SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 9
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
Christopher Grandy
                                                                                               University of Hawaii




                      The “Efficient” Public Administrator: Pareto and a                                                 New Ideas for
                                                                                                                       Improving Public
                      Well-Rounded Approach to Public Administration                                                   Administration




The New Public Management movement was only                 alternatives which produces the largest result for the     Christopher Grandy is an associate
                                                                                                                       professor of public administration at
the latest demand that public organizations promote         given application of resources” (Simon 1976, 179).         the University of Hawaii (Manoa). After
efficiency by adopting business methods. There again          Herbert A. Simon (1976, xxviii–xxxi) softened the im-      completing a doctorate in economics at
followed reactions from those arguing that other values,    plied dictate to public administrators by recognizing      the University of California, Berkeley, he
                                                                                                                       taught in the economics departments of
such as equity, citizen participation, and democracy, are   the bounded, rather than full, rationality of human        Barnard College and the University of
as important as efficiency. This article suggests that an     beings and by acknowledging the appropriateness of         Hawaii before working for six years as
economic rather than business perspective on efficiency       satisficing, rather than optimizing behavior. Yet, as       an economist for the Hawaii Department
                                                                                                                       of Business, Economic Development, and
may usefully contribute to the scholarly conversation. It   observed by Hendriekje van der Meer and Mark R.            Tourism. He specializes in public policy and
also suggests that it is “efficient” to identify the public   Rutgers, technical efficiency still dominates the field:      public finance issues, particularly taxation
values in play within any given situation.                  “The most encompassing or general meaning of ef-           and public budgeting. He was a member of
                                                                                                                       the 2005–2007 Hawaii State Tax Review
                                                            ficiency as used in the public administration literature    Commission.




A
        lmost from the beginnings of the field, ef-          is represented by the term ‘technical efficiency.’ Tech-     E-mail: grandy@hawaii.edu
        ficiency has been a source of contention in          nical efficiency can be defined as the ‘ratio between
        public administration. As George W. Downs           input and output’” (2006, 3). The difficulty with
and Patrick D. Larkey observed two decades ago,             applying this definition to the public sector is that the
“Efficiency ranks with motherhood, apple pie, citizen         “problem” can rarely be framed so easily. Instead, ends
participation, and balanced budgets as a fundamental        are multiple and shifting.
American value” (1986, 237). And yet, fairly quickly
in public administration’s his-                                               This article began as an
tory, challenges to efficiency as a                                             economist’s reaction to the
primary public value were artic-           The suggestion by those            critique of efficiency central to
ulated by those acknowledging             skeptical of [New Public            the arguments of those critical
other values such as equity, citi-    Management’s] orientation that          of the New Public Manage-
zenship, and public deliberation.                                             ment (NPM) paradigm. To a
                                       efficiency is only one of several
In concluding a review of the                                                 new member of a small public
“rational model” of public or-          values that public managers           administration program, the ef-
ganizations, Robert B. Denhardt          might appropriately pursue           ficiency focus of NPM seemed
observes that, despite decades of       [seems] . . . odd, at best. For       a sensible, if somewhat obvious,
challenges, the model’s emphasis      the view implies that a manager         goal for public organizations.
on “technical rationality (often         might sacrifice efficiency in           The suggestion by those skepti-
translated as ‘efficiency’)” (2004,                                             cal of NPM’s orientation that
                                       order to advance other values.
87) continues to dominate as a                                                efficiency is only one of several
primary criterion for the evalua-        Yet given a particular goal,         values that public managers
tion of public organizations.           wouldn’t one always want to           might appropriately pursue
                                             pursue it efficiently?             appeared odd, at best. For the
Much of the controversy over                                                  view implies that a manager
efficiency within public admin-                                                 might sacrifice efficiency in or-
istration revolves around a definition that Downs and    der to advance other values. Yet given a particular goal,
Larkey term “managerial efficiency” (1986, 6) and         wouldn’t one always want to pursue it efficiently?
Denhardt calls “technical rationality” (2004, 25). This
notion of efficiency envisions managers pursuing the      The literature on efficiency within public administra-
least costly means of achieving given ends.1 Or, from   tion has modified these initial reactions, and, using
another direction, “efficiency dictates that choice of    an unconventional focus, this article argues that an
                                                                                                     The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1115
economist’s notion of Pareto efficiency can be useful in the debate.        Another source of suspicion came from efficiency’s association with
In the words of Van der Meer and Rutgers, “a more limited inter-          private—that is, business—administration (Waldo 1952, 83–84).
pretation of efficiency as technical efficiency will not do” (2006, 9).       Businesses, in a competitive environment, must be primarily
Ironically, Pareto efficiency’s usefulness lies in a direction that many,   concerned with maximizing profit. Being efficient implies pursu-
suspicious of economic thinking in the public sector, advocate—           ing activities that are most likely to increase profits. Besides being
becoming clearer about values.                                            somewhat distasteful, many within public administration simply
                                                                          found this notion of efficiency inappropriate for public institu-
Efficiency in Public Administration                                        tions. The analogy was inapt. Public agencies do not have a single,
Efficiency was privileged at the beginnings of the field as Progressive      well-specified objective that all agree they should pursue. Instead,
Era reforms sought to systematize and rationalize the administration      as discussed later, public agencies face multiple objectives reflect-
of the public’s business.2 The Progressive movement that ushered in       ing multiple values. In this context, it is not even clear what public
the notion of professional public management was, in large part, a        efficiency would mean.4
reaction against the inefficiencies of the spoils system that had come
before (Hood 1995, 94; Waldo 1952, 86). Appeals to efficiency               The controversy over efficiency reemerged with respect to the New
justified the centralization of public functions, the rise of bureaucra-   Public Management and reinventing government movements. In
cies, and executive budgeting.                                            spite of Waldo’s (1952, 88) suggestion that, 50 years ago, public ad-
                                                                          ministrators were rejecting efficiency as a criterion for public action,
Two early public administration writers who held a broad view             “efficiency” has hung on. David Osborne and Ted Gaebler’s popular
of efficiency were Morris Cooke and Frederick Cleveland. Citing             book (1993), and the wave of writings known as the New Public
Hindy Lauer Schachter’s (1989) work, Van der Meer and Rutgers             Management, raised again the call for government to “get more
(2006, 10) note that Cooke and Cleveland thought of efficiency as           bang for the buck”—that is, to be more efficient.5 The New Zealand
a means of promoting public responsiveness to citizen demands in a        reforms that ushered in the NPM discussion, and the U.S. federal
democracy. Curiously, however, both Schachter (1989, 76, 99) and          government’s reinvention efforts, even harked back to the business
Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 10) interpret this perspective as         metaphor of efficiency that had appealed to the Progressives.6 In
implying that efficiency is a secondary, rather than a primary, value.      response, many in public administration have reacted with skepti-
One might instead note that the Cooke/Cleveland view implies that         cism to the call for greater efficiency.7
efficiency is a basic value—one that undergirds and supports the
broader values of government activity. This interpretive difference is   Multiple Values and Pareto
discussed more fully later.                                             Perhaps the primary objection to “efficiency” as a guiding principle
                                                                                                of public administration is that it seems so
Public administration scholars came to ques-                                                    narrow. Being efficient suggests selecting one,
                                                             Perhaps the primary
tion the preeminence of efficiency as they                                                        or at most a handful, of values at the core of
challenged the Progressives’ separation of              objection to “efficiency” as a            public agencies. It connotes single-mindedly
politics from administration. That separation            guiding principle of public            pursuing an objective with little attention to
was a defining feature of the first phase of            administration is that it seems           external effects. Thus, Waldo suggested that
professional administration. As Dwight Waldo              so narrow. Being efficient              economy and efficiency are about “getting
(1952, 87) noted nearly 60 years ago, sepa-             suggests selecting one, or at           things done” (1952, 93–94), with little at-
rating politics from administration did not                                                     tention to how they are done. Yet how things
                                                      most a handful, of values at the
square with the observation that agencies were                                                  are done—and, in particular, how people are
as much enmeshed in political maneuvering                  core of public agencies.             treated as they get things done—is of princi-
as were legislatures. Thus, if administrators                                                   pal interest to many. One can imagine a mod-
effectively make value decisions, then they cannot be seen as simply     ern Taylorite suggesting to the manager of a state tax department
choosing the “optimal” method of implementing policy decisions.         that he or she measure the number of returns processed, with the
                                                                        implied goal of maximizing that number per unit of time. Skeptics
These critiques of efficiency also objected to separating means from      might worry about the values sacrificed in pursuing such a goal.
ends (Waldo 1952, 90–91). Critics noted that “means are relative to
ends,” that administration is not an end in itself, and that students   The prescriptions of reinventing government and the NPM litera-
of public administration must abandon the notion that “efficiency         ture seem similarly narrow. In several places, Osborne and Gaebler
and economy are objectives superior to any others that may be           (1993, 35–36, 77, 79) focus on lowering the costs of public services
sought” (Kingsley 1945, 89). This directly challenged the technical     and minimizing waste (78, 81, 119). In advocating “mission-driven”
meaning of efficiency as finding an “optimal” method of advancing          public organizations, the authors (14, 113) attacked public agency
given ends. If, as Aaron Wildavsky (1966, 292, 298, 299–300) sug-       rules that stifle effective delivery of services. Osborne and Gaebler’s
gested, means and ends are jointly determined, then in what sense       book talked of putting the customer first; of making public manag-
is a criterion of “efficiency” well specified that focuses on the many     ers more entrepreneurial, presumably with the intention of finding
means by which an end could be attained?3 Moreover, as Denhardt         innovative ways to provide services—perhaps on a paying basis; and
observes, concentrating on efficiency alone draws attention away          of eliminating rules that lead to higher costs. The authors did not
from ends, and in doing so, “we might fail to fully examine and         explicitly advocate a single goal. Indeed, in some places, they recog-
participate in decisions that are of importance to us, thus failing to  nized that there may be multiple goals. But the overall sense of their
meet our democratic obligations” (2004, 150).                           prescriptions was to weed out the “inefficiencies” of public activity
1116   Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
by refocusing on something like “core” values. Similarly, the federal     rather than business. For example, if society values citizen partici-
government’s reinvention efforts, reflected in the National Perform-        pation, the fulfillment of minimal physical requirements for all,
ance Review (1993, chap. 3-2), urged Congress to simplify the             universal education, and economic growth—to propose a necessarily
responsibilities of public agencies in order to enable management ac-     abbreviated list—then an efficient use of resources would require
countability. In general, Denhardt (2004, 140) notes, NPM sought          that it be impossible to advance some of these values without reduc-
to impose a new set of values, coming from the business sector.           ing others. If such advancement is possible, then currently society
                                                                          is not using resources efficiently—some of society’s goals could be
Critics of NPM point out that the efficiency prescriptions of               furthered without reducing the levels of others. Those familiar with
government reinventors excluded important, but not necessarily            economic welfare analysis will recognize this as a particular applica-
measurable, public values. Thus, Demetrios Argyriades (2003, 523)         tion of the Pareto efficiency principle.8 Rather than being applied to
argues that the rise of efficiency in the hierarchy of public organiza-     the allocation of goods and services, however, the suggestion here is
tion values has been accompanied by a lowering of the rule of law         that the public administrator apply the criterion to the public values
and of due process. In his view (526–27), privileging efficiency            at play in a particular issue. Notice that the definition does not re-
undermines debate, consultation, and public deliberation. Linda           quire specifying the overall objective to be advanced—it is sufficient
deLeon and Robert B. Denhardt (2000, 93–95) see the reinvention           to list the component elements (in this case, public values) that
movement as devaluing collaboration, the public interest, and citi-       contribute to the objective. Of course, there may be much discus-
zenship. Suzanne J. Piotrowski and David H. Rosenbloom (2002,             sion about that list.
646) note official concern with efficiency well before the New Public
Management ideas took hold, quoting a 1972 U.S. Supreme Court             Pareto efficiency differs substantially from how “efficiency” is
decision that observed that the due process clause may be inter-          commonly used in the public administration literature. Thus, it
preted as a mechanism to protect citizens from the overly rigorous        is offered here not as a refutation of the concerns about technical
pursuit of efficiency by competent public servants. Rita Mae Kelly          rationality raised by critics of NPM so much as a way of looking at
asserts that others go further, arguing that “[p]rocedural due process,   efficiency that is both consistent with a broad perspective on public
substantive rights, equity, and protection of minority rights . . . are   management and, ironically, more consistent with efficiency’s stand-
values that have precedence over efficiency” (1998, 201). Michael           ard definition in economics. As noted earlier, technical efficiency
Spicer (2007) argues that NPM advocates ignore the intended role          (also known as technical rationality and managerial efficiency) is
of politics in managing conflict over values and thereby threaten          the usual efficiency concept in public administration, understood
harm in promoting simplistic solutions to complex problems.               as pursuing “given objectives with the least cost,” or as a ratio of
                                                                          output to input.9 Moreover, many express concerns about proposals,
Denhardt (2004, 8–9) provides a useful example of efficiency-               such as those implied by NPM advocates, to focus on efficiency be-
motivated, narrow goals. Two experienced managers were tasked             cause “efficiency is a value chosen from among a larger set of values
with quickly establishing a housing loan program. As the supervi-         and . . . the adoption of the value of efficiency precludes attention
sor, John was under considerable pressure, both from within the           to any other, such as equity and participation” (Denhardt 2004,
organization and from potential clients, to process applications          105). In contrast, the concept of Pareto efficiency leaves goals and
rapidly. His co-manager, Carol, recognized the need for quick action      their underlying values unspecified, explicitly allowing for multiple
but also had more direct contact with potential clients. To speed         goals and values. Pareto efficiency is attained only if it is impossible
things along, John asked Carol to have clients sign blank applica-        to advance any of the goals without impairing at least one of the
tion forms, which could later be filled in as information arrived.         others. In this sense, Pareto efficiency is value neutral, or, as Luther
Carol objected, wanting to provide clients full information and           Gulick (1937, 192–93) implied, it is efficiency as meta-value. As ap-
concerned about potential illegality. Denhardt observes that John         plied here, Pareto efficiency is therefore broader than the concept of
seemed “most concerned with the efficient completion of the task”           technical efficiency commonly used in public administration.
(9). Here, Denhardt uses efficiency to refer to the quick processing
of loan applications. Implicitly, getting “work out the door”—that        The difference may be illustrated by returning to the example of the
is, loan applications completed and filed—is the agency’s primary          housing loan program. John’s suggestion to have clients sign blank
work. Anything that interfered with that task threatened to make          forms advances one goal: getting applications into the pipeline
the program look inefficient.                                               as quickly as possible. But if John and Carol applied the Pareto
                                                                          efficiency concept, they would explicitly consider whether other
In the “real world,” public decision makers face multiple values,         goals exist. There may be trust-building and education functions
and these values come from multiple sources. Assuredly, legisla-          fulfilled by communicating frequently with clients and in going
tive bodies give public agencies a variety of marching orders. But        over information submitted on their housing applications. Signing
the executive (mayor, governor, president) may take a somewhat            blank forms may advance the goal of getting applications processed
different perspective on these instructions, urging movement in one        quickly, but it impairs the communication and trust-building goals.
direction rather than another. Moreover, the media and constituents       From this perspective, an exclusive focus on fast processing does not
express their own views and demands—sometimes requiring the               advance (Pareto) efficiency because it promotes one of the agency’s
administrator to respond in ways that differ from what the executive       goals while reducing others.10
or legislators might choose.
                                                                          Public administration scholars have occasionally commented on
The point of this article is that the existence of multiple values is     Pareto efficiency, but usually in a cursory fashion. For example, in
consistent with a definition of efficiency that comes from economics         his deconstruction of efficiency, David John Farmer (1995, 199)
                                                                                                     The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1117
briefly mentions the Pareto concept and notes that it does not              denying the claim; the value of upholding the authority of the legis-
guarantee a just allocation of goods and services. While Patria D.         lative mandate overrides the claim of the business manager.
de Lancer (1999, 536) uses the term in her description of a specific
technique for evaluating efficiency in public organizations, the             The contest over values also evolves. At one point, public deci-
concept of Pareto efficiency is much broader than the technical              sion makers deemed it appropriate to expend resources segregating
application she presents. Van der Meer and Rutgers suggest that            public facilities by race. Today, most people would consider such a
because a Pareto-efficient, or Pareto-optimal, allocation of resources       use of resources inappropriate—that is, illegitimate (not to mention
means that it is impossible to improve the welfare of one person           illegal). This reflects an evolution of values toward the “universal
without reducing that of another, the “welfare of society is at its        equality framework” that Kelly (1998, 203) notes took nearly 200
maximum” (2006, 5). They unfortunately characterize the concept            years to achieve. Similarly, decisions made in the aftermath of the
as a synonym for “optimality,” which thereby falls outside the scope       9/11 terrorist attacks that conflict with understandings of civil liber-
of the concepts of efficiency with which public administration               ties may be seen as wholly inappropriate 20 years from now.13 This
deals.11                                                                   observation is consistent with Charles E. Lindblom’s (1959) incre-
                                                                           mental model of public decision making, which stresses the complex
Peter Self stands out as a sustained public administration critic of       and varying nature of promoting public values.
what he called the “absurdly revered ‘Pareto principle’” (1985, 70) as
a criterion for public decision making. It is important to understand     Lindblom’s (1990) later work expands on the idea of evolving
that Self addressed the Pareto concept as it is usually applied in        values. In Lindblom’s framework, individuals in society are, to
economics—that is, as a criterion of proposed policy that affects the      one degree or another, engaged in probing their world in order
distribution of goods and services in an economy. Instead, this ar-       to figure things out. Such probing may be impaired in various
ticle proposes that public administrators apply the Pareto efficiency       ways—including by professional social scientists. Yet he sees a
concept to the public values that are at play in a particular situation.  society in which many (all?) members participate in the process
Self ’s critiques, and this distinction, are elaborated on later.         of advancing knowledge and understanding; Lindblom calls this a
                                                                          self-guiding society. This guidance presumably applies to all aspects
As discussed in the next section, a positive consequence of using the of knowledge—including the identification, modification, and
Pareto efficiency concept is the implied need to be clear about which acceptance or rejection of legitimate values. Exploring the process
values are legitimately “public.”                                         by which such values are agreed upon lies beyond the scope of this
                                                                          article. However, as discussed later, the public administrator is in a
Pareto Efficiency as Necessary, but                                                                unique position to participate in such prob-
Not Sufficient, Meta-Value                                                                         ing and, indeed, to advance or hinder values
                                                       When an administrator makes
When an administrator makes a decision in                                                         by his or her decisions. The Pareto efficiency
the multiple-value environment, he or she                 a decision in our multiple-             criterion, applied as suggested here, provides
may be hard-pressed to explain the process.             value environment, he or she              public administrators with a conceptual
The political and economic forces that emerge          may be hard-pressed to explain             framework that can improve the quality of
for a particular problem are varied and com-            the process. The political and            their decisions in ways that are consistent
plex, and the values put forward come from              economic forces that emerge               with Lindblom’s vision.
many quarters with differing intensities. Thus,
                                                         for a particular problem are
the administrator of a tax compliance unit,                                                       From the Pareto efficiency perspective, to say
attempting to determine whether a business               varied and complex, and the              that an agency acts inefficiently is to say either
tax credit should apply in a specific case, may         values put forward come from               (1) that it pursues some values that are not le-
face several sources of influence: legislators           many quarters with differing               gitimate, or (2) that it neglects to pursue some
who voted for the credit on the grounds of                         intensities.                   legitimate values that it can affect. Thus, the
diversifying the local economy; legislators who                                                   tax compliance administrator who approves
opposed the credit with concerns about the                                                        the application of the business tax credit to
fiscal implications; businesses who may qualify for the credit; busi-      his brother’s firm, despite having rejected similar claims by others in
nesses who clearly do not qualify and wonder where their tax break        the past, is acting inefficiently. The inefficiency lies in promoting a
is; and taxpayers who are concerned about the upward pressure on          value (the support of his brother’s company) that is not legitimate
rates that might result from the negative revenue implications. The       from a public perspective. Similarly, should Carol, the housing loan
values implicit in these perspectives are legitimate, and the adminis-    program co-manager, make no effort toward moving applications
trator who ignores many of them will find life unpleasant.12               along, then she would be acting inefficiently.

However, to say that an agency faces the task of managing multiple         Of course, the word “efficiency” is often part of the contest over
values does not imply that all values are legitimate. In a general         the legitimacy of values. Downs and Larkey observe a tendency to
sense, one can imagine values put forward to cover as many interests       label as “inefficient” the pursuit of goals “that differ from one’s own”
as there are people in the community. Clearly, not all can receive         (1986, 13). “Efficiency” is a powerful word, whose use can bestow
equal weight when allocating public resources. The businessperson          legitimacy on the ideas to which it is attached. Thus, the early public
whose activities obviously fall outside the scope of a tax credit’s leg-   administration writers who sought to incorporate business methods,
islative intent may argue that all businesses—including his—should         such as formal hierarchical organization, into the public sphere did
get a break. But the administrator is not likely to have much trouble      so in large part by appealing to efficiency (see, e.g., Denhardt 2004,
1118   Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
77). As has been noted, promoters of NPM, explicitly utilizing busi-       defined relative to other values, the concept takes the superordinat-
ness concepts, made similar appeals to efficiency. Downs and Larkey          ing status of meta-value rather than a subordinating, second-order
observed that “efficiency is [often] less a goal of reorganization than      status. For the Pareto proposition is to “efficiently” pursue the set of
a justification for it” (1986, 186).                                        values deemed relevant in a particular situation (where this means
                                                                           taking actions that advance at least one value without impairing
Virtually all of the critiques of NPM prescriptions can be seen as         others). In this interpretation, efficiency is not a second-order value
examples of the contest over which values to include in the “legiti-       as a result of its relationship to other values, nor can efficiency be
mate” set. For example, Argyriades’s implicit critique of the “3Es         seen as merely one of many values without priority, because it makes
(economy, efficiency, and effectiveness)” (2003, 523) is a defense            no sense to think of trading off Pareto efficiency for another value
of the values of rule of law, due process, debate, and public delib-       over which it is defined. Rather, the notion of Pareto efficiency
eration. DeLeon and Denhardt’s (2000) critique of reinvention’s            with respect to public values raises “efficiency” to meta-value, even
market, customer service, and entrepreneurial orientations empha-          beyond where Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 15–16) place their
sizes the values of collaboration, the public interest, and citizenship.   concept of “substantive efficiency” (defined as a general assessment
Here, “efficiency” is seen as one value that is advanced at the expense      of well-functioning administration) as equal with other values.
of others.
                                                                           And yet, this article does not propose that Pareto efficiency can be
Yet these critiques apply to the technical, or managerial, efficiency        relied on as a sole guide for managerial action. Many combinations
concept of Denhardt (2004, 87), Downs and Larkey (1986, 6),                of public values may be consistent with the Pareto criterion. More-
and Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 3) rather than to the Pareto           over, public managers must often make decisions that violate the
concept. The objections come down to insisting that pursuing               Pareto criterion. That is, they are compelled to make decisions that
(technical or managerial) efficiency neglects other, valued goals that       advance some legitimate values at the expense of others. Making
an agency might legitimately pursue. In contrast, Pareto efficiency          those decisions is not a matter of efficiency as defined by the Pareto
characterizes a relationship among values: given the set of legitimate     criterion. It lies beyond efficiency. That is, the concept of Pareto
values, efficiency is defined in terms of whether some must be sacri-         efficiency gets the administrator only so far as a guide to action. It
ficed in order to advance others.                                           tells the administrator to be on the lookout for the multiple values
                                                                           in play in a given situation. But the likely course of action will have
Stated another way, the trade-off among values cannot apply to the          to be taken on grounds other than efficiency itself.14
concept of (Pareto) efficiency. If by “efficiency,” one means “tech-
nical rationality” or “managerial efficiency,” then such a trade-off        Given that managers must make decisions that choose among val-
makes sense: one could imagine consciously incurring higher than         ues, it seems desirable that as many legitimate values as possible be
minimum costs in order to advance another value, such as due             included in the decision maker’s calculus.15 Otherwise, the manager
process. But Pareto efficiency is defined in terms of trade-offs among       will make decisions that neglect some legitimate values. For exam-
values: administrators have acted efficiently if it is not possible        ple, the tax compliance manager who focuses only on the number of
to advance any of society’s legitimate values without accepting a        returns processed each month may neglect the values of fairness and
reduction in another. If all legitimate values are considered, then it   accuracy in taking more time with particularly complicated cases.
would be tautological to propose a trade-off of Pareto efficiency for       Similarly, John’s proposal to have clients sign blank application
another value. This point emphasizes the very different meanings          forms may have been made without regard to the trust-building and
between technical rationality or managerial efficiency (a value that       communication goals of the unit. For these reasons, a grounding in
can be conceptually weighed against other values, as in Jorgensen        common knowledge and shared values, to which Kelly (1998, 202)
and Bozeman 2007, 367), and Pareto efficiency (a statement about a         refers, ensures that, within a specific context, the manager does not
particular set of values).                                               exclude important values in play. Schachter (2007, 807) notes that
                                                                                                 acquiring such a grounding requires that the
Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 9–10, 14)                                                        public manager engage with the community’s
discuss related issues that serve to emphasize            . . . the notion of Pareto             citizens.
the meta-value status of Pareto efficiency rela-       efficiency with respect to public
tive to other definitions. The authors (9–10)             values raises “efficiency” to              Of course, literally considering all values
note that Dwight Waldo famously observed                                                          is impossible, and an attempt to do so is
                                                      meta-value, . . . yet this article
that it does not make sense to advocate “being                                                    likely undesirable. Again, Lindblom’s (1959)
efficient” in the abstract. To be operational, ef-     does not propose . . . that Pareto work is relevant in that he argued against an
ficiency must be related to the pursuit of some         efficiency can be relied upon                analytical model that attempts a complete
particular value or goal. Because efficiency             as a sole guide for managerial             listing of alternative methods for achieving
can only be understood with respect to other                         action.                      a given end. Lindblom’s apt objection is that
values, Waldo (1984, 193) concluded that                                                          constructing such a list is impossible in most
efficiency could not be fundamental to public                                                       cases and undesirable to the extent that valu-
administration. Van der Meer and Rutgers adopt this perspective           able resources are used in constructing a list, most of which would
with respect to technical efficiency, arguing that “[e]fficiency can          be irrelevant to the actual decision made.
be seen as a second-order value” (2006, 14). Yet, as suggested in
this article, if one instead adopts the Pareto efficiency criterion with    Thus the set of “all” legitimate values must be read as all values that
respect to public values, then, although efficiency continues to be         the administrator, upon self-reflection and in consultation with
                                                                                                      The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1119
colleagues and the public, can reasonably identify as being related to      Second, and more importantly, the public manager’s utilization
the question at hand. The goal of such reflection (a form of Lind-           of the Pareto principle as applied to the public values at play in a
blom’s probing) is to cut short the urge to quickly identify a course       particular issue compels explicit consideration of those values. In
of action at the cost of negative unintended consequences. If the           this sense, conscious application of the Pareto principle can promote
administrator takes the time to identify relevant values in play, then      a transformative, value-regarding approach to public administration.
he or she is more likely to be prepared for challenges to the policy        As mentioned, such an approach is consistent with Lindblom’s call
proposal and to anticipate further developments. Acting in this way         for “probing” societal issues. The application of the Pareto principle
is consistent with acting (Pareto) efficiently.                               by public managers is a concrete step toward ensuring that public
                                                                            managers engage in, and support, such probing either within the
It is instructive to understand Self ’s critique of Pareto efficiency         walls of a public institution or in the broader community. Thus, as
and why it has less force in the context suggested here. For Self, the      John and Carol develop the habit of asking themselves what public
major objection to Pareto efficiency as applied to goods and services         values are at play in a given situation, and whether some of those
is that it essentially conserves the status quo.16 If adopted as a policy   values can be advanced by actions that do not impair others, they
criterion, Pareto efficiency requires permitting only changes in the          continuously remind themselves of the larger context of their work.
distribution of goods and services that make at least one person bet-       And they regularly remind themselves of the boundaries at which
ter off and no persons worse off; thus, implicitly, the existing distri-      further pursuit of some values requires accepting the diminution
bution of goods and services is privileged (Self 1977, 26, 143; 1985,       of others. The managers thereby open themselves to the option of
70; 1993, 248–49). Moreover, strict application of the criterion to         seeking public input about those choices and of participating in
public policy would virtually guarantee that nothing gets done—             dialogue about both the set of relevant values and how their con-
because the criterion essentially gives veto power to anyone who may        stituents weigh them.
claim harm from a change in policy (Self 1985, 76; 1993, 249).
                                                                            Finally, the Pareto efficiency approach envisions a role for public
While these are strong arguments against the adoption of Pareto             administrators that is philosophically distinct from that of NPM’s
efficiency as a general criterion for public policy decisions, they have      advocates. Vice President Al Gore is quoted in the National Per-
less force in the context suggested here of an administrator’s con-         formance Review with respect to values as follows: “There has to be
siderations of the relevant public values in a specific issue. A public      a clear, shared sense of mission. There have to be clearly understood
decision maker can be said to be acting efficiently with respect to a         goals. There have to be common values according to which deci-
public issue if he or she has reached a point where it is impossible to     sions are made. There has to be trust placed in the employees who
further at least one public value relevant to that issue without im-        actually do the work” (1993, chap. 3-2). While these might be desir-
pairing other relevant public values. Once that point is reached, the       able features of a well-focused public agency, getting to this point
administrator will have to make decisions that involve trading off           is nontrivial. In the real world of most public agencies that manage
at least one value against others, and so those decisions lie beyond        complex issues with multiple facets, the costs of seeking value con-
efficiency. If society forbade the administrator to act beyond the            sensus should be weighed against the likely success. Alternatively,
Pareto efficiency criterion, then Self ’s critiques would apply here;         if managers are imbued with the mind-set to consider the range of
then, Pareto efficiency would be of little help to the administrator.         public values raised by a particular issue, then the sense of shared
However, once an administrator has exhausted efforts to advance              mission and values becomes an ongoing, negotiated process within
relevant public values where no impairment of others is implied,            and among agencies and the public. This description of process may
then the requirements of efficiency have been satisfied. The admin-            be a more realistic guide for public managers than the end-state
istrator may then move on to consider the (probably more difficult)           envisioned in Vice President Gore’s remarks.
issues of which public values to advance at the expense of others and
by what criteria to make those choices.17                                   It is worth noting characteristics of the public decision-making
                                                                            process that are likely to be consistent with, if not necessary to,
The adoption of this application of Pareto efficiency by public               the use of the Pareto principle proposed here. First, the approach
decision makers offers both (1) a modest improvement in the                  presumes the existence of a degree of openness to discussion and
immediate allocation of energies by administrators with influence            issues exploration (Lindblom’s probing) within the public agency.
on public policy, and (2) a significant step forward in the quality          In an autocratic, closed organizational environment, it may be
of public decision processes. First, in the short run, to encourage         impossible to even pose the question of which values are in play
public managers to take actions that will advance some goal(s) that         in an issue—because the question suggests that other values might
do not impair the attainment of others seems common sense. The              be considered. Of course, there are different degrees of openness,
more frequent, and more difficult, problem facing an administrator            and even in strongly hierarchical organizations, it may be possible
involves choosing among actions, all of which require sacrificing            for managers to find ways to pose thought-provoking (thought-
some desirable goals in order to advance others. Thus, the problem          promoting?) questions in the guise of loyalty to the organization:
facing John and Carol is not simply how to minimize processing              for example, “How should we expect constituent group X to react
time—it is how to get the housing loan program going quickly                to our proposed course of action?” Such questions at least open the
while promoting the trust-building and educational goals of the             door to a strategic, and possibly substantive, discussion of other
agency.18 Application of the Pareto principle at least satisfies the goal    values in play.19
of using available resources efficiently—making sure that actions are
undertaken that promote some values which do not threaten other             A second institutional feature implied by the explicit adoption
values.                                                                     of Pareto efficiency with respect to public values relates to public
1120   Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
forums. If public administrators begin to practice the accounting         of the multiple, legitimate values at play. Their decisions may not
for public values that the Pareto principle requires, then they will      be explainable in terms of maximizing a well-defined function that
find themselves compelled to seek direct information about such            indexes the component legitimate values. But if the administrator
values in conversations with constituents, meetings with community        can provide a coherent explanation of why some values are pursued
groups, public hearings, legislative committee meetings, and so on.       more fully than others, and can do this for the relevant legitimate
Efforts to seriously identify public values in play demand such in-        values, then she has succeeded in implicitly weighing those values in
put. And the conversation goes both ways. For the public adminis-         some way. This approach may be thought of as an extension of the
trator must also be able to articulate his or her reasoning in arriving   “let managers manage” philosophy—by adding the requirement that
at a decision. If such reasoning explicitly acknowledges public values    managers be prepared to explain their choices.21 And the manager
that are relevant, but that have not been advanced by a particular        has satisfied the economic definition of efficiency: using available
decision, then the administrator may have at least signaled aware-        resources so that it is not possible to advance some values without
ness of those values and accepted their relevance. That may not           impairing others.22
appease the ardent activist, but it may prove helpful in subsequent
encounters. Thus, adoption of this application of Pareto efficiency         Denhardt (2004, 153) argues that practitioners want a public
both contributes to an improved (inclusive) decision-making proc-         administration theory that provides them understanding from
ess and it provides a framework within which to legitimate decisions      which new approaches to their work can be constructed, as well as
once made.                                                                a conceptual framework within which to interpret their experience.
                                                                          In this light, the long-standing public administration debate about
We should note here Lindblom’s (1990, 109–14) concern about               efficiency must be particularly frustrating. The approach suggested
public officials using their position and authority to impair the           here may offer the practitioner some clarity that is consistent with
probing process. The public administrator described here is one of        an important version of efficiency:
many who have some decision-making authority with respect to
public issues. Lindblom expresses concern that the official might              Accept that you will be placed under demands from many
choose to make his or her life easier by suppressing discussion and          sources and that you will have to weigh the values implied.
conflict over values. Yet this would violate the maintained assump-           Some of these values will carry more weight than others,
tion that the administrator wishes to act efficiently; if that is not the      and these weights will shift over time. When presented with
case, then the implied management issues lie beyond this article’s           the (probably rare) opportunity to advance some values
scope. In the framework described here, the administrator must               without impairing others, pursue it vigorously. Most of the
explicitly consider other views and values in order to act efficiently.        rest of the time you will have to choose among competing
Moreover, that consideration by the administrator may be the most            values; do so with awareness for what is being advanced and
constructive result of her effort to be efficient.                              what is not.

Herein lies the value of adopting the Pareto definition of efficiency        If this advice does not seem particularly startling, that may be a
in public administration: it forces the decision maker to identify        good thing. For it suggests an approach to administration that is
the values in play.20 This may lead to recognition that some of the       consistent with the view that an important part of the work of
values are not legitimate, in which case the course of action becomes     public managers is to “express the values of our society” (Denhardt
relatively clear. In cases in which many conflicting values are legiti-    2004, 192).
mate, explicit identification may help the decision maker embark
on a process that will determine a decision. But the administrator        The argument offered here is not that efficiency is unimportant, nor
will not be able to justify that decision on the basis of efficiency. In    that some values are more important than efficiency. Indeed, the
most cases, all the administrator can do is to start from a position in   concept of Pareto efficiency places it in the position of meta-value.
which he or she is using resources well (Pareto efficiently) and then       The argument here is that managers need not run the risk of being
make decisions in awareness of the value trade-offs.                       accused of inefficiency when they entertain contending values.
                                                                          Pareto efficiency requires that they do so. Nevertheless, manag-
In the housing loan example, ultimately, John’s direction to sign         ers will often have to justify decisions on grounds that go beyond
blank forms might be defensible. If John was well aware of the            efficiency. In this sense, efficiency is a necessary, but not sufficient,
potential negative impact on client trust and, in light of that, still    condition for sensibly and responsibly carrying out the work of
felt the overriding need to get some applications processed immedi-       public organizations.
ately, then the decision might not be gainsaid. Perhaps more likely,
reflecting on the negative impact on client                                                      Acknowledgments
trust and the possible long-term impairment                                                     The author is especially grateful to Dick Pratt
of the client base, John might look for ways to      This article has argued that public        for his patient guidance and suggestions dur-
ameliorate those effects—perhaps by making                                                       ing the writing of this article. For extensive
the signing of blank forms temporary.
                                                      administrators act in ways that           comments on earlier versions, thanks go to
                                                      are consistent with “efficiency”            Roger Blair, Jim Mak, Jim Roumasset, and
Conclusion                                              when they make decisions                Sumner LaCroix. Valuable suggestions were
This article has argued that public administra-        while aware of the multiple,             made by Jill Tao, David Nixon, and Tsedev
tors act in ways that are consistent with “effi-           legitimate values at play.             Damiran. Mark Rutgers kindly shared his un-
ciency” when they make decisions while aware                                                    published work. Finally, the author gratefully
                                                                                                    The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1121
acknowledges the careful reading and suggestions offered by three                     in the sense that the value of a social welfare function has peaked.
anonymous reviewers of PAR.                                                          Lockwood notes that a particular allocation of resources is only
                                                                                     Pareto-optimal “in the limited sense that not everybody can be made
Notes                                                                                better off,” and for this reason, “the word ‘Pareto-optimal’ has gradu-
1.  As expressed, for example, in Gulick (1937, 192). For recent sub-                ally been replaced by ‘Pareto-efficient’” (1987, 811). In any case, the
    stantive discussions of efficiency in public administration, see Van               Pareto efficiency concept suggested here relates not to the allocation
    der Meer and Rutgers (2006) and Schachter (2007).                                of goods and services in society (the usual definition), but instead to
2. See Dwight Waldo (1952) for a survey of public administration’s                   the relevant public values involved in a particular issue. In this sense,
    origins as part of his call for a theory of “democratic administration.”         this article transfers the Pareto efficiency concept from the economic
3. Similarly, Denhardt’s (2004, 71–72) discussion of Robert Dahl’s                   realm to the realm of applied public decision making.
    early work emphasizes the public administrator’s involvement in            12.   For an effort to identify and systematically discuss public values, see
    both ends and means, making adherence to technical efficiency logi-                Jorgensen and Bozeman (2007).
    cally and ethically problematic.                                           13.   Denhardt defines the field of public administration as the manage-
4. This is a time-honored conversation; see Denhardt (2004, 15 and                   ment of the “change processes” necessary to pursue “publicly defined
    passim) and Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 11) for valuable                     societal values” (2004, 16).
    discussions. Downs and Larkey observe that public institutions will        14.   Joseph A. Schumpeter observed that Pareto made a similar point:
    necessarily seem inefficient when goals of due process or redistribu-              “Pareto pointed out that welfare judgments that cannot be salvaged
    tion “consume resources that a private organization would spend on               in this manner [i.e., justified by the Pareto principle] must be explic-
    the primary mission alone” (1986, 242).                                          itly based on extra-economic, e.g. ‘ethical,’ considerations” (1965,
5. See Osborne and Gaebler (1993, 15, 35, 80). Kaboolian notes that                  131). Here Schumpeter’s phrase “extra-economic” is interpreted as
    each of the government reform movements labeled as part of NPM                   meaning beyond efficiency.
    sought to “maximize productive and allocative efficiencies” (1998,           15.   This assertion is consistent with Denhardt’s argument that managers
    190).                                                                            of public organizations “bear a responsibility to examine, under-
6. On New Zealand, see, for example, Schwartz (1997, 412, 416). For                  stand, and interpret public values to the best of their ability” (2004,
    the United States, see National Performance Review (1993, chap. 2).              124). Lindblom’s discussion of the “method of successive limited
7. For example, see Argyriades (2003), deLeon and Denhardt (2000),                   comparisons” (1959, 81), or incrementalism, makes the important
    and Spicer (2004, 2007). The emerging public value paradigm in                   point that it is not possible to identify literally all the values at play
    public administration shares this skepticism (Moore 1995; O’Flynn                in a policy decision. Still, the argument presented here is consistent
    2007; Rhodes and Wanna 2007).                                                    with Lindblom’s rejection of what he called the “root” approach to
8. Named for the Italian economist and sociologist Vilfredo Pareto, the              analysis, which would require weighting and aggregating all relevant
    concept is fundamental to neoclassical economics. See Lockwood                   values prior to considering alternative policy options.
    (1987) for a discussion. Economics entertains several notions of ef-       16.   Lindblom (1990, 148–49) makes similar points. Although Lind-
    ficiency, some that appear to go well beyond the conceptual require-              blom appears to share Self ’s criticisms of the Pareto criterion, it is
    ments of the Pareto definition. Still, as Downs and Larkey (1986, 7)              interesting that the conserving aspect of the criterion is consistent
    suggest, the Pareto criterion is the economist’s preferred definition of          with Lindblom’s interest in the incremental accretion of knowledge
    efficiency; perhaps for this reason, these authors label it “economic              and policy development.
    efficiency.” Moreover, Lockwood (1987, 813) observes that within             17.   In an article that offers a “public failure” model to supplement the
    mainstream neoclassical economics, all other concepts of efficiency                existing market failure model central to public policy analysis, Barry
    eventually reduce to Pareto efficiency. This observation suggests                  Bozeman suggests that Pareto efficiency is equivalent to “conventional
    an irony in Van der Meer and Rutgers’s (2006, 7, 8) association of               utilitarian calculus” (2002, 147). This misstates the Pareto criterion:
    technical efficiency (a relationship between inputs and output) with               rather than promoting the interpersonal comparisons of utility that
    economics; Pareto efficiency goes well beyond technical efficiency.                  are a major drawback of utilitarianism, the Pareto criterion specifi-
9. See Denhardt (2004, 148) and Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 3).                  cally avoids such comparisons by focusing only on changes that do
    Also see Denhardt’s discussion of Weber’s view of “technical rational-           not reduce any individual’s welfare level. In the context of this paper,
    ity (i.e. formal efficiency)” (25), emphasizing private ownership                  the criterion would have the administrator look for opportunities to
    and managerial control of productive resources, as well as page 43               advance at least some public values without impairing others.
    (discussing Woodrow Wilson’s businesslike approach), pages 51–53           18.   Of course, this example abstracts from the existence of other goals
    (Frederick W. Taylor’s scientific management), and pages 61–65 (ef-               and values that might be at play in the housing loan program.
    ficiency as the measure of success).                                        19.   Note that National Performance Review’s advocacy of decentralizing
10. In the language of welfare economics, John’s proposal is “Pareto in-             decision-making power is also consistent with the suggestion here
    ferior.” A policy that would advance at least one of the agency’s goals          to give managers latitude to question and challenge the underlying
    without impeding others would be called “Pareto superior” relative               values promoted (and ignored) by a particular course of action.
    to the existing situation. It should be noted that in the framework        20.   As with Bozeman’s (2002, 150, 157) proposed model of public
    suggested here, the public administrator identifies public values,                failure in advancing values, this approach does not require agreement
    rather than creating such values, as Mark H. Moore (1995) and oth-               on public values—merely attention to them. This point partially ad-
    ers have advocated.                                                              dresses John Bohte’s (2007, 812) question about what an administra-
11. Van der Meer and Rutgers correctly observe that the phrases “Pareto-             tor is to do when faced with conflict over desired outcomes.
    optimal” and “Pareto-efficient” are used synonymously; however,              21.   See Donald F. Kettl’s (1997, 447) discussion of letting, versus mak-
    the concept does not imply that society’s welfare is at a maximum                ing, managers manage.

1122     Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
22. There is some irony here: while many public administration writers have urged the consideration of multiple public values in addition to, or to contest the
    primacy of (technical) efficiency, this article suggests that the public administrator use Pareto efficiency in order to ensure the consideration of relevant public
    values.

References
Argyriades, Demetrios. 2003. Values for Public Service: Lessons Learned from Recent Trends and the Millennium Summit. International Review of Administrative
     Sciences 69(4): 521–33.
Bohte, John. 2007. Governmental Efficiency in Our Time: Is the “What” Really More Important than the “How”? Public Administration Review 67(5): 811–15.
Bozeman, Barry. 2002. Public-Value Failure: When Efficient Markets May Not Do. Public Administration Review 62(2): 145–61.
De Lancer, Patria D. 1999. Data Envelopment Analysis: An Introduction. In Handbook of Research Methods in Public Administration, edited by Gerard J. Miller
     and Marcia L. Whicker, 535–48. New York: Marcel Dekker.
deLeon, Linda, and Robert B. Denhardt. 2000. The Political Theory of Reinvention. Public Administration Review 60(2): 89–97.
Denhardt, Robert B. 2004. Theories of Public Organization. 4th ed. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomson.
Downs, George W., and Patrick D. Larkey. 1986. The Search for Government Efficiency: From Hubris to Helplessness. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
Farmer, David John. 1995. The Language of Public Administration: Bureaucracy, Modernity, and Postmodernity. Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press.
Gulick, Luther. 1937. Science, Values, and Public Administration. In Papers on the Science of Administration Luther Gulick and L. Urwick, 189–202. New York:
     Institute of Public Administration.
Hood, Christopher. 1995. The “New Public Management” in the 1980s: Variations on a Theme. Accounting, Organizations and Society 20(2–3): 93–109.
Jorgensen, Torben Beck, and Barry Bozeman. 2007. Public Values: An Inventory. Administration & Society 39(3): 354–81.
Kaboolian, Linda. 1998. The New Public Management: Challenging the Boundaries of the Management vs. Administration Debate.” Public Administration Review
     58(3): 189–93.
Kelly, Rita Mae. 1998. An Inclusive Democratic Polity, Representative Bureaucracies, and the New Public Management. Public Administration Review 58(8):
     201–8.
Kettl, Donald F. 1997. The Global Revolution in Public Management: Driving Themes, Missing Links. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 16(3): 446–62.
Kingsley, J. Donald. 1945. Political Ends and Administrative Means: The Administrative Principles of Hamilton and Jefferson. Public Administration Review 5(1):
     87–89.
Lindblom, Charles E. 1959. The Science of “Muddling Through.” Public Administration Review 19(2): 79–88.
———. 1990. Inquiry and Change: The Troubled Attempt to Understand and Change Society. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Lockwood, B. 1987. Pareto Efficiency. In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, vol. 3, edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman,
     811–13. London: Macmillan.
Moore, Mark H. 1995. Creating Public Value: Strategic Management in Government. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
National Performance Review (NPR). 1993. From Red Tape to Results: Creating a Government that Works Better and Costs Less. http://govinfo.library.unt.
     edu/npr/library/nprrpt/annrpt/redtpe93/index.html [accessed July 27, 2009].
O’Flynn, Janine. 2007. From New Public Management to Public Value: Paradigmatic Change and Managerial Implications. Australian Journal of Public Adminis-
     tration 66(3): 353–66.
Osborne, David and Ted Gaebler. 1993. Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit Is Transforming the Public Sector. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Piotrowski, Suzanne J., and David H. Rosenbloom. 2002. Non-Mission-Based Values in Results-Oriented Public Management: The Case of Freedom of Informa-
     tion. Public Administration Review 62(6): 643–57.
Rhodes, R. A. W., and John Wanna. 2007. The Limits to Public Value, or Rescuing Responsible Government from the Platonic Guardians. Australian Journal of
     Public Administration 66(4): 406–21.
Schachter, Hindy Lauer. 1989. Frederick Taylor and the Public Administration Community: A Reevaluation. Albany: State University of New York Press.
———. 2007. Does Frederick Taylor’s Ghost Still Haunt the Halls of Government? A Look at the Concept of Governmental Efficiency in Our Time. Public
     Administration Review 67(5): 800–810.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1952. Ten Great Economists: From Marx to Keynes. London: Allen and Unwin, 1965.
Schwartz, Herman M. 1997. Reinvention and Retrenchment: Lessons from the Application of the New Zealand Model to Alberta, Canada. Journal of Policy
     Analysis and Management 16(3): 405–22.
Self, Peter. 1977. Econocrats and the Policy Process: The Politics and Philosophy of Cost-Benefit Analysis. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
———. 1985. Political Theories of Modern Government, Its Role and Reform. London: Allen and Unwin.
———. 1993. Government by the Market? The Politics of Public Choice. London: Macmillan.
Simon, Herbert A. 1976. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization. 3rd ed. New York: Free Press.
Spicer, Michael. 2004. Public Administration, the History of Ideas, and the Reinventing Government Movement. Public Administration Review 64(3): 353–62.
———. 2007. Politics and the Limits of a Science of Governance: Some Reflections on the Thought of Bernard Crick. Public Administration Review 67(4):
     768–79.
Van der Meer, Hendriekje, and Mark R. Rutgers. 2006. Reinstating Efficiency: Recapturing the Substantial Meaning of Efficiency in Public Administration. Paper
     presented to the Annual Conference of the European Group of Public Administration, Bocconi University Milan, September 6–9.
Waldo, Dwight. 1952. Development of Theory of Administration. American Political Science Review 46(1): 81–103.
———. 1984. The Administrative State: A Study of the Political Theory of American Public Administration. 2nd ed. New York: Holmes & Meier.
Wildavsky, Aaron. 1966. The Political Economy of Efficiency: Cost–Benefit Analysis, Systems Analysis, and Program Budgeting. Public Administration Review
     26(4): 292–310.

                                                                                                                            The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1123

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Ähnlich wie Grandy2009

Overview Of South African Public Management
Overview Of South African Public ManagementOverview Of South African Public Management
Overview Of South African Public ManagementJessica Tanner
 
Paving The Way
Paving The WayPaving The Way
Paving The Waycoryhelene
 
A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...
A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...
A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...Stacy Taylor
 
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTUSantosConleyha
 
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTUBenitoSumpter862
 
The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...
The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...
The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...paperpublications3
 
Social Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docx
Social Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docxSocial Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docx
Social Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docxjensgosney
 
10 kelly mulgan muers creating public value
10 kelly mulgan muers creating public value10 kelly mulgan muers creating public value
10 kelly mulgan muers creating public valueJordi Puig
 
Defining Public Administration
Defining Public AdministrationDefining Public Administration
Defining Public AdministrationCarmen Sanborn
 
Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...
Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...
Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...Ahasan Uddin Bhuiyan
 
New Public Management, is it a reality?
New Public Management, is it a reality?New Public Management, is it a reality?
New Public Management, is it a reality?Ashiki_Elahi
 
6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docx
6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docx6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docx
6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docxJospehStull43
 
Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)
Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)
Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)Ahasan Uddin Bhuiyan
 
Comparaive management
Comparaive managementComparaive management
Comparaive managementfaith ijeoma
 
Accountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGO
Accountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGOAccountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGO
Accountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGORyan MacNeil
 
The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling
The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling
The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling Ekta Grover
 

Ähnlich wie Grandy2009 (20)

New Public Administration
New Public AdministrationNew Public Administration
New Public Administration
 
New Public Administration
New Public AdministrationNew Public Administration
New Public Administration
 
Overview Of South African Public Management
Overview Of South African Public ManagementOverview Of South African Public Management
Overview Of South African Public Management
 
Paving The Way
Paving The WayPaving The Way
Paving The Way
 
A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...
A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...
A Critical Review Of Literature On Influence Of Good Governance On Service Qu...
 
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTU
 
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY  March 2000Peters, Pierre  MUTU
10ADMINISTRATION & SOCIETY March 2000Peters, Pierre MUTU
 
The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...
The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...
The Organization and Direction of Human Resources for Set Goals: A Public Adm...
 
Social Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docx
Social Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docxSocial Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docx
Social Value Added AMetric for ImplementingCorporate Soci.docx
 
10 kelly mulgan muers creating public value
10 kelly mulgan muers creating public value10 kelly mulgan muers creating public value
10 kelly mulgan muers creating public value
 
Defining Public Administration
Defining Public AdministrationDefining Public Administration
Defining Public Administration
 
Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...
Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...
Book review on The Public Sector: Concepts, Models and Approaches By Jan-Erik...
 
New Public Management, is it a reality?
New Public Management, is it a reality?New Public Management, is it a reality?
New Public Management, is it a reality?
 
New Public Management
New Public ManagementNew Public Management
New Public Management
 
6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docx
6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docx6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docx
6.1. Week 6 DiscussionThe topics for this weeks Discussion are.docx
 
Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)
Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)
Achieving MDGs through NPM (Bangladesh perspective)
 
Developments in public management theory
Developments in public management theoryDevelopments in public management theory
Developments in public management theory
 
Comparaive management
Comparaive managementComparaive management
Comparaive management
 
Accountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGO
Accountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGOAccountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGO
Accountability CED: The Funder-Governed NGO
 
The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling
The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling
The rise of Social Capital and collapse of traditional Market Signalling
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen

4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptx
4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptx4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptx
4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptxmary850239
 
Multi Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP Module
Multi Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP ModuleMulti Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP Module
Multi Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP ModuleCeline George
 
Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4
Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4
Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4JOYLYNSAMANIEGO
 
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentationCongestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentationdeepaannamalai16
 
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnvESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnvRicaMaeCastro1
 
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...Association for Project Management
 
Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1
Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1
Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1GloryAnnCastre1
 
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptxGrade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptxkarenfajardo43
 
Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...
Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...
Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...DhatriParmar
 
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQuiz Club NITW
 
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea DevelopmentUsing Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Developmentchesterberbo7
 
ClimART Action | eTwinning Project
ClimART Action    |    eTwinning ProjectClimART Action    |    eTwinning Project
ClimART Action | eTwinning Projectjordimapav
 
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptxDecoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptxDhatriParmar
 
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young mindsMental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young mindsPooky Knightsmith
 
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...Seán Kennedy
 
How to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 Database
How to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 DatabaseHow to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 Database
How to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 DatabaseCeline George
 
Q4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptx
Q4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptxQ4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptx
Q4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptxlancelewisportillo
 
4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptx
4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptx4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptx
4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptxmary850239
 
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQuiz Club NITW
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen (20)

4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptx
4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptx4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptx
4.11.24 Mass Incarceration and the New Jim Crow.pptx
 
Multi Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP Module
Multi Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP ModuleMulti Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP Module
Multi Domain Alias In the Odoo 17 ERP Module
 
Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4
Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4
Daily Lesson Plan in Mathematics Quarter 4
 
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentationCongestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
Congestive Cardiac Failure..presentation
 
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnvESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
ESP 4-EDITED.pdfmmcncncncmcmmnmnmncnmncmnnjvnnv
 
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
Team Lead Succeed – Helping you and your team achieve high-performance teamwo...
 
Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1
Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1
Reading and Writing Skills 11 quarter 4 melc 1
 
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptxGrade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
Grade Three -ELLNA-REVIEWER-ENGLISH.pptx
 
Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...
Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...
Blowin' in the Wind of Caste_ Bob Dylan's Song as a Catalyst for Social Justi...
 
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor General Quiz-7th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
 
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea DevelopmentUsing Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
Using Grammatical Signals Suitable to Patterns of Idea Development
 
ClimART Action | eTwinning Project
ClimART Action    |    eTwinning ProjectClimART Action    |    eTwinning Project
ClimART Action | eTwinning Project
 
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptxDecoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
Decoding the Tweet _ Practical Criticism in the Age of Hashtag.pptx
 
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
31 ĐỀ THI THỬ VÀO LỚP 10 - TIẾNG ANH - FORM MỚI 2025 - 40 CÂU HỎI - BÙI VĂN V...
 
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young mindsMental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
Mental Health Awareness - a toolkit for supporting young minds
 
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
 
How to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 Database
How to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 DatabaseHow to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 Database
How to Make a Duplicate of Your Odoo 17 Database
 
Q4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptx
Q4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptxQ4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptx
Q4-PPT-Music9_Lesson-1-Romantic-Opera.pptx
 
4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptx
4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptx4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptx
4.11.24 Poverty and Inequality in America.pptx
 
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITWQ-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
Q-Factor HISPOL Quiz-6th April 2024, Quiz Club NITW
 

Grandy2009

  • 1. Christopher Grandy University of Hawaii The “Efficient” Public Administrator: Pareto and a New Ideas for Improving Public Well-Rounded Approach to Public Administration Administration The New Public Management movement was only alternatives which produces the largest result for the Christopher Grandy is an associate professor of public administration at the latest demand that public organizations promote given application of resources” (Simon 1976, 179). the University of Hawaii (Manoa). After efficiency by adopting business methods. There again Herbert A. Simon (1976, xxviii–xxxi) softened the im- completing a doctorate in economics at followed reactions from those arguing that other values, plied dictate to public administrators by recognizing the University of California, Berkeley, he taught in the economics departments of such as equity, citizen participation, and democracy, are the bounded, rather than full, rationality of human Barnard College and the University of as important as efficiency. This article suggests that an beings and by acknowledging the appropriateness of Hawaii before working for six years as economic rather than business perspective on efficiency satisficing, rather than optimizing behavior. Yet, as an economist for the Hawaii Department of Business, Economic Development, and may usefully contribute to the scholarly conversation. It observed by Hendriekje van der Meer and Mark R. Tourism. He specializes in public policy and also suggests that it is “efficient” to identify the public Rutgers, technical efficiency still dominates the field: public finance issues, particularly taxation values in play within any given situation. “The most encompassing or general meaning of ef- and public budgeting. He was a member of the 2005–2007 Hawaii State Tax Review ficiency as used in the public administration literature Commission. A lmost from the beginnings of the field, ef- is represented by the term ‘technical efficiency.’ Tech- E-mail: grandy@hawaii.edu ficiency has been a source of contention in nical efficiency can be defined as the ‘ratio between public administration. As George W. Downs input and output’” (2006, 3). The difficulty with and Patrick D. Larkey observed two decades ago, applying this definition to the public sector is that the “Efficiency ranks with motherhood, apple pie, citizen “problem” can rarely be framed so easily. Instead, ends participation, and balanced budgets as a fundamental are multiple and shifting. American value” (1986, 237). And yet, fairly quickly in public administration’s his- This article began as an tory, challenges to efficiency as a economist’s reaction to the primary public value were artic- The suggestion by those critique of efficiency central to ulated by those acknowledging skeptical of [New Public the arguments of those critical other values such as equity, citi- Management’s] orientation that of the New Public Manage- zenship, and public deliberation. ment (NPM) paradigm. To a efficiency is only one of several In concluding a review of the new member of a small public “rational model” of public or- values that public managers administration program, the ef- ganizations, Robert B. Denhardt might appropriately pursue ficiency focus of NPM seemed observes that, despite decades of [seems] . . . odd, at best. For a sensible, if somewhat obvious, challenges, the model’s emphasis the view implies that a manager goal for public organizations. on “technical rationality (often might sacrifice efficiency in The suggestion by those skepti- translated as ‘efficiency’)” (2004, cal of NPM’s orientation that order to advance other values. 87) continues to dominate as a efficiency is only one of several primary criterion for the evalua- Yet given a particular goal, values that public managers tion of public organizations. wouldn’t one always want to might appropriately pursue pursue it efficiently? appeared odd, at best. For the Much of the controversy over view implies that a manager efficiency within public admin- might sacrifice efficiency in or- istration revolves around a definition that Downs and der to advance other values. Yet given a particular goal, Larkey term “managerial efficiency” (1986, 6) and wouldn’t one always want to pursue it efficiently? Denhardt calls “technical rationality” (2004, 25). This notion of efficiency envisions managers pursuing the The literature on efficiency within public administra- least costly means of achieving given ends.1 Or, from tion has modified these initial reactions, and, using another direction, “efficiency dictates that choice of an unconventional focus, this article argues that an The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1115
  • 2. economist’s notion of Pareto efficiency can be useful in the debate. Another source of suspicion came from efficiency’s association with In the words of Van der Meer and Rutgers, “a more limited inter- private—that is, business—administration (Waldo 1952, 83–84). pretation of efficiency as technical efficiency will not do” (2006, 9). Businesses, in a competitive environment, must be primarily Ironically, Pareto efficiency’s usefulness lies in a direction that many, concerned with maximizing profit. Being efficient implies pursu- suspicious of economic thinking in the public sector, advocate— ing activities that are most likely to increase profits. Besides being becoming clearer about values. somewhat distasteful, many within public administration simply found this notion of efficiency inappropriate for public institu- Efficiency in Public Administration tions. The analogy was inapt. Public agencies do not have a single, Efficiency was privileged at the beginnings of the field as Progressive well-specified objective that all agree they should pursue. Instead, Era reforms sought to systematize and rationalize the administration as discussed later, public agencies face multiple objectives reflect- of the public’s business.2 The Progressive movement that ushered in ing multiple values. In this context, it is not even clear what public the notion of professional public management was, in large part, a efficiency would mean.4 reaction against the inefficiencies of the spoils system that had come before (Hood 1995, 94; Waldo 1952, 86). Appeals to efficiency The controversy over efficiency reemerged with respect to the New justified the centralization of public functions, the rise of bureaucra- Public Management and reinventing government movements. In cies, and executive budgeting. spite of Waldo’s (1952, 88) suggestion that, 50 years ago, public ad- ministrators were rejecting efficiency as a criterion for public action, Two early public administration writers who held a broad view “efficiency” has hung on. David Osborne and Ted Gaebler’s popular of efficiency were Morris Cooke and Frederick Cleveland. Citing book (1993), and the wave of writings known as the New Public Hindy Lauer Schachter’s (1989) work, Van der Meer and Rutgers Management, raised again the call for government to “get more (2006, 10) note that Cooke and Cleveland thought of efficiency as bang for the buck”—that is, to be more efficient.5 The New Zealand a means of promoting public responsiveness to citizen demands in a reforms that ushered in the NPM discussion, and the U.S. federal democracy. Curiously, however, both Schachter (1989, 76, 99) and government’s reinvention efforts, even harked back to the business Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 10) interpret this perspective as metaphor of efficiency that had appealed to the Progressives.6 In implying that efficiency is a secondary, rather than a primary, value. response, many in public administration have reacted with skepti- One might instead note that the Cooke/Cleveland view implies that cism to the call for greater efficiency.7 efficiency is a basic value—one that undergirds and supports the broader values of government activity. This interpretive difference is Multiple Values and Pareto discussed more fully later. Perhaps the primary objection to “efficiency” as a guiding principle of public administration is that it seems so Public administration scholars came to ques- narrow. Being efficient suggests selecting one, Perhaps the primary tion the preeminence of efficiency as they or at most a handful, of values at the core of challenged the Progressives’ separation of objection to “efficiency” as a public agencies. It connotes single-mindedly politics from administration. That separation guiding principle of public pursuing an objective with little attention to was a defining feature of the first phase of administration is that it seems external effects. Thus, Waldo suggested that professional administration. As Dwight Waldo so narrow. Being efficient economy and efficiency are about “getting (1952, 87) noted nearly 60 years ago, sepa- suggests selecting one, or at things done” (1952, 93–94), with little at- rating politics from administration did not tention to how they are done. Yet how things most a handful, of values at the square with the observation that agencies were are done—and, in particular, how people are as much enmeshed in political maneuvering core of public agencies. treated as they get things done—is of princi- as were legislatures. Thus, if administrators pal interest to many. One can imagine a mod- effectively make value decisions, then they cannot be seen as simply ern Taylorite suggesting to the manager of a state tax department choosing the “optimal” method of implementing policy decisions. that he or she measure the number of returns processed, with the implied goal of maximizing that number per unit of time. Skeptics These critiques of efficiency also objected to separating means from might worry about the values sacrificed in pursuing such a goal. ends (Waldo 1952, 90–91). Critics noted that “means are relative to ends,” that administration is not an end in itself, and that students The prescriptions of reinventing government and the NPM litera- of public administration must abandon the notion that “efficiency ture seem similarly narrow. In several places, Osborne and Gaebler and economy are objectives superior to any others that may be (1993, 35–36, 77, 79) focus on lowering the costs of public services sought” (Kingsley 1945, 89). This directly challenged the technical and minimizing waste (78, 81, 119). In advocating “mission-driven” meaning of efficiency as finding an “optimal” method of advancing public organizations, the authors (14, 113) attacked public agency given ends. If, as Aaron Wildavsky (1966, 292, 298, 299–300) sug- rules that stifle effective delivery of services. Osborne and Gaebler’s gested, means and ends are jointly determined, then in what sense book talked of putting the customer first; of making public manag- is a criterion of “efficiency” well specified that focuses on the many ers more entrepreneurial, presumably with the intention of finding means by which an end could be attained?3 Moreover, as Denhardt innovative ways to provide services—perhaps on a paying basis; and observes, concentrating on efficiency alone draws attention away of eliminating rules that lead to higher costs. The authors did not from ends, and in doing so, “we might fail to fully examine and explicitly advocate a single goal. Indeed, in some places, they recog- participate in decisions that are of importance to us, thus failing to nized that there may be multiple goals. But the overall sense of their meet our democratic obligations” (2004, 150). prescriptions was to weed out the “inefficiencies” of public activity 1116 Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
  • 3. by refocusing on something like “core” values. Similarly, the federal rather than business. For example, if society values citizen partici- government’s reinvention efforts, reflected in the National Perform- pation, the fulfillment of minimal physical requirements for all, ance Review (1993, chap. 3-2), urged Congress to simplify the universal education, and economic growth—to propose a necessarily responsibilities of public agencies in order to enable management ac- abbreviated list—then an efficient use of resources would require countability. In general, Denhardt (2004, 140) notes, NPM sought that it be impossible to advance some of these values without reduc- to impose a new set of values, coming from the business sector. ing others. If such advancement is possible, then currently society is not using resources efficiently—some of society’s goals could be Critics of NPM point out that the efficiency prescriptions of furthered without reducing the levels of others. Those familiar with government reinventors excluded important, but not necessarily economic welfare analysis will recognize this as a particular applica- measurable, public values. Thus, Demetrios Argyriades (2003, 523) tion of the Pareto efficiency principle.8 Rather than being applied to argues that the rise of efficiency in the hierarchy of public organiza- the allocation of goods and services, however, the suggestion here is tion values has been accompanied by a lowering of the rule of law that the public administrator apply the criterion to the public values and of due process. In his view (526–27), privileging efficiency at play in a particular issue. Notice that the definition does not re- undermines debate, consultation, and public deliberation. Linda quire specifying the overall objective to be advanced—it is sufficient deLeon and Robert B. Denhardt (2000, 93–95) see the reinvention to list the component elements (in this case, public values) that movement as devaluing collaboration, the public interest, and citi- contribute to the objective. Of course, there may be much discus- zenship. Suzanne J. Piotrowski and David H. Rosenbloom (2002, sion about that list. 646) note official concern with efficiency well before the New Public Management ideas took hold, quoting a 1972 U.S. Supreme Court Pareto efficiency differs substantially from how “efficiency” is decision that observed that the due process clause may be inter- commonly used in the public administration literature. Thus, it preted as a mechanism to protect citizens from the overly rigorous is offered here not as a refutation of the concerns about technical pursuit of efficiency by competent public servants. Rita Mae Kelly rationality raised by critics of NPM so much as a way of looking at asserts that others go further, arguing that “[p]rocedural due process, efficiency that is both consistent with a broad perspective on public substantive rights, equity, and protection of minority rights . . . are management and, ironically, more consistent with efficiency’s stand- values that have precedence over efficiency” (1998, 201). Michael ard definition in economics. As noted earlier, technical efficiency Spicer (2007) argues that NPM advocates ignore the intended role (also known as technical rationality and managerial efficiency) is of politics in managing conflict over values and thereby threaten the usual efficiency concept in public administration, understood harm in promoting simplistic solutions to complex problems. as pursuing “given objectives with the least cost,” or as a ratio of output to input.9 Moreover, many express concerns about proposals, Denhardt (2004, 8–9) provides a useful example of efficiency- such as those implied by NPM advocates, to focus on efficiency be- motivated, narrow goals. Two experienced managers were tasked cause “efficiency is a value chosen from among a larger set of values with quickly establishing a housing loan program. As the supervi- and . . . the adoption of the value of efficiency precludes attention sor, John was under considerable pressure, both from within the to any other, such as equity and participation” (Denhardt 2004, organization and from potential clients, to process applications 105). In contrast, the concept of Pareto efficiency leaves goals and rapidly. His co-manager, Carol, recognized the need for quick action their underlying values unspecified, explicitly allowing for multiple but also had more direct contact with potential clients. To speed goals and values. Pareto efficiency is attained only if it is impossible things along, John asked Carol to have clients sign blank applica- to advance any of the goals without impairing at least one of the tion forms, which could later be filled in as information arrived. others. In this sense, Pareto efficiency is value neutral, or, as Luther Carol objected, wanting to provide clients full information and Gulick (1937, 192–93) implied, it is efficiency as meta-value. As ap- concerned about potential illegality. Denhardt observes that John plied here, Pareto efficiency is therefore broader than the concept of seemed “most concerned with the efficient completion of the task” technical efficiency commonly used in public administration. (9). Here, Denhardt uses efficiency to refer to the quick processing of loan applications. Implicitly, getting “work out the door”—that The difference may be illustrated by returning to the example of the is, loan applications completed and filed—is the agency’s primary housing loan program. John’s suggestion to have clients sign blank work. Anything that interfered with that task threatened to make forms advances one goal: getting applications into the pipeline the program look inefficient. as quickly as possible. But if John and Carol applied the Pareto efficiency concept, they would explicitly consider whether other In the “real world,” public decision makers face multiple values, goals exist. There may be trust-building and education functions and these values come from multiple sources. Assuredly, legisla- fulfilled by communicating frequently with clients and in going tive bodies give public agencies a variety of marching orders. But over information submitted on their housing applications. Signing the executive (mayor, governor, president) may take a somewhat blank forms may advance the goal of getting applications processed different perspective on these instructions, urging movement in one quickly, but it impairs the communication and trust-building goals. direction rather than another. Moreover, the media and constituents From this perspective, an exclusive focus on fast processing does not express their own views and demands—sometimes requiring the advance (Pareto) efficiency because it promotes one of the agency’s administrator to respond in ways that differ from what the executive goals while reducing others.10 or legislators might choose. Public administration scholars have occasionally commented on The point of this article is that the existence of multiple values is Pareto efficiency, but usually in a cursory fashion. For example, in consistent with a definition of efficiency that comes from economics his deconstruction of efficiency, David John Farmer (1995, 199) The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1117
  • 4. briefly mentions the Pareto concept and notes that it does not denying the claim; the value of upholding the authority of the legis- guarantee a just allocation of goods and services. While Patria D. lative mandate overrides the claim of the business manager. de Lancer (1999, 536) uses the term in her description of a specific technique for evaluating efficiency in public organizations, the The contest over values also evolves. At one point, public deci- concept of Pareto efficiency is much broader than the technical sion makers deemed it appropriate to expend resources segregating application she presents. Van der Meer and Rutgers suggest that public facilities by race. Today, most people would consider such a because a Pareto-efficient, or Pareto-optimal, allocation of resources use of resources inappropriate—that is, illegitimate (not to mention means that it is impossible to improve the welfare of one person illegal). This reflects an evolution of values toward the “universal without reducing that of another, the “welfare of society is at its equality framework” that Kelly (1998, 203) notes took nearly 200 maximum” (2006, 5). They unfortunately characterize the concept years to achieve. Similarly, decisions made in the aftermath of the as a synonym for “optimality,” which thereby falls outside the scope 9/11 terrorist attacks that conflict with understandings of civil liber- of the concepts of efficiency with which public administration ties may be seen as wholly inappropriate 20 years from now.13 This deals.11 observation is consistent with Charles E. Lindblom’s (1959) incre- mental model of public decision making, which stresses the complex Peter Self stands out as a sustained public administration critic of and varying nature of promoting public values. what he called the “absurdly revered ‘Pareto principle’” (1985, 70) as a criterion for public decision making. It is important to understand Lindblom’s (1990) later work expands on the idea of evolving that Self addressed the Pareto concept as it is usually applied in values. In Lindblom’s framework, individuals in society are, to economics—that is, as a criterion of proposed policy that affects the one degree or another, engaged in probing their world in order distribution of goods and services in an economy. Instead, this ar- to figure things out. Such probing may be impaired in various ticle proposes that public administrators apply the Pareto efficiency ways—including by professional social scientists. Yet he sees a concept to the public values that are at play in a particular situation. society in which many (all?) members participate in the process Self ’s critiques, and this distinction, are elaborated on later. of advancing knowledge and understanding; Lindblom calls this a self-guiding society. This guidance presumably applies to all aspects As discussed in the next section, a positive consequence of using the of knowledge—including the identification, modification, and Pareto efficiency concept is the implied need to be clear about which acceptance or rejection of legitimate values. Exploring the process values are legitimately “public.” by which such values are agreed upon lies beyond the scope of this article. However, as discussed later, the public administrator is in a Pareto Efficiency as Necessary, but unique position to participate in such prob- Not Sufficient, Meta-Value ing and, indeed, to advance or hinder values When an administrator makes When an administrator makes a decision in by his or her decisions. The Pareto efficiency the multiple-value environment, he or she a decision in our multiple- criterion, applied as suggested here, provides may be hard-pressed to explain the process. value environment, he or she public administrators with a conceptual The political and economic forces that emerge may be hard-pressed to explain framework that can improve the quality of for a particular problem are varied and com- the process. The political and their decisions in ways that are consistent plex, and the values put forward come from economic forces that emerge with Lindblom’s vision. many quarters with differing intensities. Thus, for a particular problem are the administrator of a tax compliance unit, From the Pareto efficiency perspective, to say attempting to determine whether a business varied and complex, and the that an agency acts inefficiently is to say either tax credit should apply in a specific case, may values put forward come from (1) that it pursues some values that are not le- face several sources of influence: legislators many quarters with differing gitimate, or (2) that it neglects to pursue some who voted for the credit on the grounds of intensities. legitimate values that it can affect. Thus, the diversifying the local economy; legislators who tax compliance administrator who approves opposed the credit with concerns about the the application of the business tax credit to fiscal implications; businesses who may qualify for the credit; busi- his brother’s firm, despite having rejected similar claims by others in nesses who clearly do not qualify and wonder where their tax break the past, is acting inefficiently. The inefficiency lies in promoting a is; and taxpayers who are concerned about the upward pressure on value (the support of his brother’s company) that is not legitimate rates that might result from the negative revenue implications. The from a public perspective. Similarly, should Carol, the housing loan values implicit in these perspectives are legitimate, and the adminis- program co-manager, make no effort toward moving applications trator who ignores many of them will find life unpleasant.12 along, then she would be acting inefficiently. However, to say that an agency faces the task of managing multiple Of course, the word “efficiency” is often part of the contest over values does not imply that all values are legitimate. In a general the legitimacy of values. Downs and Larkey observe a tendency to sense, one can imagine values put forward to cover as many interests label as “inefficient” the pursuit of goals “that differ from one’s own” as there are people in the community. Clearly, not all can receive (1986, 13). “Efficiency” is a powerful word, whose use can bestow equal weight when allocating public resources. The businessperson legitimacy on the ideas to which it is attached. Thus, the early public whose activities obviously fall outside the scope of a tax credit’s leg- administration writers who sought to incorporate business methods, islative intent may argue that all businesses—including his—should such as formal hierarchical organization, into the public sphere did get a break. But the administrator is not likely to have much trouble so in large part by appealing to efficiency (see, e.g., Denhardt 2004, 1118 Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
  • 5. 77). As has been noted, promoters of NPM, explicitly utilizing busi- defined relative to other values, the concept takes the superordinat- ness concepts, made similar appeals to efficiency. Downs and Larkey ing status of meta-value rather than a subordinating, second-order observed that “efficiency is [often] less a goal of reorganization than status. For the Pareto proposition is to “efficiently” pursue the set of a justification for it” (1986, 186). values deemed relevant in a particular situation (where this means taking actions that advance at least one value without impairing Virtually all of the critiques of NPM prescriptions can be seen as others). In this interpretation, efficiency is not a second-order value examples of the contest over which values to include in the “legiti- as a result of its relationship to other values, nor can efficiency be mate” set. For example, Argyriades’s implicit critique of the “3Es seen as merely one of many values without priority, because it makes (economy, efficiency, and effectiveness)” (2003, 523) is a defense no sense to think of trading off Pareto efficiency for another value of the values of rule of law, due process, debate, and public delib- over which it is defined. Rather, the notion of Pareto efficiency eration. DeLeon and Denhardt’s (2000) critique of reinvention’s with respect to public values raises “efficiency” to meta-value, even market, customer service, and entrepreneurial orientations empha- beyond where Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 15–16) place their sizes the values of collaboration, the public interest, and citizenship. concept of “substantive efficiency” (defined as a general assessment Here, “efficiency” is seen as one value that is advanced at the expense of well-functioning administration) as equal with other values. of others. And yet, this article does not propose that Pareto efficiency can be Yet these critiques apply to the technical, or managerial, efficiency relied on as a sole guide for managerial action. Many combinations concept of Denhardt (2004, 87), Downs and Larkey (1986, 6), of public values may be consistent with the Pareto criterion. More- and Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 3) rather than to the Pareto over, public managers must often make decisions that violate the concept. The objections come down to insisting that pursuing Pareto criterion. That is, they are compelled to make decisions that (technical or managerial) efficiency neglects other, valued goals that advance some legitimate values at the expense of others. Making an agency might legitimately pursue. In contrast, Pareto efficiency those decisions is not a matter of efficiency as defined by the Pareto characterizes a relationship among values: given the set of legitimate criterion. It lies beyond efficiency. That is, the concept of Pareto values, efficiency is defined in terms of whether some must be sacri- efficiency gets the administrator only so far as a guide to action. It ficed in order to advance others. tells the administrator to be on the lookout for the multiple values in play in a given situation. But the likely course of action will have Stated another way, the trade-off among values cannot apply to the to be taken on grounds other than efficiency itself.14 concept of (Pareto) efficiency. If by “efficiency,” one means “tech- nical rationality” or “managerial efficiency,” then such a trade-off Given that managers must make decisions that choose among val- makes sense: one could imagine consciously incurring higher than ues, it seems desirable that as many legitimate values as possible be minimum costs in order to advance another value, such as due included in the decision maker’s calculus.15 Otherwise, the manager process. But Pareto efficiency is defined in terms of trade-offs among will make decisions that neglect some legitimate values. For exam- values: administrators have acted efficiently if it is not possible ple, the tax compliance manager who focuses only on the number of to advance any of society’s legitimate values without accepting a returns processed each month may neglect the values of fairness and reduction in another. If all legitimate values are considered, then it accuracy in taking more time with particularly complicated cases. would be tautological to propose a trade-off of Pareto efficiency for Similarly, John’s proposal to have clients sign blank application another value. This point emphasizes the very different meanings forms may have been made without regard to the trust-building and between technical rationality or managerial efficiency (a value that communication goals of the unit. For these reasons, a grounding in can be conceptually weighed against other values, as in Jorgensen common knowledge and shared values, to which Kelly (1998, 202) and Bozeman 2007, 367), and Pareto efficiency (a statement about a refers, ensures that, within a specific context, the manager does not particular set of values). exclude important values in play. Schachter (2007, 807) notes that acquiring such a grounding requires that the Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 9–10, 14) public manager engage with the community’s discuss related issues that serve to emphasize . . . the notion of Pareto citizens. the meta-value status of Pareto efficiency rela- efficiency with respect to public tive to other definitions. The authors (9–10) values raises “efficiency” to Of course, literally considering all values note that Dwight Waldo famously observed is impossible, and an attempt to do so is meta-value, . . . yet this article that it does not make sense to advocate “being likely undesirable. Again, Lindblom’s (1959) efficient” in the abstract. To be operational, ef- does not propose . . . that Pareto work is relevant in that he argued against an ficiency must be related to the pursuit of some efficiency can be relied upon analytical model that attempts a complete particular value or goal. Because efficiency as a sole guide for managerial listing of alternative methods for achieving can only be understood with respect to other action. a given end. Lindblom’s apt objection is that values, Waldo (1984, 193) concluded that constructing such a list is impossible in most efficiency could not be fundamental to public cases and undesirable to the extent that valu- administration. Van der Meer and Rutgers adopt this perspective able resources are used in constructing a list, most of which would with respect to technical efficiency, arguing that “[e]fficiency can be irrelevant to the actual decision made. be seen as a second-order value” (2006, 14). Yet, as suggested in this article, if one instead adopts the Pareto efficiency criterion with Thus the set of “all” legitimate values must be read as all values that respect to public values, then, although efficiency continues to be the administrator, upon self-reflection and in consultation with The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1119
  • 6. colleagues and the public, can reasonably identify as being related to Second, and more importantly, the public manager’s utilization the question at hand. The goal of such reflection (a form of Lind- of the Pareto principle as applied to the public values at play in a blom’s probing) is to cut short the urge to quickly identify a course particular issue compels explicit consideration of those values. In of action at the cost of negative unintended consequences. If the this sense, conscious application of the Pareto principle can promote administrator takes the time to identify relevant values in play, then a transformative, value-regarding approach to public administration. he or she is more likely to be prepared for challenges to the policy As mentioned, such an approach is consistent with Lindblom’s call proposal and to anticipate further developments. Acting in this way for “probing” societal issues. The application of the Pareto principle is consistent with acting (Pareto) efficiently. by public managers is a concrete step toward ensuring that public managers engage in, and support, such probing either within the It is instructive to understand Self ’s critique of Pareto efficiency walls of a public institution or in the broader community. Thus, as and why it has less force in the context suggested here. For Self, the John and Carol develop the habit of asking themselves what public major objection to Pareto efficiency as applied to goods and services values are at play in a given situation, and whether some of those is that it essentially conserves the status quo.16 If adopted as a policy values can be advanced by actions that do not impair others, they criterion, Pareto efficiency requires permitting only changes in the continuously remind themselves of the larger context of their work. distribution of goods and services that make at least one person bet- And they regularly remind themselves of the boundaries at which ter off and no persons worse off; thus, implicitly, the existing distri- further pursuit of some values requires accepting the diminution bution of goods and services is privileged (Self 1977, 26, 143; 1985, of others. The managers thereby open themselves to the option of 70; 1993, 248–49). Moreover, strict application of the criterion to seeking public input about those choices and of participating in public policy would virtually guarantee that nothing gets done— dialogue about both the set of relevant values and how their con- because the criterion essentially gives veto power to anyone who may stituents weigh them. claim harm from a change in policy (Self 1985, 76; 1993, 249). Finally, the Pareto efficiency approach envisions a role for public While these are strong arguments against the adoption of Pareto administrators that is philosophically distinct from that of NPM’s efficiency as a general criterion for public policy decisions, they have advocates. Vice President Al Gore is quoted in the National Per- less force in the context suggested here of an administrator’s con- formance Review with respect to values as follows: “There has to be siderations of the relevant public values in a specific issue. A public a clear, shared sense of mission. There have to be clearly understood decision maker can be said to be acting efficiently with respect to a goals. There have to be common values according to which deci- public issue if he or she has reached a point where it is impossible to sions are made. There has to be trust placed in the employees who further at least one public value relevant to that issue without im- actually do the work” (1993, chap. 3-2). While these might be desir- pairing other relevant public values. Once that point is reached, the able features of a well-focused public agency, getting to this point administrator will have to make decisions that involve trading off is nontrivial. In the real world of most public agencies that manage at least one value against others, and so those decisions lie beyond complex issues with multiple facets, the costs of seeking value con- efficiency. If society forbade the administrator to act beyond the sensus should be weighed against the likely success. Alternatively, Pareto efficiency criterion, then Self ’s critiques would apply here; if managers are imbued with the mind-set to consider the range of then, Pareto efficiency would be of little help to the administrator. public values raised by a particular issue, then the sense of shared However, once an administrator has exhausted efforts to advance mission and values becomes an ongoing, negotiated process within relevant public values where no impairment of others is implied, and among agencies and the public. This description of process may then the requirements of efficiency have been satisfied. The admin- be a more realistic guide for public managers than the end-state istrator may then move on to consider the (probably more difficult) envisioned in Vice President Gore’s remarks. issues of which public values to advance at the expense of others and by what criteria to make those choices.17 It is worth noting characteristics of the public decision-making process that are likely to be consistent with, if not necessary to, The adoption of this application of Pareto efficiency by public the use of the Pareto principle proposed here. First, the approach decision makers offers both (1) a modest improvement in the presumes the existence of a degree of openness to discussion and immediate allocation of energies by administrators with influence issues exploration (Lindblom’s probing) within the public agency. on public policy, and (2) a significant step forward in the quality In an autocratic, closed organizational environment, it may be of public decision processes. First, in the short run, to encourage impossible to even pose the question of which values are in play public managers to take actions that will advance some goal(s) that in an issue—because the question suggests that other values might do not impair the attainment of others seems common sense. The be considered. Of course, there are different degrees of openness, more frequent, and more difficult, problem facing an administrator and even in strongly hierarchical organizations, it may be possible involves choosing among actions, all of which require sacrificing for managers to find ways to pose thought-provoking (thought- some desirable goals in order to advance others. Thus, the problem promoting?) questions in the guise of loyalty to the organization: facing John and Carol is not simply how to minimize processing for example, “How should we expect constituent group X to react time—it is how to get the housing loan program going quickly to our proposed course of action?” Such questions at least open the while promoting the trust-building and educational goals of the door to a strategic, and possibly substantive, discussion of other agency.18 Application of the Pareto principle at least satisfies the goal values in play.19 of using available resources efficiently—making sure that actions are undertaken that promote some values which do not threaten other A second institutional feature implied by the explicit adoption values. of Pareto efficiency with respect to public values relates to public 1120 Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
  • 7. forums. If public administrators begin to practice the accounting of the multiple, legitimate values at play. Their decisions may not for public values that the Pareto principle requires, then they will be explainable in terms of maximizing a well-defined function that find themselves compelled to seek direct information about such indexes the component legitimate values. But if the administrator values in conversations with constituents, meetings with community can provide a coherent explanation of why some values are pursued groups, public hearings, legislative committee meetings, and so on. more fully than others, and can do this for the relevant legitimate Efforts to seriously identify public values in play demand such in- values, then she has succeeded in implicitly weighing those values in put. And the conversation goes both ways. For the public adminis- some way. This approach may be thought of as an extension of the trator must also be able to articulate his or her reasoning in arriving “let managers manage” philosophy—by adding the requirement that at a decision. If such reasoning explicitly acknowledges public values managers be prepared to explain their choices.21 And the manager that are relevant, but that have not been advanced by a particular has satisfied the economic definition of efficiency: using available decision, then the administrator may have at least signaled aware- resources so that it is not possible to advance some values without ness of those values and accepted their relevance. That may not impairing others.22 appease the ardent activist, but it may prove helpful in subsequent encounters. Thus, adoption of this application of Pareto efficiency Denhardt (2004, 153) argues that practitioners want a public both contributes to an improved (inclusive) decision-making proc- administration theory that provides them understanding from ess and it provides a framework within which to legitimate decisions which new approaches to their work can be constructed, as well as once made. a conceptual framework within which to interpret their experience. In this light, the long-standing public administration debate about We should note here Lindblom’s (1990, 109–14) concern about efficiency must be particularly frustrating. The approach suggested public officials using their position and authority to impair the here may offer the practitioner some clarity that is consistent with probing process. The public administrator described here is one of an important version of efficiency: many who have some decision-making authority with respect to public issues. Lindblom expresses concern that the official might Accept that you will be placed under demands from many choose to make his or her life easier by suppressing discussion and sources and that you will have to weigh the values implied. conflict over values. Yet this would violate the maintained assump- Some of these values will carry more weight than others, tion that the administrator wishes to act efficiently; if that is not the and these weights will shift over time. When presented with case, then the implied management issues lie beyond this article’s the (probably rare) opportunity to advance some values scope. In the framework described here, the administrator must without impairing others, pursue it vigorously. Most of the explicitly consider other views and values in order to act efficiently. rest of the time you will have to choose among competing Moreover, that consideration by the administrator may be the most values; do so with awareness for what is being advanced and constructive result of her effort to be efficient. what is not. Herein lies the value of adopting the Pareto definition of efficiency If this advice does not seem particularly startling, that may be a in public administration: it forces the decision maker to identify good thing. For it suggests an approach to administration that is the values in play.20 This may lead to recognition that some of the consistent with the view that an important part of the work of values are not legitimate, in which case the course of action becomes public managers is to “express the values of our society” (Denhardt relatively clear. In cases in which many conflicting values are legiti- 2004, 192). mate, explicit identification may help the decision maker embark on a process that will determine a decision. But the administrator The argument offered here is not that efficiency is unimportant, nor will not be able to justify that decision on the basis of efficiency. In that some values are more important than efficiency. Indeed, the most cases, all the administrator can do is to start from a position in concept of Pareto efficiency places it in the position of meta-value. which he or she is using resources well (Pareto efficiently) and then The argument here is that managers need not run the risk of being make decisions in awareness of the value trade-offs. accused of inefficiency when they entertain contending values. Pareto efficiency requires that they do so. Nevertheless, manag- In the housing loan example, ultimately, John’s direction to sign ers will often have to justify decisions on grounds that go beyond blank forms might be defensible. If John was well aware of the efficiency. In this sense, efficiency is a necessary, but not sufficient, potential negative impact on client trust and, in light of that, still condition for sensibly and responsibly carrying out the work of felt the overriding need to get some applications processed immedi- public organizations. ately, then the decision might not be gainsaid. Perhaps more likely, reflecting on the negative impact on client Acknowledgments trust and the possible long-term impairment The author is especially grateful to Dick Pratt of the client base, John might look for ways to This article has argued that public for his patient guidance and suggestions dur- ameliorate those effects—perhaps by making ing the writing of this article. For extensive the signing of blank forms temporary. administrators act in ways that comments on earlier versions, thanks go to are consistent with “efficiency” Roger Blair, Jim Mak, Jim Roumasset, and Conclusion when they make decisions Sumner LaCroix. Valuable suggestions were This article has argued that public administra- while aware of the multiple, made by Jill Tao, David Nixon, and Tsedev tors act in ways that are consistent with “effi- legitimate values at play. Damiran. Mark Rutgers kindly shared his un- ciency” when they make decisions while aware published work. Finally, the author gratefully The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1121
  • 8. acknowledges the careful reading and suggestions offered by three in the sense that the value of a social welfare function has peaked. anonymous reviewers of PAR. Lockwood notes that a particular allocation of resources is only Pareto-optimal “in the limited sense that not everybody can be made Notes better off,” and for this reason, “the word ‘Pareto-optimal’ has gradu- 1. As expressed, for example, in Gulick (1937, 192). For recent sub- ally been replaced by ‘Pareto-efficient’” (1987, 811). In any case, the stantive discussions of efficiency in public administration, see Van Pareto efficiency concept suggested here relates not to the allocation der Meer and Rutgers (2006) and Schachter (2007). of goods and services in society (the usual definition), but instead to 2. See Dwight Waldo (1952) for a survey of public administration’s the relevant public values involved in a particular issue. In this sense, origins as part of his call for a theory of “democratic administration.” this article transfers the Pareto efficiency concept from the economic 3. Similarly, Denhardt’s (2004, 71–72) discussion of Robert Dahl’s realm to the realm of applied public decision making. early work emphasizes the public administrator’s involvement in 12. For an effort to identify and systematically discuss public values, see both ends and means, making adherence to technical efficiency logi- Jorgensen and Bozeman (2007). cally and ethically problematic. 13. Denhardt defines the field of public administration as the manage- 4. This is a time-honored conversation; see Denhardt (2004, 15 and ment of the “change processes” necessary to pursue “publicly defined passim) and Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 11) for valuable societal values” (2004, 16). discussions. Downs and Larkey observe that public institutions will 14. Joseph A. Schumpeter observed that Pareto made a similar point: necessarily seem inefficient when goals of due process or redistribu- “Pareto pointed out that welfare judgments that cannot be salvaged tion “consume resources that a private organization would spend on in this manner [i.e., justified by the Pareto principle] must be explic- the primary mission alone” (1986, 242). itly based on extra-economic, e.g. ‘ethical,’ considerations” (1965, 5. See Osborne and Gaebler (1993, 15, 35, 80). Kaboolian notes that 131). Here Schumpeter’s phrase “extra-economic” is interpreted as each of the government reform movements labeled as part of NPM meaning beyond efficiency. sought to “maximize productive and allocative efficiencies” (1998, 15. This assertion is consistent with Denhardt’s argument that managers 190). of public organizations “bear a responsibility to examine, under- 6. On New Zealand, see, for example, Schwartz (1997, 412, 416). For stand, and interpret public values to the best of their ability” (2004, the United States, see National Performance Review (1993, chap. 2). 124). Lindblom’s discussion of the “method of successive limited 7. For example, see Argyriades (2003), deLeon and Denhardt (2000), comparisons” (1959, 81), or incrementalism, makes the important and Spicer (2004, 2007). The emerging public value paradigm in point that it is not possible to identify literally all the values at play public administration shares this skepticism (Moore 1995; O’Flynn in a policy decision. Still, the argument presented here is consistent 2007; Rhodes and Wanna 2007). with Lindblom’s rejection of what he called the “root” approach to 8. Named for the Italian economist and sociologist Vilfredo Pareto, the analysis, which would require weighting and aggregating all relevant concept is fundamental to neoclassical economics. See Lockwood values prior to considering alternative policy options. (1987) for a discussion. Economics entertains several notions of ef- 16. Lindblom (1990, 148–49) makes similar points. Although Lind- ficiency, some that appear to go well beyond the conceptual require- blom appears to share Self ’s criticisms of the Pareto criterion, it is ments of the Pareto definition. Still, as Downs and Larkey (1986, 7) interesting that the conserving aspect of the criterion is consistent suggest, the Pareto criterion is the economist’s preferred definition of with Lindblom’s interest in the incremental accretion of knowledge efficiency; perhaps for this reason, these authors label it “economic and policy development. efficiency.” Moreover, Lockwood (1987, 813) observes that within 17. In an article that offers a “public failure” model to supplement the mainstream neoclassical economics, all other concepts of efficiency existing market failure model central to public policy analysis, Barry eventually reduce to Pareto efficiency. This observation suggests Bozeman suggests that Pareto efficiency is equivalent to “conventional an irony in Van der Meer and Rutgers’s (2006, 7, 8) association of utilitarian calculus” (2002, 147). This misstates the Pareto criterion: technical efficiency (a relationship between inputs and output) with rather than promoting the interpersonal comparisons of utility that economics; Pareto efficiency goes well beyond technical efficiency. are a major drawback of utilitarianism, the Pareto criterion specifi- 9. See Denhardt (2004, 148) and Van der Meer and Rutgers (2006, 3). cally avoids such comparisons by focusing only on changes that do Also see Denhardt’s discussion of Weber’s view of “technical rational- not reduce any individual’s welfare level. In the context of this paper, ity (i.e. formal efficiency)” (25), emphasizing private ownership the criterion would have the administrator look for opportunities to and managerial control of productive resources, as well as page 43 advance at least some public values without impairing others. (discussing Woodrow Wilson’s businesslike approach), pages 51–53 18. Of course, this example abstracts from the existence of other goals (Frederick W. Taylor’s scientific management), and pages 61–65 (ef- and values that might be at play in the housing loan program. ficiency as the measure of success). 19. Note that National Performance Review’s advocacy of decentralizing 10. In the language of welfare economics, John’s proposal is “Pareto in- decision-making power is also consistent with the suggestion here ferior.” A policy that would advance at least one of the agency’s goals to give managers latitude to question and challenge the underlying without impeding others would be called “Pareto superior” relative values promoted (and ignored) by a particular course of action. to the existing situation. It should be noted that in the framework 20. As with Bozeman’s (2002, 150, 157) proposed model of public suggested here, the public administrator identifies public values, failure in advancing values, this approach does not require agreement rather than creating such values, as Mark H. Moore (1995) and oth- on public values—merely attention to them. This point partially ad- ers have advocated. dresses John Bohte’s (2007, 812) question about what an administra- 11. Van der Meer and Rutgers correctly observe that the phrases “Pareto- tor is to do when faced with conflict over desired outcomes. optimal” and “Pareto-efficient” are used synonymously; however, 21. See Donald F. Kettl’s (1997, 447) discussion of letting, versus mak- the concept does not imply that society’s welfare is at a maximum ing, managers manage. 1122 Public Administration Review • November | December 2009
  • 9. 22. There is some irony here: while many public administration writers have urged the consideration of multiple public values in addition to, or to contest the primacy of (technical) efficiency, this article suggests that the public administrator use Pareto efficiency in order to ensure the consideration of relevant public values. References Argyriades, Demetrios. 2003. Values for Public Service: Lessons Learned from Recent Trends and the Millennium Summit. International Review of Administrative Sciences 69(4): 521–33. Bohte, John. 2007. Governmental Efficiency in Our Time: Is the “What” Really More Important than the “How”? Public Administration Review 67(5): 811–15. Bozeman, Barry. 2002. Public-Value Failure: When Efficient Markets May Not Do. Public Administration Review 62(2): 145–61. De Lancer, Patria D. 1999. Data Envelopment Analysis: An Introduction. In Handbook of Research Methods in Public Administration, edited by Gerard J. Miller and Marcia L. Whicker, 535–48. New York: Marcel Dekker. deLeon, Linda, and Robert B. Denhardt. 2000. The Political Theory of Reinvention. Public Administration Review 60(2): 89–97. Denhardt, Robert B. 2004. Theories of Public Organization. 4th ed. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomson. Downs, George W., and Patrick D. Larkey. 1986. The Search for Government Efficiency: From Hubris to Helplessness. Philadelphia: Temple University Press. Farmer, David John. 1995. The Language of Public Administration: Bureaucracy, Modernity, and Postmodernity. Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press. Gulick, Luther. 1937. Science, Values, and Public Administration. In Papers on the Science of Administration Luther Gulick and L. Urwick, 189–202. New York: Institute of Public Administration. Hood, Christopher. 1995. The “New Public Management” in the 1980s: Variations on a Theme. Accounting, Organizations and Society 20(2–3): 93–109. Jorgensen, Torben Beck, and Barry Bozeman. 2007. Public Values: An Inventory. Administration & Society 39(3): 354–81. Kaboolian, Linda. 1998. The New Public Management: Challenging the Boundaries of the Management vs. Administration Debate.” Public Administration Review 58(3): 189–93. Kelly, Rita Mae. 1998. An Inclusive Democratic Polity, Representative Bureaucracies, and the New Public Management. Public Administration Review 58(8): 201–8. Kettl, Donald F. 1997. The Global Revolution in Public Management: Driving Themes, Missing Links. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 16(3): 446–62. Kingsley, J. Donald. 1945. Political Ends and Administrative Means: The Administrative Principles of Hamilton and Jefferson. Public Administration Review 5(1): 87–89. Lindblom, Charles E. 1959. The Science of “Muddling Through.” Public Administration Review 19(2): 79–88. ———. 1990. Inquiry and Change: The Troubled Attempt to Understand and Change Society. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Lockwood, B. 1987. Pareto Efficiency. In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, vol. 3, edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, 811–13. London: Macmillan. Moore, Mark H. 1995. Creating Public Value: Strategic Management in Government. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. National Performance Review (NPR). 1993. From Red Tape to Results: Creating a Government that Works Better and Costs Less. http://govinfo.library.unt. edu/npr/library/nprrpt/annrpt/redtpe93/index.html [accessed July 27, 2009]. O’Flynn, Janine. 2007. From New Public Management to Public Value: Paradigmatic Change and Managerial Implications. Australian Journal of Public Adminis- tration 66(3): 353–66. Osborne, David and Ted Gaebler. 1993. Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit Is Transforming the Public Sector. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Piotrowski, Suzanne J., and David H. Rosenbloom. 2002. Non-Mission-Based Values in Results-Oriented Public Management: The Case of Freedom of Informa- tion. Public Administration Review 62(6): 643–57. Rhodes, R. A. W., and John Wanna. 2007. The Limits to Public Value, or Rescuing Responsible Government from the Platonic Guardians. Australian Journal of Public Administration 66(4): 406–21. Schachter, Hindy Lauer. 1989. Frederick Taylor and the Public Administration Community: A Reevaluation. Albany: State University of New York Press. ———. 2007. Does Frederick Taylor’s Ghost Still Haunt the Halls of Government? A Look at the Concept of Governmental Efficiency in Our Time. Public Administration Review 67(5): 800–810. Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1952. Ten Great Economists: From Marx to Keynes. London: Allen and Unwin, 1965. Schwartz, Herman M. 1997. Reinvention and Retrenchment: Lessons from the Application of the New Zealand Model to Alberta, Canada. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 16(3): 405–22. Self, Peter. 1977. Econocrats and the Policy Process: The Politics and Philosophy of Cost-Benefit Analysis. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. ———. 1985. Political Theories of Modern Government, Its Role and Reform. London: Allen and Unwin. ———. 1993. Government by the Market? The Politics of Public Choice. London: Macmillan. Simon, Herbert A. 1976. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization. 3rd ed. New York: Free Press. Spicer, Michael. 2004. Public Administration, the History of Ideas, and the Reinventing Government Movement. Public Administration Review 64(3): 353–62. ———. 2007. Politics and the Limits of a Science of Governance: Some Reflections on the Thought of Bernard Crick. Public Administration Review 67(4): 768–79. Van der Meer, Hendriekje, and Mark R. Rutgers. 2006. Reinstating Efficiency: Recapturing the Substantial Meaning of Efficiency in Public Administration. Paper presented to the Annual Conference of the European Group of Public Administration, Bocconi University Milan, September 6–9. Waldo, Dwight. 1952. Development of Theory of Administration. American Political Science Review 46(1): 81–103. ———. 1984. The Administrative State: A Study of the Political Theory of American Public Administration. 2nd ed. New York: Holmes & Meier. Wildavsky, Aaron. 1966. The Political Economy of Efficiency: Cost–Benefit Analysis, Systems Analysis, and Program Budgeting. Public Administration Review 26(4): 292–310. The “Efficient” Public Administrator 1123