our dependent variables. Second, the
business strategy variables are highly correlated with each other. Third, business
practices are highly correlated with firm performance and, thus, productivity and the
firm’s ability to pay higher wages than its competitors.                  Fourth, they are all binary or
other forms of categorical variables. These combine to make analysis difficult and
potential make our estimated coefficients erratic and even counter-intuitive. Because
of these issues, we also performed factor analysis and took the factor that had an
Eigenvalue of one 24 (which in our econometric analysis will be called BS1). The
results of our factor analysis are set our it Table 7 and Table 8.


Table 7 Principal component factor analysis of business strategy variables
Factor       Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative
Factor1        1.03421         0.79462         1.3842            1.3842
Factor2        0.23959         0.23876         0.3207            1.7049
Factor3        0.00083         0.06736         0.0011            1.7060
Factor4        -0.06653        0.01844         -0.0890           1.6169
Factor5        -0.08497        0.07256         -0.1137           1.5032
Factor6        -0.15753        0.06092         -0.2108           1.2924
Factor7        -0.21845                        -0.2924           1.0000
    LR test: independent vs. saturated: chi2(21) = 2374.58 Prob>chi2 = 0.0000


Table 8 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances
Variable            Factor1 (BS1)        Factor2       Factor3       Uniqueness
Mark_Inter               0.4563          -0.2085        0.0097          0.7482
Customise                0.1627           0.2250        0.0119          0.9228
Price_Leader             0.2047           0.2074        0.0150          0.9148
Innovate                 0.2598           0.2691       -0.0100          0.8600
R&D                      0.4721           0.0954       -0.0127          0.7678
Export                   0.5731          -0.1229        0.0047          0.6565
ODI                      0.3725          -0.0765       -0.0093          0.8553



The panel nature of the BOS allows us to consider the firms business strategy in
years prior to the current year’s vacancies (and SSVs).                          However, some of the
variables (i.e., those in Module C) are not available.                       Therefore, we consider a
different set of variables and also undertake a separate factor analysis of these. The
24
     The so called ‘Kaiser-Guttman rule’ after Guttman (1954) and Kaiser (1970).


                                                                                                      25
variables we take from the 2007 BOS included the three variables from Module A in
the above analysis: whether they conducted R&D (R&D07), exported (Export07), or
undertook ODI (ODI07). Because we have access to the innovation module B in 2007,
we are able to divide their innovation activity into the four constituent parts, that is,
new or significantly altered: products (prod_inno07), processes (proc_inno07),
organisation (org_innov07) and marketing (mark_inno07).                         The results of our factor
analysis are set out in Table 9 and Table 10.



Table 9 Principal component factor analysis of 2007 business strategy
Factor      Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative
Factor1       1.49186         1.03350          1.1324           1.1324
Factor2       0.45836         0.47050          0.3479           1.4803
Factor3       -0.01214        0.08671          -0.0092          1.4711
Factor4       -0.09885        0.03521          -0.0750          1.3961
Factor5       -0.13406        0.01513          -0.1018          1.2943
Factor6       -0.14918        0.08937          -0.1132          1.1811
Factor7       -0.23855           .             -0.1811          1.0000
   LR test: independent vs. saturated: chi2(21) = 3637.14 Prob>chi2 = 0.0000


Table 10 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances
                       Factor1
Variable                                Factor2      Uniqueness
                        (BS07)
R&D07                   0.4245            0.3145         0.7208
Export07                0.3133            0.3712         0.7641
ODI07                   0.2351            0.2875         0.8621
prod_innov07            0.5866            0.0259         0.6552
proc_innov07            0.5428           -0.1862         0.6707
org_innov07             0.5153           -0.2451         0.6744
mark_innov07            0.5039           -0.2088         0.7025




4.3. Probability of SSVs
In addition to some of the control variables included in the selection equation, we
also investigate the relationship between SSVs and relative wages, the local labour
market and types of staff for whom firms are seeking to hire.




                                                                                                       26
Wages

One might expect a major determinant of firms’ ability to fill any vacancy to be the
wages it pays relative to other potential employers. We have discussed above why
this might not be as clear as it first seems and so the sign on the coefficient of
relative wages will tell us something about the function of the New Zealand labour
market.

In considering the appropriate measure of outside wages, there are a number of
factors to take into account. The unit of observation for the data on wages is the
establishment. We do not have information on wages by skill level. Our measure of
wages is the total wage bill divided by the number of employees on the 13 th of the
month. This can be aggregated from a monthly establishment measure to an annual
enterprise measure using employment weights (or, equivalently, by summing wage
costs and rolling mean employment over the year and dividing one by the other)25.

The two dimensions over which we can measure variation in the outside wage are
industry classification and geography.           However, firms often operate in multiple
industries and/or multiple locations. Firm level analysis generally uses the concept of
‘predominant industry’. This is typically measured by taking the industry in which the
firm employs the most workers.             Thus, if a firm has two establishments, one
employing 100 workers constructing boats and one employing 20 to sell marine
safety equipment, we say the firm is a boat-maker. If the firm has establishments in
more than one region, we could proceed by analogy to determine its ‘predominant
region’. This is the course followed by Grimes, Ren and Stevens (2012)26. Because
we have information of the numbers of employees and wages at the establishment
level, along with the region in which that establishment is situated and its ANZSIC
code, we can calculate a more sophisticated measure. We calculate the relative
wage at the establishment level and aggregate it across industries and locations in
which it operates using employment weights.

In the analysis for this paper, we actually considered three outside wage measures:
the average wage in the 4-digit industry; the average wage in the local region and;

25
   As with other measures using LEED employment, this measure does not take into account the
hours worked by employees (we cannot calculate hourly wages), but it does take into account monthly
variations within the year (e.g. seasonal working).
26
   This is because in the questions on internet connectivity in the 2006 Business Operations Survey
used by Grimes et al., respondents are answer with respect to their largest operation.


                                                                                                 27
the average wage of firms in the industry in the region. However, the measures are
highly correlated with each other at the enterprise level and the influence on the
results is marginal.       Therefore, in this paper, we present results from only the
industry-regional measure as it reflects both the national market for skills of a similar
nature and the geographic area.

We chose the Territorial Authority as the appropriate region as we believe that this
most closely approximates a travel-to-work area27. In order to maintain cell sizes, the
definition of industry on which we settled was the 2-digit level according to the
ANZSIC 1996 classification.         In cases where the number of firms in a cell dropped
below 50, we used data at the next level of industry aggregation.

The industry-region outside wage for an enterprise (the unit of observation in the LBD
that broadly corresponds with what economists would call the firm) was calculated as
the average wage in the industry-region cell in which the establishments in the
enterprise operated, aggregated using establishment employment weights. That is,
the outside wage of enterprise i, consisting of L establishments, is given by
                                       L   M
                                                  Ei
(5)                             Woi                W jrm
                                       l 1 m 1 Eikm


where Wjrm is the average wage of the establishments in the 2-digit industry j in the
Territorial Authority r in month m (M will typically, but not exclusively, be 12), Ei is the
total employment in the enterprise and Eikm is the employment in each establishment
in a given month.

Local Labour Market Conditions

We consider three measures of the local labour market conditions (beyond the
industry-region wage).        These come from the 2006 Census of Population and
Dwellings. The first two are measures of the supply of labour at the two ends of the
education distribution. First, we consider the percentage of the population with a
degree or higher qualification. Second, we consider the percentage of the population
with no qualifications. The third variable we consider is the unemployment rate in the
Territorial Authority.


27
  It is possible to calculate more sophisticated measures of outside wages and local labour market
conditions using more disaggregated (Area Unit or even Meshblock) data and weighting it by some
function of the distance between the two areas. We leave this to later work.


                                                                                                     28
Because these variables are highly correlated, we perform a factor analysis. The
factor analysis produces two primary factors with Eigenvalues of greater than one. In
order to facilitate interpretation, we undertake factor rotation and obtain the two
factors (Census1 and Census2) as set out in Table 11 to Table 13. The first factor is
primarily made up of the percentage of the population with no qualifications and
unemployment rate variables. The second is a combination of the percentage with
degree and unemployment rate.



Table 11 Principal component factor analysis of census variables

Factor         Eigenvalue        Difference       Proportion       Cumulative

Factor 1         1.50331          0.27826            0.5011            0.5011
Factor 2         1.22505          0.95341            0.4083            0.9095
Factor 3         0.27164             .               0.0905            1.0000
   LR test: independent vs. saturated: chi2(3) = 3782.54 Prob>chi2 = 0.0000


Table 12 Rotated factor analysis

Factor         Eigenvalue         Difference       Proportion       Cumulative

Census1           1.41023          0.09211            0.4701           0.4701
Census2           1.31812             .               0.4394           0.9095
   Rotation method: orthogonal varimax


Table 13 Rotated factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances

Variable                    Census1        Census2        Uniqueness

% no qualifications          0.9318         -0.2150           0.0854
% degree or higher           -0.1096        0.9553            0.0754
% unemployment               0.7279         0.5995            0.1108




Occupational breakdown of vacancies

Given the specific nature of many skills, an important element of the ease with which
firms will be able to vacancies will be for whom they are seeking. We therefore
include four variables for the proportion of vacancies that are for the following
occupational groups: managers (Vman), professionals (Vprof), technicians and associate
professionals (Vtech) and tradespersons and related workers (Vtrade). The baseline is a


                                                                                     29
combination of clerical sales and services workers and labourers, production,
transport or other workers28.


5. Results
Our results are set out in three sections. In the first section (5.1) we examine SSVs
using contemporaneous variables.                These will show us which types of firms are
currently experiencing SSVs. Next we consider lagged values of the BOS and other
LBD variables (5.2). This allows us to look at the characteristics of firms prior to the
year in which they reported SSVs. Finally, we consider different specifications of the
dependent variable to give some contextual information to help understand our main
results (5.3).

5.1. Using contemporaneous variables
The results from our estimation using contemporaneous variables are set out in
Table 14 and Table 15.             The first two columns show the impact of our industry
dummies, with column (1) excluding industry dummies and the subsequent columns
including them.       In column (3) we introduce internal skill gaps and our business
strategy variables.        Column (4) replaces the strategy variables with the principal
factor and the final column presents a more parsimonious specification.

Table 14 presents the results for the selection equation of our contemporaneous
specifications. Comparison of (1) and (2) suggests that the impact of our industry
dummies on the remaining coefficients is relatively minor.

In general, larger firms and those that are growing are more likely to be posting a
vacancy. The separation rate of the firm has no more predictive power beyond the
total number of employees in explaining the variation in the probability of posting a
vacancy.

Firms that are increasing their wages faster than their competitors tend to be more
likely to have a vacancy, although this is not statistically significant in all
specifications. Note, however, that in this contemporaneous specification this may
reflect firms raising wages in response to staff turnover or firm expansion. This is
something we return to when we consider our lagged specifications in section 5.2

28
  We also included the first of these in preliminary analysis, but its coefficient was never statistically
significant.


                                                                                                             30
below. The productivity of the firm does not appear to help explain the probability of a
firm posting a vacancy, ceteris paribus29.

Firms that undertake training in the current year are more likely to have vacancies.
Firms enjoying a monopoly in their product market and those with collective
agreements are no more likely to have vacancies.

None of the occupations appear to be any more likely to create a need for vacancies.
When we account for the occupational make-up of the firms employment (in columns
(1) to (3)), we find no relationship between this and the likelihood of posting a
vacancy. Because of this, we exclude the occupational variables from specifications
(4) and (5).

We introduce our measure of internal skill gaps (ISG) and business strategy
variables in column (3). Firms with internal skill gaps are no more likely to have
vacancies, ceteris paribus. Firms that consider themselves to be price leaders and
those that have innovated are more likely to have vacancies, a result that is
statistically significant at the 1% level. Firms that undertake a high degree of
customisation and ODI are also more likely to have a vacancy, although these results
are significant only at the 10% level.

When we replace these binary variables with the factor (BS1), this is positively
correlated with the probability of having vacancies (columns (4) and (5)). This result
is significant at the 5% level.




29
  Note that we estimated a number of different specifications of the productivity variable and obtain
similar results. We also estimated the models in Table 14 and Table 15 with both labour productivity
and MFP, but the models with MFP either failed or experienced difficulty converging. We take this as
a sign of a less well-specified model and so do not present the results.


                                                                                                    31
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms
A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Was ist angesagt?

2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.com
2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.com2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.com
2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.comPearson North America
 
Projections- Employee Orientation
Projections- Employee OrientationProjections- Employee Orientation
Projections- Employee OrientationProjections, Inc
 
Apprenticeships in sm es the key debates
Apprenticeships in sm es   the key debatesApprenticeships in sm es   the key debates
Apprenticeships in sm es the key debatesGed Mirfin
 
#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...
#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...
#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...Emma Mirrington
 
KGWI: What Talent Wants - Finance
KGWI: What Talent Wants - FinanceKGWI: What Talent Wants - Finance
KGWI: What Talent Wants - FinanceKelly Services
 
An Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern Corporation
An Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern CorporationAn Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern Corporation
An Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern Corporationujiroveron
 
Management Consulting Project
Management Consulting ProjectManagement Consulting Project
Management Consulting ProjectTanya Shulha
 
business pulse report 04sm
business pulse report 04smbusiness pulse report 04sm
business pulse report 04smCathy Hawkins
 
34-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.05
34-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.0534-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.05
34-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.05Sham Majid
 
Presentation group assignment
Presentation group assignmentPresentation group assignment
Presentation group assignmentfarnidakamal
 
A-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-gen
A-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-genA-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-gen
A-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-genKammie Reile
 
http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015
http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015
http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015Vijayan Chetty
 
International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)
International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)
International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)inventionjournals
 
Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...
Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...
Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...Total Assignment Help
 
Chapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource Management
Chapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource ManagementChapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource Management
Chapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource ManagementWisnu Dewobroto
 

Was ist angesagt? (18)

2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.com
2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.com2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.com
2010 PLS Career Summit: Eric Winegardner, VP of Client Adoptions, Monster.com
 
Projections- Employee Orientation
Projections- Employee OrientationProjections- Employee Orientation
Projections- Employee Orientation
 
Apprenticeships in sm es the key debates
Apprenticeships in sm es   the key debatesApprenticeships in sm es   the key debates
Apprenticeships in sm es the key debates
 
#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...
#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...
#FIRMday Oct 22nd London - Hireserve - How can academia transform your grad r...
 
KGWI: What Talent Wants - Finance
KGWI: What Talent Wants - FinanceKGWI: What Talent Wants - Finance
KGWI: What Talent Wants - Finance
 
An Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern Corporation
An Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern CorporationAn Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern Corporation
An Analysis of Human Resources In The Modern Corporation
 
Management Consulting Project
Management Consulting ProjectManagement Consulting Project
Management Consulting Project
 
business pulse report 04sm
business pulse report 04smbusiness pulse report 04sm
business pulse report 04sm
 
IDQ-2016-03-Lauricella
IDQ-2016-03-LauricellaIDQ-2016-03-Lauricella
IDQ-2016-03-Lauricella
 
34-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.05
34-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.0534-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.05
34-36_SP Feature (HR & Compliance)_16.05
 
Presentation group assignment
Presentation group assignmentPresentation group assignment
Presentation group assignment
 
A-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-gen
A-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-genA-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-gen
A-Business-Case-Report-for-Workers Age 50Plus-res-gen
 
http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015
http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015
http://www.slideshare.net/VijayanChetty/comment-annual-report-2015
 
International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)
International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)
International Journal of Business and Management Invention (IJBMI)
 
Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...
Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...
Human resource-management-essay-challenges-in-employee-attraction-and-retenti...
 
Chapter 3
Chapter 3 Chapter 3
Chapter 3
 
Chapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource Management
Chapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource ManagementChapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource Management
Chapter 1 Dynamic Environment of Human Resource Management
 
Recruiting
RecruitingRecruiting
Recruiting
 

Ähnlich wie A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms

A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...
A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...
A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...IIJSRJournal
 
White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)
White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)
White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)Tracey Kelly
 
How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...
How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...
How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...The Pathway Group
 
Reed_HR_2015_Salary_Guide
Reed_HR_2015_Salary_GuideReed_HR_2015_Salary_Guide
Reed_HR_2015_Salary_GuideSara Lee
 
Festo manage-to-engage-whitepaper
Festo manage-to-engage-whitepaperFesto manage-to-engage-whitepaper
Festo manage-to-engage-whitepaperNicolas VAREILLAS
 
Business Strategy and Skills in New Zealand
Business Strategy and Skills in New ZealandBusiness Strategy and Skills in New Zealand
Business Strategy and Skills in New ZealandWesley Schwalje
 
Inclusion challenges for talent with disabilties
Inclusion challenges for talent with disabiltiesInclusion challenges for talent with disabilties
Inclusion challenges for talent with disabiltiesPhaidon International
 
Trends in employee development for 2020
Trends in employee development for 2020Trends in employee development for 2020
Trends in employee development for 2020House of Skills
 
Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014
Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014
Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014Corporate Spirit Ltd
 
Maximizing the Return on Your Talent Investment
Maximizing the Return on Your Talent InvestmentMaximizing the Return on Your Talent Investment
Maximizing the Return on Your Talent InvestmentBurCom Consulting Ltd.
 

Ähnlich wie A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms (20)

useful
usefuluseful
useful
 
A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...
A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...
A Systematic Review on Importance of Employee Turnover with Special Reference...
 
How Companies Measure Success
How Companies Measure SuccessHow Companies Measure Success
How Companies Measure Success
 
Synopsis of abhishek
Synopsis of abhishekSynopsis of abhishek
Synopsis of abhishek
 
Synopsis of abhishek
Synopsis of abhishekSynopsis of abhishek
Synopsis of abhishek
 
Synopsis of abhishek
Synopsis of abhishekSynopsis of abhishek
Synopsis of abhishek
 
White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)
White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)
White Paper Report - Technology Industry Draft (00000002)
 
Hrm
HrmHrm
Hrm
 
A
AA
A
 
Employee attrition
Employee attritionEmployee attrition
Employee attrition
 
How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...
How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...
How Independent Training Providers (ITPs) can survive and thrive in an inflat...
 
Untapped Human Equity
Untapped Human Equity Untapped Human Equity
Untapped Human Equity
 
Reed_HR_2015_Salary_Guide
Reed_HR_2015_Salary_GuideReed_HR_2015_Salary_Guide
Reed_HR_2015_Salary_Guide
 
The War for Talent
The War for TalentThe War for Talent
The War for Talent
 
Festo manage-to-engage-whitepaper
Festo manage-to-engage-whitepaperFesto manage-to-engage-whitepaper
Festo manage-to-engage-whitepaper
 
Business Strategy and Skills in New Zealand
Business Strategy and Skills in New ZealandBusiness Strategy and Skills in New Zealand
Business Strategy and Skills in New Zealand
 
Inclusion challenges for talent with disabilties
Inclusion challenges for talent with disabiltiesInclusion challenges for talent with disabilties
Inclusion challenges for talent with disabilties
 
Trends in employee development for 2020
Trends in employee development for 2020Trends in employee development for 2020
Trends in employee development for 2020
 
Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014
Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014
Corporate Spirit Newsletter 2/2014
 
Maximizing the Return on Your Talent Investment
Maximizing the Return on Your Talent InvestmentMaximizing the Return on Your Talent Investment
Maximizing the Return on Your Talent Investment
 

Mehr von Wesley Schwalje

Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...Wesley Schwalje
 
Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...
Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...
Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...Wesley Schwalje
 
More Arab Women Studying STEM
More Arab Women Studying STEMMore Arab Women Studying STEM
More Arab Women Studying STEMWesley Schwalje
 
The State of Higher Education in the Middle East
The State of Higher Education in the Middle EastThe State of Higher Education in the Middle East
The State of Higher Education in the Middle EastWesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...Wesley Schwalje
 
Why Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy Now
Why Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy NowWhy Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy Now
Why Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy NowWesley Schwalje
 
Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...
Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...
Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...Wesley Schwalje
 
The Knowledge-based Economy and the Arab Dream: What Happened?
The Knowledge-based Economy and the  Arab Dream:  What Happened?The Knowledge-based Economy and the  Arab Dream:  What Happened?
The Knowledge-based Economy and the Arab Dream: What Happened?Wesley Schwalje
 
Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs and Former Head of the UN Commission on...
Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs  and Former Head of the UN Commission on...Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs  and Former Head of the UN Commission on...
Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs and Former Head of the UN Commission on...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...
Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...
Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...
Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...
Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...
Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...
Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...Wesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global Report
Tahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global ReportTahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global Report
Tahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global ReportWesley Schwalje
 
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...Wesley Schwalje
 
Women Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in Qatar
Women Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in QatarWomen Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in Qatar
Women Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in QatarWesley Schwalje
 

Mehr von Wesley Schwalje (20)

Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje on Regulating the Sharing Economy in the Ar...
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Walid Aradi Discusses the Critical Economic Policy Role ...
 
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Knowledge Economy in the UAE Cited ...
 
Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...
Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...
Kingdom of Saudi Arabia Publishing Industry Analysis: Challenges and Opportun...
 
More Arab Women Studying STEM
More Arab Women Studying STEMMore Arab Women Studying STEM
More Arab Women Studying STEM
 
The State of Higher Education in the Middle East
The State of Higher Education in the Middle EastThe State of Higher Education in the Middle East
The State of Higher Education in the Middle East
 
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...
Tahseen Consulting Analysis on Building a Sustainable Economy in the UAE Cite...
 
Why Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy Now
Why Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy NowWhy Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy Now
Why Qatar Needs a New Technical Vocational Education and Training Strategy Now
 
Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...
Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...
Director General of Emirates Identity Authority Cites Tahseen Consulting’s Wo...
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Leads Panel on Female Retention in the GCC ...
 
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Potential for Dubai’s Growth as an Islam...
 
The Knowledge-based Economy and the Arab Dream: What Happened?
The Knowledge-based Economy and the  Arab Dream:  What Happened?The Knowledge-based Economy and the  Arab Dream:  What Happened?
The Knowledge-based Economy and the Arab Dream: What Happened?
 
Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs and Former Head of the UN Commission on...
Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs  and Former Head of the UN Commission on...Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs  and Former Head of the UN Commission on...
Tunisian Minister of Foreign Affairs and Former Head of the UN Commission on...
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...
Tahseen Consulting’s Wes Schwalje Speaks With Forbes Woman Middle East About ...
 
Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...
Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...
Tahseen Consulting’s National Skills Formation Governance Model Applied to th...
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...
Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...
Tahseen Consulting’s Research on Knowledge Economies Cited by the Nigerian Fe...
 
Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...
Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...
Tahseen Consulting’s Work on Knowledge-based Economies in the Arab Word is Ci...
 
Tahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global Report
Tahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global ReportTahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global Report
Tahseen Consulting Contributes to the 2013 Open Data Barometer Global Report
 
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...
Tahseen Consulting’s CEO Sees Strong Growth Potential for Local Banks in the ...
 
Women Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in Qatar
Women Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in QatarWomen Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in Qatar
Women Wanted: Attracting Women to Technical Fields in Qatar
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen

Creating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature Set
Creating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature SetCreating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature Set
Creating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature SetDenis Gagné
 
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesMysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesDipal Arora
 
Event mailer assignment progress report .pdf
Event mailer assignment progress report .pdfEvent mailer assignment progress report .pdf
Event mailer assignment progress report .pdftbatkhuu1
 
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779Delhi Call girls
 
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSMMonte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSMRavindra Nath Shukla
 
Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...
Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...
Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...anilsa9823
 
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine ServiceCall Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Serviceritikaroy0888
 
Call Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service AvailableCall Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service AvailableDipal Arora
 
RSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors Data
RSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors DataRSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors Data
RSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors DataExhibitors Data
 
The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...
The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...
The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...Aggregage
 
Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...
Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...
Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...lizamodels9
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Dipal Arora
 
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyThe Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyEthan lee
 
HONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael Hawkins
HONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael HawkinsHONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael Hawkins
HONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael HawkinsMichael W. Hawkins
 
Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...
Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...
Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...Roland Driesen
 
0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdf
0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdf0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdf
0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdfRenandantas16
 
9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 Delhi
9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 Delhi9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 Delhi
9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 DelhiCall Girls in Delhi
 
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageInsurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageMatteo Carbone
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen (20)

Creating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature Set
Creating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature SetCreating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature Set
Creating Low-Code Loan Applications using the Trisotech Mortgage Feature Set
 
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best ServicesMysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
Mysore Call Girls 8617370543 WhatsApp Number 24x7 Best Services
 
Event mailer assignment progress report .pdf
Event mailer assignment progress report .pdfEvent mailer assignment progress report .pdf
Event mailer assignment progress report .pdf
 
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779
Best VIP Call Girls Noida Sector 40 Call Me: 8448380779
 
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSMMonte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
Monte Carlo simulation : Simulation using MCSM
 
Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...
Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...
Lucknow 💋 Escorts in Lucknow - 450+ Call Girl Cash Payment 8923113531 Neha Th...
 
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine ServiceCall Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
Call Girls In Panjim North Goa 9971646499 Genuine Service
 
Call Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service AvailableCall Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
Call Girls Pune Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Available
 
RSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors Data
RSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors DataRSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors Data
RSA Conference Exhibitor List 2024 - Exhibitors Data
 
The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...
The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...
The Path to Product Excellence: Avoiding Common Pitfalls and Enhancing Commun...
 
Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...
Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...
Call Girls In Holiday Inn Express Gurugram➥99902@11544 ( Best price)100% Genu...
 
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
Call Girls Navi Mumbai Just Call 9907093804 Top Class Call Girl Service Avail...
 
Forklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
Forklift Operations: Safety through CartoonsForklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
Forklift Operations: Safety through Cartoons
 
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case studyThe Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
The Coffee Bean & Tea Leaf(CBTL), Business strategy case study
 
HONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael Hawkins
HONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael HawkinsHONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael Hawkins
HONOR Veterans Event Keynote by Michael Hawkins
 
Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...
Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...
Boost the utilization of your HCL environment by reevaluating use cases and f...
 
0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdf
0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdf0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdf
0183760ssssssssssssssssssssssssssss00101011 (27).pdf
 
9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 Delhi
9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 Delhi9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 Delhi
9599632723 Top Call Girls in Delhi at your Door Step Available 24x7 Delhi
 
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usageInsurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
Insurers' journeys to build a mastery in the IoT usage
 
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
VVVIP Call Girls In Greater Kailash ➡️ Delhi ➡️ 9999965857 🚀 No Advance 24HRS...
 

A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms

  • 1. A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms Penny Mok, Geoff Mason, Philip Stevens and Jason Timmins Ministry of Economic Development Occasional Paper 12/05 April 2012 ISBN: 978-0-478-38237-2 (PDF) ISBN: 978-0-478-38236-5 (online)
  • 2. Ministry of Economic Development Occasional Paper 12/05 A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms Date: April 2012 Author: Penny Mok Treasury Geoff Mason National Institute of Economic and Social Research, London Philip Stevens Ministry of Economic Development Jason Timmins Department of Labour Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank Belinda Buxton, Rosie Byford, Elizabeth Chisholm, Hilary Devine, Sid Durbin, Richard Fabling, Bette Flagler, Julia Gretton, Hamish Hill, Bill Kaye-Blake, Peter Nunns, Meighan Ragg, Lynda Sanderson, Steven Stillman, Richard White and participants in the Industry Training Federation, the Labour, Employment and Work, the New Zealand Association of Economists, and the New Zealand Centre for SME Research conferences (and others whom we have neglected to mention). We acknowledge two lots of funding from the Cross- Departmental Research Funding for the production of IBULDD (and thence the LBD) and for the Impact of Skills on New Zealand Firms project. Contact: Occasionalpapers@med.govt.nz Disclaimer The views, opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this Occasional Paper are strictly those of the author(s). They do not necessarily reflect the views of the Ministry of Economic Development or the Department of Labour, Treasury or the National Institute of Economics and Social Research. The Ministry takes no responsibility for any errors or omissions in, or for the correctness of, the
  • 3. information contained in these occasional papers. The paper is presented not as policy, but with a view to inform and stimulate wider debate. Access to the data used in this paper was provided by Statistics NZ in accordance with security and confidentiality provisions of the Statistics Act 1975. Only people authorised by the Statistics Act 1975 are allowed to see data about a particular, business or organisation. The results in this paper have been confidentialised to protect individual businesses from identification. The results are based in part on tax data supplied by Inland Revenue to Statistics NZ under the Tax Administration Act 1994. This tax data must be used only for statistical purposes, and no individual information is published or disclosed in any other form, or provided back to Inland Revenue for administrative or regulatory purposes. Any person who had access to the unit-record data has certified that they have been shown, have read and have understood section 81 of the Tax Administration Act 1994, which relates to privacy and confidentiality. Any discussion of data limitations or weaknesses is not related to the data's ability to support Inland Revenue's core operational requirements.
  • 4. Abstract This paper examines the determinants of firms’ skill shortages, using a specially- designed survey, the Business Strategy and Skills (BSS) module of the Business Operations Survey. We combine the BSS module with additional data on firms in the Statistics New Zealand’s prototype Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). We focus on vacancies that were hard-to-fill because the applicants lacked the necessary skills, qualification or experience - which we define as skill-related reasons (skill shortage vacancies). We also contrast these with vacancies that were hard-to- fill for non-skill-related reasons. JEL Classification: J24, J31, L60 Keywords: skill shortages, hard-to-fill vacancies, Business Operations Survey, Heckman Selection model i
  • 5. Executive Summary Skills are an important determinant of the economic performance of people, firms, industries and economies. Shortages of skilled labour directly constrain production and prevent firms from meeting demand and using available inputs efficiently. They inhibit innovation and the use of new technologies. This may have longer-term impacts on the way firms do business, in terms of their location, size, structure, production methods and product strategy. In this paper we have examined factors relating to firms’ skill shortages. Our focus has been on vacancies that were hard-to-fill because the applicants lacked the necessary skills, qualification or experience – what we have defined as ‘skill shortage vacancies’ (SSVs). We have also contrasted these with vacancies that were hard-to- fill for reasons other than the skills of applicants. Worker turnover is a basic fact of economic life. In any given year one in eight workers leaves their employer. Searching for new staff is, therefore, a position most businesses find themselves in, regardless of their situation. Almost half of businesses find some of these vacancies hard-to-fill and more than a third experience difficulties in finding workers with the required skills, qualifications or experience they need. We have examined patterns of skill shortage vacancies using an econometric technique that allows us to account, in part, for the interrelationship between the likelihood of a firm posting a vacancy and for those vacancies being hard-to-fill for skill-related reasons. Large firms are more likely to have vacancies – they have more workers and so the chance of at least one of them leaving is consequently higher. However, larger firms do not appear to find it more difficult to source workers with the required skills than smaller firms, once we account for other characteristics. As we might expect, when firms’ output grows, the need to seek additional staff also grows. However, this is only in the years the firm is expanding. Expanding sales is not a good predictor of future additional staff requirements. Businesses can experience skill shortages internally or externally. A shortage in the skills it requires can manifest itself: (a) in terms of the ability of its existing staff to do ii
  • 6. their job; or (b) in terms of its ability to find appropriately skilled workers through recruitment. We have found evidence that these two phenomena co-exist. Businesses experiencing internal skill gaps are also more-likely to have skill shortage vacancies. We also find evidence of persistence in this relationship; businesses experiencing internal skill gaps are also more likely to have SSVs in the following year. Businesses have a ‘make or buy’ option when it comes to skills. If they cannot source the skills internally or externally, they can up-skill existing or new workers through training. Firms’ training choices are the subject of a companion paper to this (Mason et al., 2012). In this paper, we find that firms who undertake training are more likely to have vacancies, suggesting that their response to skill shortages is likely to be a mixture of recruitment and up-skilling strategies. Our results confirm earlier work that highlights the importance of two distinctions: First, it is important to distinguish between firms’ general recruitment activity and it having skill shortage vacancies. Second, we must distinguish between firms experiencing recruitment difficulties related to skills and those for other reasons (such as the firm not offering good enough pay and conditions). Failing to account for this may cause us to misdiagnose the problem and will therefore undermine the appropriateness of any policy prescription. In any market there will be a number of potential customers that cannot purchase all they would wish because they are unwilling or unable to pay the market price. This does not mean that the market is malfunctioning. There is an important question for researchers and policymakers to ask before interpreting reports of unfilled vacancies of any kind, and of SSVs in particular, as a ‘skills problem’. This question is: Why do businesses that cannot fill a vacancy not simply raise the wages they are offering? There a number of reason why firms may not be able to do so. First, it may be because the firm cannot afford to pay any more. If this is the case, the problem is not the labour market or the education system, but the firm’s own productivity. Firms that that undertake activities associated with high productivity are likely to both have a higher demand for skills and be more able to afford to pay skill premia. Second, the supply of labour takes a long time to adjust. Because of the length of time required to educate and train skilled workers, it takes a long time for changes in iii
  • 7. wages to influence changes in skill acquisition (particularly if we are relying on the rather indirect mechanism of changes in relative wages influencing the choices of students at school) and immigration is restrained by, among other things, legal barriers and the costs of relocation. We have found that the businesses that feel the applicants they are attracting do not have the required skills, qualifications or experience are those that are paying higher wages. The fact that businesses that pay higher wages than others in the same industry and region are actually more likely to experience SSVs suggests that raising wages is not sufficient to fill these vacancies. In contrast, when we focus on vacancies that are hard-to-fill for reasons other than skill, paying higher wages does appear to be a successful policy to fill vacancies. Firms that pay higher relative wages are less likely to have non-skill-related hard-to-fill vacancies. The implication of this is that SSVs and NSRs are different phenomena. One important issue researchers have to confront when undertaking analysis of this type is that of causality. It is one thing to establish a statistical regularity – a correlation between firm characteristics, activities or environment and an outcome such as external skill shortages. It is another thing to interpret this as a causal relationship. In this paper, we have uncovered some clear statistical regularities. These are consistent we with certain predictions we have discussed in this paper and provide us with useful information to aid our understanding of how the landscape of skills in New Zealand and, in particular, we done this from the perspective what businesses are looking for, rather than what the education and training system has provided. iv
  • 8. Table of Contents Abstract ...................................................................................................................... i Executive Summary ................................................................................................. ii Table of Contents ..................................................................................................... v List of Figures ......................................................................................................... vii List of Tables .......................................................................................................... vii 1. Introduction ....................................................................................................... 1 2. Background – Skills and Economic Performance .......................................... 2 2.1. Skills and Firm Performance ........................................................................ 2 2.2. Labour Turnover and Vacancies .................................................................. 5 2.3. Skill Shortages ............................................................................................. 6 2.4. Skills and the Labour Market ........................................................................ 7 2.5. Firm’s Responses to Skill Shortages ............................................................ 8 2.6. Summary .................................................................................................... 10 3. Data and Preliminary Analysis ....................................................................... 12 3.1. Business Operations Survey (BOS) ........................................................... 12 3.2. Vacancies ................................................................................................... 14 3.3. Hard-to-fill vacancies .................................................................................. 16 3.4. Skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies ............................................ 19 3.5. Internal skill gaps........................................................................................ 20 4. Method.............................................................................................................. 21 4.1. Basic econometric model ........................................................................... 22 4.2. Selection equation – The likelihood of vacancies ....................................... 23 4.3. Probability of SSVs..................................................................................... 26 5. Results ............................................................................................................. 30 5.1. Using contemporaneous variables ............................................................. 30 5.2. Using lagged variables ............................................................................... 35 5.3. Skill and non-skill related hard-to-fill vacancies .......................................... 39 6. Summary and Conclusions ............................................................................ 41 References .............................................................................................................. 45 Appendix A1. Data Appendix .............................................................................. 53 A1.1 BOS Variables ............................................................................................ 53 6.1.1. Module A (2005 – 2008) ....................................................................... 53 6.1.2. Module B – Innovation (2007) ............................................................... 54 6.1.3. Module C – Employment Practices (2006) ............................................ 55 6.1.4. Module C – Business Strategy and Skills ............................................. 55 A1.2 LEED/PAYE Data ....................................................................................... 58 A1.3 Other LBD Data (AES, BAI, and IR10) ....................................................... 60 v
  • 9. Appendix A2. Comparison of hard-to-fill vacancies in Module C with recruitment difficulties in Module A ...................................................................... 62 vi
  • 10. List of Figures Figure 1 Skill shortages and Hard-to-fill vacancies in Green et al. (1998) .................. 7 Figure 2 Vacancies, hard-to-fill and skill shortage vacancies ................................... 14 List of Tables Table 1 Vacancies, hard-to-fill, skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies, % .... 15 Table 2 Businesses reporting vacancies, % ............................................................. 16 Table 3 Businesses reporting hard-to-fill vacancies, % ............................................ 17 Table 4 Year-to-year rank correlation between reported recruitment difficulties ....... 19 Table 5 Skill-related reasons for hard-to-fill vacancies, by size ................................ 20 Table 6 Existing staff with skills required to do their job ........................................... 21 Table 7 Principal component factor analysis of business strategy variables ............ 25 Table 8 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances ................................ 25 Table 9 Principal component factor analysis of 2007 business strategy ................... 26 Table 10 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances .............................. 26 Table 11 Principal component factor analysis of census variables ........................... 29 Table 12 Rotated factor analysis .............................................................................. 29 Table 13 Rotated factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances .................. 29 Table 14 Results - SSVs - Contemporaneous variables - Selection equation .......... 32 Table 15 Results – SSVs – Contemporaneous variables – Outcome equation ........ 34 Table 16 Results - SSVs - Lagged variables - Selection equation............................ 36 Table 17 Results - SSVs - Lagged variables - Outcome equation ............................ 38 Table 18 Results – Different definitions of dependent variable ................................. 40 Table 19 Staff occupation/role variables ................................................................... 58 Table 20 Weighted counts of firms reporting levels of difficulty recruiting new staff in Module A by Module C hard-to-fill vacancy response .................................. 63 vii
  • 11. A Good Worker is Hard to Find: Skills Shortages in New Zealand Firms 1. Introduction Skills are an important determinant of the economic performance of people, firms, industries and economies1. Shortages of skilled labour directly constrain production and prevent firms from meeting demand and using available inputs efficiently (Haskel and Martin, 1993a; Stevens, 2007). Indirectly, skill shortages inhibit innovation and the use of new technologies. This may have longer-term impacts on the way firms do business, in terms of their location, size, structure, production methods and product strategy (Mason and Wilson, 2003; Durbin, 2004; Mason, 2005). The success of policies to enable the emergence and performance of successful businesses depends upon having a workforce with the appropriate skills. There are, however, concerns that New Zealand is experiencing a shortage of workers with particular skills2. If New Zealand is to raise productivity and improve its international competitiveness, it is important to understand whether skill shortages do indeed exist, how they manifest themselves and develop policies to address them. In this paper we investigate skill shortages deriving from recruitment difficulties at firm level. That is, vacancies that are hard-to-fill because applicants do not have the 1 See Card (1999) or Dickson and Harmon (2011) for an overview of the results on the individual returns to education and skills, Abowd, Kramarz, Margolis (1999) or Haskel, Hawkes and Periera (2005) for evidence on the relationship between firm performance and skills, Kneller and Stevens (2005) present international evidence for skills at the industry level in OECD economies and Stevens and Weale (2004) or Madsen (2010) discuss evidence on the relationship between education levels and growth. 2 ‘Skills shortage hits agricultural science ‘, Dominion Post, 13/01/12, ‘Half of Kiwi companies facing skill shortages’, NZ Herald, 30/11/11, ‘Academic warns of major skills shortage’, Waikato Times, 4/3/11 1
  • 12. skill, qualifications or experience the business requires. In order to carry out this analysis, we make use of a specially-designed survey, the Business Strategy and Skills (BSS) module of the Business Operations Survey (BOS) 2008. We combine this with information from other sections of the current and previous years’ BOS and data from the prototype Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). The LBD includes information from tax and survey-based financial data, merchandise and services trade data and a variety of sample surveys on business practices and outcomes. This allows us to link the responses of the BSS module to a wealth of information on firms to inform our analysis. The rest of this paper is as follows. In section 2 we discuss some of the issues that influence the interrelationship between the skills of the workforce and the performance of businesses. In section 3 we describe our data and present some descriptive information on New Zealand firms’ experiences of skills. We set out our empirical model in section 4 and our results in section 5. Section 6 concludes. 2. Background – Skills and Economic Performance Human capital (and education in particular) has been found to be an important determinant of economic development and explanator of international differences in aggregate economic growth or productivity (Barro and Sala-i-Martín, 1995; Stevens and Weale, 2004; Kneller and Stevens, 2005; Madsen, 2010). There is a large literature examining the links between the availability of skills and the performance of firms. These range from detailed case studies (see Keep, Mayhew and Corney, 2002, for a summary of those undertaken by the UK National Institute for Economic and Social Research) to econometric analysis using firm-level data and industry level measures of skill shortages (e.g. Haskell and Martin, 1993b, 2001; Haskel, Martin and Periera, 2005; Stevens, 2007). In this section, we consider the importance of skills for firms, how labour markets match the skills of workers to their uses in firms, and how firms respond to skills shortages. We also consider what we mean by a ‘skill shortage’. Can such a thing exist in a well-functioning economy? 2.1. Skills and Firm Performance There are essentially two elements to the link between skills and firm performance. First, skills represent a basic input into the firm’s production technology. Individuals 2
  • 13. with higher skills have more human capital and so produce greater output. There is a large literature that consistently finds positive private and social returns to skill and education in particular (Card, 1999; Psacharopoulos and Patrinos, 2004; McMahon, 2004). Higher skill levels do not only increase firm productivity through the direct impact on the worker’s own productivity. They also create synergies with other productive inputs, such as other workers, physical and knowledge capital, R&D or new technologies. An obvious example of how skills enhance the performance of other workers is the skills of managers, who organise and shape production. The quality of management in businesses is an important predictor of business performance across a number of dimensions in many countries (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007, 2010; 2011), including New Zealand (UTS, 2009). Another way skilled labour increases the productivity of other workers is through what are known as ‘knowledge spillovers’ (Arrow, 1962; Battu, Belfield and Sloane, 2004; Audretsch and Feldman, 2004). Spillovers occur when other workers pick up these skills through observation, interaction or tuition. These spillovers can occur within the firm and across the boundaries of the firms through direct relationships (i.e. with suppliers and customers) or through geographic proximity (Glaeser, Kallal, Scheinkman and Shleifer, 1992; Audretsch and Feldman, 2004). For a long time it has been suggested that skilled labour is more complementary with capital than unskilled labour (Griliches, 1969; Duffy, Papageorgiou, and Perez- Sebastian, 2004). Many capital goods (e.g. computers) require skills to operate (Autor, Katz and Krueger, 1998; Morrison-Paul and Siegel, 2001; Falk, 2004). Autor, Levy and Murname (2003) found that over three decades, computer capital has replaced workers undertaking routine or repetitive manual and cognitive tasks and complemented those doing non-routine problem-solving and communications tasks. As well as physical capital, higher skill levels enable a workforce to deal with the current technology and, moreover, they enable the firm to better adapt to new technology (Machin and Van Reenen, 1998). For economists, technology is taken generally to include the means whereby inputs are brought together to produce outputs, including organisational and product strategy. Mason (2005) found that the 3
  • 14. ability of firms in a number of industries to execute ‘high value’ business strategies was contingent on the skills of their workforce. Work such as Abowd, Haltiwanger, Lane McKinney and Sandusky (2007) finds a strong positive empirical relationship between advanced technology and skill. Skills are required not only for the creation of new technology, but also both for its dispersion and implementation (Rosenberg, 1972; Lane and Lubatkin, 1998; Hall and Khan, 2003; Kneller and Stevens, 2006). Investing in skills Both workers and firms have an incentive to increase productivity through investing in skills, but their incentives are different. Individuals have an incentive to invest in skill formation because this enables them to function better in the economy and society. Crucially, they provide the basis for them to earn an income. Firms also have an incentive to increase the skills of their workforce because this enables them to perform more tasks or increase the productiveness with which they perform existing tasks. Because the skills embedded in workers can be increased by investing in them, economists use the term ‘human capital’. Firms do not have the incentive to invest in all types of human capital equally. General human capital is of value to all employers, whereas specific human capital is valuable only to specific firms or groups of firms (Becker, 1962, 1994; Stevens, 1994) 3 . Firms will tend to under-provide training of all skills that have some generality to them (i.e. they are of use to other firms) because of the risks of staff leaving or being poached; there is a risk that they will pay the costs and other firms will get the benefits. Because they may not reap all of the rewards – staff may move elsewhere or be poached by other firms – firms may invest less in such training that would be socially optimal4. The likelihood of staff using recently acquired human capital by moving elsewhere will depend of the outside options they have, in particular the wages on offer. 3 The specificity of skills may in also be determined by the structure of the market. Acemoglu and Pischke (1999) argue that certain skills might be potentially useful to other firms (i.e. general) may become specific because of market imperfections. For example, if there were only one producer in a sector a particular skill might only be of use to them, whereas if a number of firms were operating in the same area they could be competing for the same labour. 4 Both firms and individuals may under invest in skills and education if there are externalities. This might include agglomeration benefits (such as knowledge dispersion), matching externalities, benefits in terms of lower crime, higher levels of political engagement and health. 4
  • 15. This is where labour differs from other factors of production. It is not tied to the firm, beyond the terms of its contractual relationship. It can decide to take its skill and use them elsewhere. 2.2. Labour Turnover and Vacancies Labour turnover is a basic fact of economic life (Davis, Halitwanger and Schuh, 1996; Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger, 2006, 2010). For example, from the September to the December quarter of 2010, total employment in New Zealand expanded from 1,777,110 to 1,810,580, an increase of 33,4705. This change was dwarfed by the almost half a million workers either leaving or starting jobs from which it resulted. Because of the dynamic nature of the labour market, we must be careful not to equate vacancies with job creation. Firms can have positive values for both hires and separations (Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger, 2006). In the December 2010 quarter, 12.7% of workers in New Zealand became separated from their jobs6. This is not merely due to firms shrinking (what is called ‘job destruction’). The total job destruction in the December 2010 quarter was 90,890 – barely two-fifths of the total worker separations. Firms will post vacancies for two reasons: First, to replace staff who have quit, retired or been fired; Second, to fill new roles that have been created by the expansion of the firm. These two sources of vacancies are likely to have different causes. Voluntary separations may be higher in good times (as the likelihood of alternative employment increases), but involuntary separations may be lower (as firms seek to reduce employment) (Pissarides, 2000). New roles are more likely to be created when a firm is expanding7. Given this discussion, we might reasonably expect the number of vacancies generally increase with the number of employees. However, some work has found vacancy rates to decline with firms size (e.g. Holtz, 1994). Note that our discussion relates to vacancy rates. Our data is a binary variable stating whether or not a firm posts a vacancy. We would generally expect 5 Source: Statistics New Zealand Linked-Employer Employee Database. Data downloaded from: http://www.stats.govt.nz/tools_and_services/tools/TableBuilder/leed-quarterly-tables.aspx 6 Source: Authors’ calculations based on LEED data. This separation rate is calculated as ‘Worker separations’ in the December 2010 quarter divided by the average of ‘Total filled jobs’ in the December and September quarters. 7 For a textbook description of the standard dynamic model of labour demand, see Nickell (1996). 5
  • 16. phenomena that increase the numbers or rate of vacancies to also increase the probability of the firm reporting at least vacancy. 2.3. Skill Shortages The primary focus of this paper is on difficulties firms face in filling roles for reasons related to the qualifications or experience of applicants – what we call skill shortage vacancies. However, this is not the only way in which skill shortages can manifest. Much early work in this area did not distinguish between the types of skill shortage. It focussed on ‘skill shortages’ as a whole and their impacts. This was driven in part by the data that were available to researchers. For example, in the UK, the Confederation of British Industry has collected information on whether firms output was limited by shortages of skilled labour since the early 1970s8. However, it has become clear that it is important to distinguish between shortages of skills in existing workers and shortages of staff in the labour market with appropriate skills (Green, Machin and Wilkinson, 1998; Mason and Wilson, 2003). These have been called ‘internal skill gaps’ and ‘external skill gaps’, respectively (e.g. Forth and Mason, 2004)9. The primary focus of this paper is on external skill gaps. When examining external skill gaps, it is important to be clear what we are measuring. As Green et al., (1998) point out, we must be careful not to simply equate them with vacancies that are hard-to-fill. As we shall see in section 3.3, there are many reasons why vacancies may be hard-to-fill. These reasons range from the conditions of work to the fact that firms are simply not paying the market wage; not all of them are skill-related. Because of this, authors such as Mason and Stevens (2003) have focussed on the subset of vacancies that are hard-to-fill for skill-related reasons; specifically, by examining the reasons for vacancies being hard-to-fill and only considering those that relate to a lack of qualifications and/or experience in applicants. This is the approach that informed the design of the relevant sections of the Business Strategy and Skills module of the BOS 2008, and one that underlies our analysis in this paper. 8 This data has been used as an industry-level measure of shortages of skilled workers by Haskel and Martin (1993a), (1993b) and Stevens (2007). 9 Although, others have called skills deficiencies relating to the external labour market ‘skills shortages’ and those applicable to a firm’s existing workforce ‘skills gaps’ (Schwalje, 2011). 6
  • 17. We summarise the thinking on the various skill shortage concepts in Figure 1. Skill shortages can be internal to the firm, what we call internal skill gaps (ISG), or external, what we call skill shortage vacancies (SSV)10. As well as SSVs, vacancies can be hard-to-fill for other reasons, what we call non-skill related vacancies (NSR). Figure 1 Skill shortages and Hard-to-fill vacancies in Green et al. (1998) Skill shortages Hard-to-fill vacancies ISG SSV NSR  ISG = Internal Skill Gap; SSV = Skill Shortage Vacancy; NSR = Non-Skill-Related vacancy In order to understand why firms might find it difficult to source skilled labour, we need to consider the wider labour market. We turn our attention to this next. 2.4. Skills and the Labour Market Modern theories of labour markets are based around the ability of the market to match individuals to jobs (Pissarides, 2000; Petrongolo, and Pissarides, 2001; Mortensen, 2005). Trading in the labour market is not without cost. It takes time and money for businesses to advertise for and assess potential employees. It takes time and money for workers to search and apply for potential employment. We call these ‘search costs’. Furthermore, costs are incurred when incoming workers start in a new role; workers need to learn the specific tasks involved in the role and the 10 Of course some external skill gaps may not manifest themselves as SSVs because the firm may not bother to post vacancies they know they cannot fill. 7
  • 18. employer has to learn about the specific abilities of their new employee11. Another cost is the time a worker or a firm stays in a state awaiting a ‘good’ match. Workers stay in less-preferable jobs or quit to unemployment while they wait for a better offer to come along. Firms either allocate a worker who is less aptly skilled to a role, or hold it open until the ‘right’ worker comes along. We call these ‘mismatch costs’. Average search costs and mismatch costs are likely to be lower in larger labour markets; the more jobs and workers there are, the more likely it is that a good match will exist. Thus, businesses and workers operating in big cities, for example, will benefit from lower search costs, ceteris paribus. In part because of this, they are less likely to be stuck in ‘bad’ worker-job matches (as the cost of exiting a low productivity match is much lower). These ‘thick labour market agglomeration benefits’ can also come from co-location of economic activity with similar demand for skills; whilst there is more competition between firms for skilled labour, there will also be a greater supply (as workers with the appropriate skills are attracted to the area). Larger markets will be driven less by market frictions and more by the fundamental economic determinants of the productivity of the match (i.e. those that determine the productivity of the firm, the productivity of the worker and their complementarity). Firms’ ability to recruit and retain skilled staff will depend on local labour market conditions. These are typically summarised using the local unemployment rates or proportions of the population with particular qualifications (e.g. Mason and Stevens, 2003). The firm’s ability to recruit new staff will also be affected by the ‘outside wage’. The opportunity cost of taking up a job at the firm for the worker is the value of the next best potential offer foregone. This will depend on the distribution of job offers and associated wages. These can be measured by average wage in similar jobs – for example other jobs in that industry and/or region. 2.5. Firm’s Responses to Skill Shortages How firms respond to labour market conditions will affect their performance. This is part of how firms compete. The obvious question to ask if a business cannot fill a vacancy is: ‘why don’t they just pay more?’ Here we discuss two reasons why this may not be possible. First, it may be because the firm cannot afford to pay any more. 11 For more on the training of incoming staff by New Zealand firms, see the companion paper to this (Timmins, et al., 2012). 8
  • 19. In this case, the problem is not the labour market, but the firm’s own productivity. Firms that that undertake activities associated with high productivity may well both have a higher demand for skills but also be more able to afford to pay skill premia. Firms with some degree of market power may not be more productive, but will be able to compete more aggressively for scarce inputs such as skilled staff. Second, the supply of labour takes a long time to adjust; it takes a long time for changes in wages to influence changes in skill acquisition (particularly if we are relying on the rather indirect mechanism of changes in relative wages influencing the choices of students at school) and immigration is restrained by, among other things, legal barriers and the costs of relocation. In an early study of apparent shortages of engineers and scientists, Arrow and Capron (1959) defined a skill shortage as ‘a situation in which there are unfilled vacancies in positions where salaries are the same as those currently being paid in others of the same type and quality’ (1959: 301). Although they recognised that excess demand for skills in competitive labour markets should put upward pressure on salaries, Arrow and Capron suggested that, even in a competitive labour market, a steady increase in demand over time for skilled workers could produce a ‘dynamic shortage’ if there were factors impeding rapid salary increases by employers such as delays in accepting the needs for such increases, the further time needed to implement them and a reluctance to incur increased salary costs for existing high- skilled employees as well as new ones. At the same time supply responses to any salary improvements could be slowed down by the length of time required to educate and train skilled workers, as shown by Freeman (1971, 1976) in the case of engineers and scientists. Later studies have recognised that firms have a range of potential non-salary responses and ‘coping mechanisms’ available to them when confronted by shortfalls in skills – such as asking existing employees to work longer hours, making increased use of subcontractors or retraining existing staff to develop the skills in shortage. In a study based on data from the 1984 Workplace Industrial Relations Survey in the UK, Haskel and Martin (1993b) found no evidence of firms setting higher wages in response to difficulties in recruiting skilled workers. Indeed, they cited other UK survey evidence to suggest that salary responses were much less important than other means of addressing skilled recruitment difficulties. 9
  • 20. Increased training provision is a potentially important non-salary response to external skill shortages which, like salary increases, should help alleviate the shortages in question rather than just help firms to cope with them12. However, just as some firms may elect to ‘live with’ external skill shortages for periods of time rather than incur the costs of raising salaries for new recruits with knock-on effects on existing salary differentials, some may also be reluctant to respond immediately to skill shortages by increasing training provision for existing workers. Such reluctance could reflect imperfect information about the costs and benefits of training versus other potential responses to skill shortages. But economic theory also points to other possible explanations for variation between firms in the extent and speed of training responses to different kinds of skill shortage. For example, Stevens (2007) suggests that the speed of firms’ adjustment behaviour is likely to vary inversely with the degree of competition in their particular labour markets for skills specific to their industries. More generally, resource- and knowledge-based theories of the firm suggest that heterogeneity of firms’ training responses to external skill shortages is to be expected. This is because the ability of any firm to provide training will be strongly conditioned by the specific resources and capabilities (such as management skills and training capacity) which it has accumulated over time (Teece, Pisano and Shuen, 1997; Eisenhardt and Martin, 2001; Teece, 2007). 2.6. Summary This brief overview of the literature suggests a number of avenues for us to pursue in our analysis. First, we need to differentiate between firms’ general recruitment activity and it having skill shortage vacancies. Labour turnover is a basic fact of economic life. Fast-growing and large firms will be more likely to be seeking additional staff. Second, we need to distinguish between firms experiencing recruitment difficulties because of the availability of labour with the appropriate skills and those for other reasons, such as the firm merely not offering good enough pay and conditions. Failing to account for this may cause us to misdiagnose the problem and will therefore undermine the appropriateness of any policy prescription. In any 12 We examine the relationship between training and skill shortages in more detail in Mason, Mok, Stevens and Timmins, (2012). 10
  • 21. market there will be a number of potential customers that cannot purchase all they would wish because they are unwilling or unable to pay the market price. Our quick survey of the literature suggests a number of patterns we might expect to see, or hypotheses we might test: Firms are more likely to suffer SSVs the greater the proportion of higher skilled staff they are looking for. Firms operating in tighter local labour markets will find it more difficult to fill roles. Firms with high-productivity strategies will have a higher demand for skills, but will be more able to pay skill premia. Firms with a degree of market power are likely to be more able to pay skill premia relative to their competitors. From a policy perspective, we wish to know whether these skill shortages are ‘real’ or not. In any market, there will always be potential buyers who would wish to buy more, but are unwilling to do so at the current price. We know that labour markets do adjust supply to meet demand instantaneously; in the short run, the labour supply curve is likely to be almost vertical13. Thus, a positive shock to demand (caused, for example, by a firm getting a large export order) is not likely to create an instantaneous increase in the supply of labour. In the short run, the effect may only be to increase wage inflation, as the firm outbids its competitors. In some cases the firm may source skilled workers internationally, but this takes time and resources. This suggests two alternative hypotheses, one for a labour market with some slack and one where the supply of labour is tight. If the market is working satisfactorily, firms that offer higher wages will be less likely to experience SSVs. If there are shortages of skilled labour and the firms with the highest demand for skills are those that are the most productive, it may be the firms that pay the highest wages that have SSVs. As we shall see below, because we only have a cross-section of data relating to SSVs, it is likely to be difficult to distinguish some of these phenomena. Nevertheless, we shall examine both the contemporaneous relationship and that between current SSVs and previous years’ firm characteristics. 13 there may of course be some economically inactive workers that are on the margins of entering the labour market, such as single parents for whom the costs of childcare may raise the reservation wage higher than their contemporaries 11
  • 22. 3. Data and Preliminary Analysis The data come from Statistics New Zealand’s prototype Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). The LBD is built around the Longitudinal Business Frame (LBF), to which are attached, among other things, Goods and Services Tax (GST) returns, financial accounts (IR10) and aggregated Pay-As-You-Earn (PAYE) returns, all provided by the Inland Revenue Department (IRD). The full LBD is described in more detail in Fabling, Grimes, Sanderson and Stevens (2008) and Fabling (2009). The survey data considered in this chapter relate to the Business Operations Survey (BOS). The administrative data we use have four sources: the Linked Employer Employee Database (LEED), the Business Activity Indicator (BAI) dataset of GST returns, the Annual Enterprise Survey (AES) and IR10 forms. These are described in more detail in the Data Appendix. 3.1. Business Operations Survey (BOS) The Business Operation Survey (BOS) is an annual three part modular survey, which began in 2005. The first module is focussed on firm characteristics and performance. The second module alternates between biennial innovation and business use of ICT collections. The third module is a contestable module that enables specific policy- relevant data to be collected on an ad hoc basis14. The BOS is conducted using two- way stratified sampling, with stratification on rolling-mean-employment (RME) and two-digit industry according to the ANZSIC system15. The survey excludes firms with fewer than six RME and firms in the following industries: M81 Government Administration, M82 Defence, P92 Libraries, Museums and the Arts, Q95 Personal Services, Q96 Other Services, and Q97 Private Households Employing Staff. The 2008 survey achieved an 81.1% response rate (after adjusting for ceases), a total of 5,543 usable responses, representing a population of 36,075 firms. The BOS is something approaching best practice in such surveys internationally. It has removed replication of surveys16 – and thus reduces respondent load and makes 14 In 2005 and 2009 this was a ‘Business Practices Module’ and in 2006 an ‘Employment Practices Survey’. The 2007 module was on ‘International Engagement’. 15 Note that there was some minor additional stratification conducted at the three-digit level. 16 Prior to the BOS, surveys tended to occur on a fairly ad hoc basis – one assumes when policy- makers were considering a particular issue. Thus there was a Business Practices Survey in 2001, an 12
  • 23. sampling simpler. It is explicitly designed with a panel element; enabling more sophisticated analysis to be undertaken allowing us to better understand issues of causality and – as the panel element increases – dynamic issues17. We do not use SNZ-imputed values in cases of item non-response where it is impossible to obtain them by simple edit rules (e.g. more than one expenditure categories are missing). When we discuss questions from the BOS, we shall denote the question by their module followed by their question number. So, for example, question 15 of Module C is denoted C15. When there are multiple categories of response in the same question (e.g. the different occupational groups in question C18, we use the code included on the form (e.g. C1801). Question numbers will relate to the 2008 BOS, unless otherwise specified. The ‘Business Strategy and Skills’ (BSS) Module The Business Strategy and Skills (BSS) module of the 2008 Business Operations Survey was produced as part of the ‘Impact of Skills on New Zealand Firms’ project. This project involved the Ministry of Economic Development, the Department of Labour, New Zealand Treasury and the Ministry of Research, Science and Technology and was partly funded by the Cross Departmental Research Pool. The module was designed by the project team in conjunction with Statistics New Zealand and Geoff Mason, from the National Institute of Economic and Social Research in London. In this section we consider all firms that report vacancies of any kind and focus in on hard-to-fill vacancies and what we call skill shortage vacancies (SSV). The skill shortage vacancies are defined as vacancies that were hard-to-fill because the applicants lacked the necessary skills, qualification or experience, which is a subset of hard-to-fill vacancies. As there are other reasons for having hard-to-fill vacancies, this allows us to distinguish the non-skill-related vacancies from the skill shortage vacancies. Innovation Survey in 2003 and a Business Finance Survey in (2004). Elements of each of these are considered either every year as part of the Business Performance Module (Module A) or every two or more years (i.e. the Innovation Module is run every other year and the Business Practices Module was run in 2005 and is scheduled to repeat in 2009). 17 The panel element is in fact larger than it first seems as there is considerable overlap with previous surveys, such as the 2001 Business Practices Survey (Fabling, 2007). 13
  • 24. The overall percentages of firms reporting each type of vacancy are depicted as concentric circles in Figure 2. More detail on the construction and patterns of our measures of vacancies, skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies are set out in the following sections. Figure 2 Vacancies, hard-to-fill and skill shortage vacancies Skill shortage vacancies (36%) Hard-to-fill vacancies (49%) Vacancies (77%)  Figure shows the percentage of firms that report each type of vacancy  Figures based in sample strata and weights  Note that figures for the percentage of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample and (b) we do not use imputed values 3.2. Vacancies Respondents were asked: ‘During the last financial year, has this business had any vacancies?’ (C14). The first row of Table 1 summarises these data. We shall return to this table when we discuss hard-to-fill and skill shortage vacancies below. Overall, 76.6% of firms reported that they had posted a vacancy. As one might expect (given the greater number of employees), the likelihood of posting a vacancy increases with firm size. 14
  • 25. Table 1 Vacancies, hard-to-fill, skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies, % Business size Overall E <20* 20≤E<50 50≤E<100 E≥100 Vacancies 71.8 89.5 93.6 95.2 76.6 Hard-to-fill Vacancies 44.2 58.8 65.2 73.4 48.7 Skill Shortage Vacancies 32.1 43.1 48.6 58.6 35.7  Table shows percentage of firms reporting each type of vacancy  Figures based in sample strata and weights  Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.  Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business population with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data Appendix.  Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year, rather than 2007. We can break the reporting of vacancies down by occupation. Respondents that reported they had posted vacancies in the last year were asked a follow-up question: ‘During the last financial year, how many vacancies has this business had for the following roles?’ (C15). The responses to this question are set out in Table 2. It is for ‘clerical, sales and services workers’ that the greatest proportion of firms had vacancies, followed by ‘labourers, production, transport or other workers’. This reflects the greater number of staff in these occupations 18. This is not quite true across all firm sizes. ‘Managers’ is the second most popular category for firms with more than one hundred employees (and also, marginally, for those with between 50 and 99 employees). 18 See Figure 6 of Stevens (2012) 15
  • 26. Table 2 Businesses reporting vacancies, % Business size Overall E<20* 20≤E<50 50≤E<100 E≥100 Managers 10.2 23.2 40.1 62.4 15.8 Professionals 11.5 19.1 29.1 42.6 14.8 Technicians and associate profs 8.7 19.3 25.7 38.5 12.4 Tradespersons and rel. workers 20.4 25.5 27.5 36.3 22.1 Clerical sales and service workers 28.6 45.2 58.7 72.8 34.5 Labourers, production, transport or 26.2 41.1 47.3 53.3 30.7 other workers All occupations 68.5 86.1 89.4 88.0 73.1  Table presents data from questions C14: ‘During the last financial year, has this business had any vacancies?’ and C15: ‘During the last financial year, how many vacancies has this business had for the following roles?’  Table shows percentage of firms reporting each type of vacancy  Figure for ‘all occupations’ does not match that for Table 1 because some firms do not report the occupations of their vacancies  Figures based in sample strata and weights  Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.  * Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business population with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data Appendix.  Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year, rather than 2007. 3.3. Hard-to-fill vacancies Respondents were asked: ‘During the last financial year, was this business easily able to fill all vacancies with suitable applicants?’ (C16). Those who answered ‘no’ to this question were classified as having a hard-to-fill vacancy. The second row of Table 1 (repeated at the bottom of Table 3) summarises these data. Well over half of the firms that have vacancies find them hard-to-fill (47.9% compared to 76.6%). Again, the probability of having a hard-to-fill vacancy increases with firm size, with almost three-quarters of firms with rolling mean employment of one hundred or more having hard-to-fill vacancies. 16
  • 27. Table 3 Businesses reporting hard-to-fill vacancies, % Business size Overall E<20* 20≤E<50 50≤E<100 E≥100 Managers 4.9 10.1 16.7 29.4 7.2 Professionals 7.1 11.6 16.1 24.8 9.0 Technicians and associate profs 4.6 8.4 11.3 19.4 6.1 Tradespersons and related workers 13.7 16.3 15.1 19.8 14.4 Clerical sales and service workers 10.2 14.2 18.1 24.6 11.8 Labourers, production, transport or other workers 12.3 17.6 19.9 22.9 13.9 All occupations 44.2 58.8 65.4 73.6 48.7  Table presents data from questions C16 ‘During this last financial year, was this business easily able to fill all vacancies with suitable applicants?’ and C18: ‘Mark all that apply/ for this business, which roles were hard-to- fill?’  Table shows percentage of firms reporting each type of vacancy  Figure for ‘all occupations’ does not match that for Table 1 because some firms do not report the occupations of their hard-to-fill vacancies  Figures based in sample strata and weights  Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.  Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business population with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data Appendix.  Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year, rather than 2007. Respondents that reported that they found some vacancies hard-to-fill were asked: ‘For this business, which roles were hard-to-fill?’ (C18). ‘Tradespersons and related workers’ were the occupations with which most businesses had recruitment difficulties (Table 3). This reflects a more even spread of hard-to-fill vacancies by firm size and hence the influence of the greater number of small (6-19 employees) firms. ‘Managers’ were the role for which most large (100+) firms found difficult to fill vacancies. Given that managers represent a relatively small proportion of total staff, and one that has an important impact on firm performance (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007, 2010; UTS, 2010), this is a worrying result. Comparison with Recruitment Difficulties in Module A In order to place these figures in context, it is useful to compare these results with the responses to a similar question that is asked in Module A. In a section on employment, firms are asked ‘Over the last financial year, to what extent did this business experience difficulty in recruiting new staff for any of the following 17
  • 28. occupational groups?’ (A33). The different language used in module C (vacancy plus hard-to-fill vacancy) and Module A (‘difficulty in recruitment’), differences in the response categories and the influence of previous questions mean that these are not identical19. The results of such a comparison are presented in Appendix A2. In summary, there is a high degree of correlation between the two measures, but that this is not total. The majority of respondents that said they had a severe difficulty in recruiting each type of staff in Module A said that vacancies were hard-to-fill in Module C. The Persistence of Recruitment Difficulties Notwithstanding the differences between the Module A recruitment difficulties variables and the Module C hard-to-fill vacancies variable, we can use the Module A question to consider the persistence of recruitment difficulties. In order to prevent us becoming overwhelmed with tables, we focus on the year-to-year rank correlations between the responses to the recruitment difficulty question (A33) for the 2005, 2006, 2007 and 2008 surveys. As we can see from Table 4, the correlations are both high and significant. Interestingly, whilst the correlation does decline over time, this decline is not very steep. There may be a number of reasons for this. One might be that firms with recruitment difficulties are more likely to have had them in the past, but not necessarily every year. Another may be a function of the attrition in the survey, as firms enter and leave. Whatever the reasons for the particular pattern, there is clearly considerable persistence in the existence of recruitment difficulties. We shall consider the predictive power of previous recruitment difficulties for the probability of the firm posting a vacancy in our econometric analysis in the following section. 19 For more on the subject of how respondents interpret and answer questions in business surveys, with particular reference to the BOS, see Fabling, Grimes and Stevens (2008, 2012). 18
  • 29. Table 4 Year-to-year rank correlation between reported recruitment difficulties 2005 2006 2007 2008 2005 2006 2007 2008 Managers and professionals Tradesmen and related occupations 2006 0.5836*** 1 0.4827*** 1 (0.0000) (0.0000) 2007 0.4522*** 0.5402*** 1 0.4506*** 0.4592*** 1 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) 2008 0.5151*** 0.5225*** 0.5450*** 1 0.3668*** 0.4462*** 0.6254*** 1 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) Technicians and assistant professionals Other occupations *** 2006 0.4534 1 0.3357*** 1 (0.0000) (0.0000) 2007 0.4225*** 0.5687*** 1 0.3105*** 0.3874*** 1 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) 2008 0.4161*** 0.4183*** 0.6455*** 1 0.3011*** 0.3362*** 0.4067*** 1 (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000)  p value in parenthesis  * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 3.4. Skill and non-skill-related shortage vacancies Respondents that had hard-to-fill vacancies were asked ‘For which of the following reasons did this business find it hard-to-fill vacancies?’ (question C17). They were given twelve categories, from which they could choose as many as they wished. Those that replied ‘applicants lack the work experience the business demands’ or ‘applicants lack the qualifications or skills the business demands’ were defined as having skill shortage vacancies (SSVs) 20 . Around the same numbers of firms reported each of these reasons across all firm sizes (Table 5). However, only around half of businesses that reported that applicants lacked appropriate experience also reported that they lacked the appropriate qualifications or skills (and vice versa). Thus, we should be careful as considering these two explanations as synonymous. Table 5 shows that there are attributes workers obtain through their on-the-job experience that businesses value over and above qualifications and, in particular, separate from the things that they call ‘skills’. It may be that experience connotes a depth of skill rather than merely its presence. 20 For the full list of responses, see SNZ (2008). 19
  • 30. Table 5 Skill-related reasons for hard-to-fill vacancies, by size Business Size RME 20 ≤ RME 50 ≤ RME 100+ Total <20 <50 <100 RME Applicants lack work experience the 25.4 34.7 37.9 48.1 28.4 business demands Applicants lack qualifications or skills 25.1 35.2 38.3 47.5 28.2 the business demands Lack either qualifications or work 13.7 16.2 20.9 21.8 14.7 experience Lack both qualifications and work 18.4 26.8 27.7 36.8 20.9 experience  Table presents data from questions C17 ‘For which of the following reasons did this business find it hard-to-fill vacancies?’  Table shows percentage of firms reporting each response  Figures based in sample strata and weights  Business size (E) is measured by rolling mean employment, or RME.  Note that the figure for business size being fewer than 20 RME is not all firms in the total business population with fewer than 20 RME, but rather firms in the BOS sample. For more on these see the Data Appendix.  Note that figures for number of businesses with vacancies and hard-to-fill vacancies will not match the tables in the Statistics New Zealand Hot of the Press release because: (a) we use a slightly different sample; (b) we do not use imputed values; and (c) we use rolling mean employment (RME) from the 2008 financial year, rather than 2007. Firms that replied having other reasons besides ‘applicants lack the work experience the business demands’ or ‘applicants lack the qualifications or skills the business demands’ were defined as having non-skill-related shortage vacancies (NSR). We shall use this information allows us to better understand what is unique about skill- shortage vacancies than other recruitment difficulties that would have different implications for policy. 3.5. Internal skill gaps In this section, we explore the internal skill gaps from the BOS 2008 and skill improvement needs obtained from the computer-aided telephone interview (CATI). From the BOS, respondents were asked ‘How many of this business’s existing staff have the skills required to do their job?’ for 6 given occupation groups of managers; professionals; technicians and associate professionals; tradespersons and related workers; clerical, sales and service workers; and labourer, production, transport or other workers. Respondents were further asked the reasons for their staff not having the skills required. Table 6 shows that more than half of the firms have all their managers and clerical, sales and service workers with skills required. Internal skill 20
  • 31. gaps are more prominent for less skilled workers, such as clerical, sales and service workers and labourers, production, transport and other workers. Table 6 Existing staff with skills required to do their job Proportion of staff with skills (%) Occupation Less than half Half or more All staff Managers 9.8 11.7 78.5 Professionals 4.4 7.3 37.7 Technicians and associate professionals 3.3 9.0 33.0 Tradespersons and related workers 4.4 16.1 32.4 Clerical, sales and service workers 4.4 20.3 60.6 Labourers, production, transport and others 4.2 19.0 36.6  Table presents data from questions C20 ‘How many of this business’s existing staff have the skills required to do their job?’  Source: SNZ (2009)  Note that the percentages in this table are taken from ‘SNZ (2009) and are not exactly comparable with the Table 1 and Table 2 and Figure 2. For more on this, see the footnotes to Table 1 and Table 2. 4. Method In this section we outline our empirical strategy. First we set out our basic econometric model. This is a two stage, ‘Heckman selection’ model, where we allow for the interrelationship between the firm’s decision to look for staff externally and post a vacancy and the probability that these vacancies prove to be hard-to-fill for skill-related reasons.21 In the following two sections we consider the variables included in each stage of the model. One of the key issues we face is that we only have one year of information on our dependent variable, so our model is essentially a cross-sectional model. This makes interpreting coefficients as causal relationships, rather than merely uncovering statistically significant correlations, difficult. This is a problem faced by many studies of this nature (e.g. Mason and Stevens, 2003). We seek to overcome (or at least mitigate) this by using the fact that the Business Operations Survey is embedded in the prototype Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). We use additional data from 21 An earlier version of this paper (Mason et al., 2010), shows the importance of accounting for the relationship between in this way. In unpublished work we also considered using multinomial logit and bivariate probit models, but concluded that these were not appropriate also. 21
  • 32. previous years’ BOS and information on the firm we have from other sources, specifically tax and survey data. Another important issue to bear in mind is the fact that the unit of observation in our empirical analysis is the firm (in LBD parlance, the enterprise). Thus, when we estimate the probability of a skill shortage vacancy, we are estimating the probability of a firm with a vacancy having at least one that is hard-to-fill for skill-related reasons. We are not estimating the probability of a particular vacancy being hard-to-fill for skill related reasons. For this we would need vacancy-level information. Our focus is on the impact on firms rather than on individual vacancies. Finally, in order to aid interpretation, we also supplement our analysis of SSVs by considering different specifications of our dependent variable (whether the firm has an SSV): we investigate specifications where the outcome is restricted to firms that have SSV only (i.e. not for other reasons) 4.1. Basic econometric model The primary model we estimate is the probability of reporting skill shortage vacancies accounting for sample selection. We model the first stage (the selection equation) as being the probability of reporting having posted a vacancy. The second stage is the probability that a firm with vacancies finds at least one of them hard-to-fill for reasons of skill. We also investigate different outcomes in the second stage equations (i.e. non-skill-related hard-to-fill vacancies and various variations on the SSV/NSR theme). The discussion of method that follows, however, focuses on the model for SSVs, to keep the exposition clear. We suppose that the propensity of firm i to post a skill shortage vacancy can be expressed as (1) SSVi   X i    1i  where SSV* is the propensity to have a skill shortage vacancy, Xi is a (1×k) vector of k explanatory variables,  is a (k×1) vector of parameters to be estimated and  i an error term. We do not observe the SSV* terms, but the binary realisation of them. Therefore we assume: 22
  • 33. SSVi  0 if SSVi   0 (2) SSVi  1 if SSVi   0 This variable SSVi takes one of three values. If the firm reports a skill shortage, SSV takes the value of 1. It takes the value zero if the firm does not have a skill shortage vacancy, but does have a vacancy. It takes a missing value when the firm does not have any vacancies. The dependent variable in (2) for observation i is observed if: (3) Vaci  Z i   2i  0 where 1 ~ N 0,1 (4)  2 ~ N 0,1 corr 1 ,  2    When  ≠ 0, standard probit techniques applied to (2) yield biased results. The selection model provides consistent, asymptotically efficient estimates for all the parameters in the model. For the model to be identified, we should have at least one variable in the selection equation (3) that is not in the outcome equation. 4.2. Selection equation – The likelihood of vacancies In our selection equation (the probability of reporting a vacancy), we include the following variables in the X vector22. Scale will be an important issue; clearly the more employees a firm has, the more likely it is to have lost one and need to advertise for a replacement. We measure firm size by the (natural) logarithm of rolling mean employment plus a count of working proprietors (from the Linked Employer-Employee Database or LEED), ln(E). This highlights an important link between the workers in a firm and the vacancies it posts. The more workers that quit or are fired from a firm, the more it must replace. We include a direct measure of this with the separation rates (the total number of employees that leave a firm in a year divided by the number of employees, again from the LEED), SepRate. It may be the case that occupations differ in their likelihood of quitting (because they have different outside options, for example). Therefore we include variables for the 22 For more information on the variables see the Data Appendix to this paper. 23
  • 34. proportions of staff that are ‘managers’, ‘professionals’, ‘associate professionals or technicians’ or ‘tradespersons’, Propman to Proptrade. Firms that are already experiencing internal skill gaps may be more likely to attempt to fill these via external recruitment. Therefore, we include a variable that indicates whether the firm feels that their staff lack the skills to perform their roles, ISG. We consider the firms productivity levels using both (the natural logarithm of) their labour productivity, ln(LP), and multifactor productivity, MFP. The latter is generated as the residual from a series of industry-level production functions estimated by OLS. Relative wages Workers choose to accept a job offer contingent on their knowledge of all alternative offers. However, if their wages slip behind other alternatives (because wages in the firm grow more slowly or wages in similar firms grow more rapidly), workers may leave23. We therefore include the change in wages paid by the firm relative to other firms in the same industry, j, in the same region, r, (we discuss the calculation of this in more detail in section 4.3 below), [ln(Wi) – ln(Wijr)]. It may be the case that firms with market power in their product market have greater scope to compete for scarce skilled labour (their supernormal profits are, in effect, shared between the owners of capital and labour). Because of this, we also include a dummy variable to indicate whether the firm is effectively a monopoly (Monopoly). Business Strategy To investigate the relationship between he firms’ business strategy and the demand for skills, we include a set of variables to indicate the business strategy of the firm. The variables we consider are: whether it was able to obtain a higher price than its competitors for its goods and services (Price_Leader); whether it developed or introduced any new or significantly improved goods or services, operational processes, organisational/ managerial processes or marketing methods (Innovate); whether it undertook research and development (R&D); whether its primary market was international, rather than local or national (Mark_Inter); whether it provided customised goods or services (Customise); whether it exported (Export); or whether it undertook outward foreign direct investment (ODI). 23 For a discussion on the influences on individual’s decisions to quit, see Stevens (2005). 24
  • 35. There are a number of factors that make it difficult to include the whole suite of potential business strategy variables from the BOS in our analysis. First, we only have a single cross-section of information on our dependent variables. Second, the business strategy variables are highly correlated with each other. Third, business practices are highly correlated with firm performance and, thus, productivity and the firm’s ability to pay higher wages than its competitors. Fourth, they are all binary or other forms of categorical variables. These combine to make analysis difficult and potential make our estimated coefficients erratic and even counter-intuitive. Because of these issues, we also performed factor analysis and took the factor that had an Eigenvalue of one 24 (which in our econometric analysis will be called BS1). The results of our factor analysis are set our it Table 7 and Table 8. Table 7 Principal component factor analysis of business strategy variables Factor Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative Factor1 1.03421 0.79462 1.3842 1.3842 Factor2 0.23959 0.23876 0.3207 1.7049 Factor3 0.00083 0.06736 0.0011 1.7060 Factor4 -0.06653 0.01844 -0.0890 1.6169 Factor5 -0.08497 0.07256 -0.1137 1.5032 Factor6 -0.15753 0.06092 -0.2108 1.2924 Factor7 -0.21845 -0.2924 1.0000  LR test: independent vs. saturated: chi2(21) = 2374.58 Prob>chi2 = 0.0000 Table 8 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances Variable Factor1 (BS1) Factor2 Factor3 Uniqueness Mark_Inter 0.4563 -0.2085 0.0097 0.7482 Customise 0.1627 0.2250 0.0119 0.9228 Price_Leader 0.2047 0.2074 0.0150 0.9148 Innovate 0.2598 0.2691 -0.0100 0.8600 R&D 0.4721 0.0954 -0.0127 0.7678 Export 0.5731 -0.1229 0.0047 0.6565 ODI 0.3725 -0.0765 -0.0093 0.8553 The panel nature of the BOS allows us to consider the firms business strategy in years prior to the current year’s vacancies (and SSVs). However, some of the variables (i.e., those in Module C) are not available. Therefore, we consider a different set of variables and also undertake a separate factor analysis of these. The 24 The so called ‘Kaiser-Guttman rule’ after Guttman (1954) and Kaiser (1970). 25
  • 36. variables we take from the 2007 BOS included the three variables from Module A in the above analysis: whether they conducted R&D (R&D07), exported (Export07), or undertook ODI (ODI07). Because we have access to the innovation module B in 2007, we are able to divide their innovation activity into the four constituent parts, that is, new or significantly altered: products (prod_inno07), processes (proc_inno07), organisation (org_innov07) and marketing (mark_inno07). The results of our factor analysis are set out in Table 9 and Table 10. Table 9 Principal component factor analysis of 2007 business strategy Factor Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative Factor1 1.49186 1.03350 1.1324 1.1324 Factor2 0.45836 0.47050 0.3479 1.4803 Factor3 -0.01214 0.08671 -0.0092 1.4711 Factor4 -0.09885 0.03521 -0.0750 1.3961 Factor5 -0.13406 0.01513 -0.1018 1.2943 Factor6 -0.14918 0.08937 -0.1132 1.1811 Factor7 -0.23855 . -0.1811 1.0000  LR test: independent vs. saturated: chi2(21) = 3637.14 Prob>chi2 = 0.0000 Table 10 Factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances Factor1 Variable Factor2 Uniqueness (BS07) R&D07 0.4245 0.3145 0.7208 Export07 0.3133 0.3712 0.7641 ODI07 0.2351 0.2875 0.8621 prod_innov07 0.5866 0.0259 0.6552 proc_innov07 0.5428 -0.1862 0.6707 org_innov07 0.5153 -0.2451 0.6744 mark_innov07 0.5039 -0.2088 0.7025 4.3. Probability of SSVs In addition to some of the control variables included in the selection equation, we also investigate the relationship between SSVs and relative wages, the local labour market and types of staff for whom firms are seeking to hire. 26
  • 37. Wages One might expect a major determinant of firms’ ability to fill any vacancy to be the wages it pays relative to other potential employers. We have discussed above why this might not be as clear as it first seems and so the sign on the coefficient of relative wages will tell us something about the function of the New Zealand labour market. In considering the appropriate measure of outside wages, there are a number of factors to take into account. The unit of observation for the data on wages is the establishment. We do not have information on wages by skill level. Our measure of wages is the total wage bill divided by the number of employees on the 13 th of the month. This can be aggregated from a monthly establishment measure to an annual enterprise measure using employment weights (or, equivalently, by summing wage costs and rolling mean employment over the year and dividing one by the other)25. The two dimensions over which we can measure variation in the outside wage are industry classification and geography. However, firms often operate in multiple industries and/or multiple locations. Firm level analysis generally uses the concept of ‘predominant industry’. This is typically measured by taking the industry in which the firm employs the most workers. Thus, if a firm has two establishments, one employing 100 workers constructing boats and one employing 20 to sell marine safety equipment, we say the firm is a boat-maker. If the firm has establishments in more than one region, we could proceed by analogy to determine its ‘predominant region’. This is the course followed by Grimes, Ren and Stevens (2012)26. Because we have information of the numbers of employees and wages at the establishment level, along with the region in which that establishment is situated and its ANZSIC code, we can calculate a more sophisticated measure. We calculate the relative wage at the establishment level and aggregate it across industries and locations in which it operates using employment weights. In the analysis for this paper, we actually considered three outside wage measures: the average wage in the 4-digit industry; the average wage in the local region and; 25 As with other measures using LEED employment, this measure does not take into account the hours worked by employees (we cannot calculate hourly wages), but it does take into account monthly variations within the year (e.g. seasonal working). 26 This is because in the questions on internet connectivity in the 2006 Business Operations Survey used by Grimes et al., respondents are answer with respect to their largest operation. 27
  • 38. the average wage of firms in the industry in the region. However, the measures are highly correlated with each other at the enterprise level and the influence on the results is marginal. Therefore, in this paper, we present results from only the industry-regional measure as it reflects both the national market for skills of a similar nature and the geographic area. We chose the Territorial Authority as the appropriate region as we believe that this most closely approximates a travel-to-work area27. In order to maintain cell sizes, the definition of industry on which we settled was the 2-digit level according to the ANZSIC 1996 classification. In cases where the number of firms in a cell dropped below 50, we used data at the next level of industry aggregation. The industry-region outside wage for an enterprise (the unit of observation in the LBD that broadly corresponds with what economists would call the firm) was calculated as the average wage in the industry-region cell in which the establishments in the enterprise operated, aggregated using establishment employment weights. That is, the outside wage of enterprise i, consisting of L establishments, is given by L M Ei (5) Woi   W jrm l 1 m 1 Eikm where Wjrm is the average wage of the establishments in the 2-digit industry j in the Territorial Authority r in month m (M will typically, but not exclusively, be 12), Ei is the total employment in the enterprise and Eikm is the employment in each establishment in a given month. Local Labour Market Conditions We consider three measures of the local labour market conditions (beyond the industry-region wage). These come from the 2006 Census of Population and Dwellings. The first two are measures of the supply of labour at the two ends of the education distribution. First, we consider the percentage of the population with a degree or higher qualification. Second, we consider the percentage of the population with no qualifications. The third variable we consider is the unemployment rate in the Territorial Authority. 27 It is possible to calculate more sophisticated measures of outside wages and local labour market conditions using more disaggregated (Area Unit or even Meshblock) data and weighting it by some function of the distance between the two areas. We leave this to later work. 28
  • 39. Because these variables are highly correlated, we perform a factor analysis. The factor analysis produces two primary factors with Eigenvalues of greater than one. In order to facilitate interpretation, we undertake factor rotation and obtain the two factors (Census1 and Census2) as set out in Table 11 to Table 13. The first factor is primarily made up of the percentage of the population with no qualifications and unemployment rate variables. The second is a combination of the percentage with degree and unemployment rate. Table 11 Principal component factor analysis of census variables Factor Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative Factor 1 1.50331 0.27826 0.5011 0.5011 Factor 2 1.22505 0.95341 0.4083 0.9095 Factor 3 0.27164 . 0.0905 1.0000  LR test: independent vs. saturated: chi2(3) = 3782.54 Prob>chi2 = 0.0000 Table 12 Rotated factor analysis Factor Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative Census1 1.41023 0.09211 0.4701 0.4701 Census2 1.31812 . 0.4394 0.9095  Rotation method: orthogonal varimax Table 13 Rotated factor loadings (pattern matrix) and unique variances Variable Census1 Census2 Uniqueness % no qualifications 0.9318 -0.2150 0.0854 % degree or higher -0.1096 0.9553 0.0754 % unemployment 0.7279 0.5995 0.1108 Occupational breakdown of vacancies Given the specific nature of many skills, an important element of the ease with which firms will be able to vacancies will be for whom they are seeking. We therefore include four variables for the proportion of vacancies that are for the following occupational groups: managers (Vman), professionals (Vprof), technicians and associate professionals (Vtech) and tradespersons and related workers (Vtrade). The baseline is a 29
  • 40. combination of clerical sales and services workers and labourers, production, transport or other workers28. 5. Results Our results are set out in three sections. In the first section (5.1) we examine SSVs using contemporaneous variables. These will show us which types of firms are currently experiencing SSVs. Next we consider lagged values of the BOS and other LBD variables (5.2). This allows us to look at the characteristics of firms prior to the year in which they reported SSVs. Finally, we consider different specifications of the dependent variable to give some contextual information to help understand our main results (5.3). 5.1. Using contemporaneous variables The results from our estimation using contemporaneous variables are set out in Table 14 and Table 15. The first two columns show the impact of our industry dummies, with column (1) excluding industry dummies and the subsequent columns including them. In column (3) we introduce internal skill gaps and our business strategy variables. Column (4) replaces the strategy variables with the principal factor and the final column presents a more parsimonious specification. Table 14 presents the results for the selection equation of our contemporaneous specifications. Comparison of (1) and (2) suggests that the impact of our industry dummies on the remaining coefficients is relatively minor. In general, larger firms and those that are growing are more likely to be posting a vacancy. The separation rate of the firm has no more predictive power beyond the total number of employees in explaining the variation in the probability of posting a vacancy. Firms that are increasing their wages faster than their competitors tend to be more likely to have a vacancy, although this is not statistically significant in all specifications. Note, however, that in this contemporaneous specification this may reflect firms raising wages in response to staff turnover or firm expansion. This is something we return to when we consider our lagged specifications in section 5.2 28 We also included the first of these in preliminary analysis, but its coefficient was never statistically significant. 30
  • 41. below. The productivity of the firm does not appear to help explain the probability of a firm posting a vacancy, ceteris paribus29. Firms that undertake training in the current year are more likely to have vacancies. Firms enjoying a monopoly in their product market and those with collective agreements are no more likely to have vacancies. None of the occupations appear to be any more likely to create a need for vacancies. When we account for the occupational make-up of the firms employment (in columns (1) to (3)), we find no relationship between this and the likelihood of posting a vacancy. Because of this, we exclude the occupational variables from specifications (4) and (5). We introduce our measure of internal skill gaps (ISG) and business strategy variables in column (3). Firms with internal skill gaps are no more likely to have vacancies, ceteris paribus. Firms that consider themselves to be price leaders and those that have innovated are more likely to have vacancies, a result that is statistically significant at the 1% level. Firms that undertake a high degree of customisation and ODI are also more likely to have a vacancy, although these results are significant only at the 10% level. When we replace these binary variables with the factor (BS1), this is positively correlated with the probability of having vacancies (columns (4) and (5)). This result is significant at the 5% level. 29 Note that we estimated a number of different specifications of the productivity variable and obtain similar results. We also estimated the models in Table 14 and Table 15 with both labour productivity and MFP, but the models with MFP either failed or experienced difficulty converging. We take this as a sign of a less well-specified model and so do not present the results. 31