SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 476
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
Portfolio Optimization

Gerhard-Wilhelm Weber1           Erik Kropat2      Zafer-Korcan Görgülü3

                   1 Institute
                            of Applied Mathematics
                   Middle East Technical University
                           Ankara, Turkey
                    2 Department of Mathematics

                  University of Erlangen-Nuremberg
                         Erlangen, Germany
               3 University   of the Federal Armed Forces
                              Munich, Germany


                                   2008


                                                                       1 / 477
Outline I


1   The Mean-Variance Approach in a One-Period Model
      Introduction


2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem


                                                           2 / 477
Outline II




3   Option Pricing
      Introduction
      Examples
      The Replication Principle
      Arbitrage Opportunity
      Continuation
      Partial Differential Approach (PDA)
      Arbitrage & Option Pricing




                                            3 / 477
Outline III




4   Pricing of Exotic Options and Numerical Algorithms
       Introduction
       Examples
       Examples
       Equivalent Martingale Measure
       Exotic Options with Explicit Pricing Formulae
       Weak Convergence of Stochastic Processes
       Monte-Carlo Simulation
       Approximation via Binomial Trees
       The Pathwise Binomial Approach of Rogers and Stapleton



                                                                4 / 477
Outline IV



5   Optimal Portfolios
      Introduction and Formulation of the Problem
      The martingale method
      Optimal Option Portfolios
      Excursion 8: Stochastic Control
      Maximize expected value in presence of quadratic control costs
      Introduction
      Portfolio Optimization via Stochastic Control Method




                                                                   5 / 477
Outline


1   The Mean-Variance Approach in a One-Period Model




                                                       6 / 477
Outline


1   The Mean-Variance Approach in a One-Period Model
      Introduction




                                                       7 / 477
Introduction




MVA     Based on H. M ARKOWITZ
OPM   • Decisions on investment strategies only at the beginning of the
        period
      • Consequences of these decisions will be observed at the end of the
        period (−→ no action in between: static model)




                                                                       8 / 477
The one-period model




Market with d traded securities
   d different securities with positive prices p1 , . . . , pd at time t = 0
   Security prices P1 (T ), . . . , Pd (T ) at final time t = T not
   foreseeable
    −→ modeled as non-negative random variables on probability space
       (Ω, F , P)




                                                                         9 / 477
Securities in a OPM


Returns of Securities
             Pi (T )
Ri (T ) :=     pi          (1 ≤ i ≤ d )

Estimated Means, Variances and Covariances
E (Ri (T )) = µi       ,    Cov Ri (T ), Rj (T ) = σij        (1 ≤ i ≤ d )

Remark
The matrix
                                   σ := σij   i,j∈{1,...,d}

is positive semi-definite as it is a variance-covariance matrix.



                                                                             10 / 477
Securities in a OPM




Each security perfectly divisable
    Hold ϕi ∈ R shares of security i        (1 ≤ i ≤ d )
    Negative position (ϕi < 0 for some i) corresponds to a selling
    −→ Not allowed in OPM
         −→ No negative positions: pi ≥ 0    (1 ≤ i ≤ d)
         −→ No transaction costs




                                                                     11 / 477
Budget equation and portfolio return

The Budget Equation
Investor with initial wealth x > 0 holds ϕi ≥ 0 shares of security
i with
                                   ϕi · pi = x
                               1≤i≤d



The Portfolio Vector π := (π1 , . . . , πd )T
                               ϕi · pi
                       πi :=                  (1 ≤ i ≤ d )
                                 x

Portfolio Return
                      R π :=             πi · Ri (T ) = π T R
                               1≤i≤d


                                                                     12 / 477
Budget equation and portfolio return



Remark
   πi . . . fraction of total wealth invested in security i

                                            ϕi · pi
                                    1≤i≤d                 x
                             πi =                     =     =1
                                            x             x
                     1≤i≤d

   X π (T ) . . . final wealth corresponding to x and π

                         X π (T ) =             ϕi · Pi (T )
                                      1≤i≤d




                                                                 13 / 477
Budget equation and portfolio return


Remark (continued)
   Portfolio Return
                                                   ϕi · pi Pi (T )   X π (T )
         Rπ =           πi · Ri (T ) =                    ·        =
                                                     x       pi         x
                1≤i≤d                      1≤i≤d



   Portfolio Mean and Portfolio Variance

        E (R π ) =           πi · µi   ,     Var (R π ) =             πi · σij · πj
                     1≤i≤d                                  1≤i,j≤d




                                                                                      14 / 477
Selection of a portfolio–criterion




 (i) Maximize mean return (choose security of highest mean return)
    −→ risky, big fluctuations of return


 (ii) Minimize risk of fluction




                                                                15 / 477
Selection of a portfolio–approach by Markowitz (MVA)

Balance Risk (Portfolio Variance) and Return (Portfolio Mean)
 (i) Maximize E (R π ) under given upper bound c1 for Var (R π )
                                       
                                        πi ≥ 0 (1 ≤ i ≤ d )
                                       
                                       
                                       
                    π                          πi = 1
          max E (R )       subject to
          π∈Rd                          1≤i≤d
                                       
                                       
                                       
                                          Var (R π ) ≤ c1

 (ii) Minimize Var (R π ) under given lower bound c2 for E (R π )
                                          
                                           πi ≥ 0
                                          
                                                         (1 ≤ i ≤ d )
                                          
          min Var (R π )     subject to              πi = 1
          π∈Rd                            
                                             1≤i≤d
                                          
                                              E (R π )   ≥ c2


                                                                        16 / 477
Solution methods



 (i) Linear Optimization Problem with quadratic constraint
    −→ No standard algorithms, numerical inefficient

(ii) Quadratic Optimization Problem with positive semidefinite
     objective matrix σ
    −→ efficient algorithms (i.e., G OLDFARB/I DNANI, G ILL/M URRAY)
       Feasible region non-empty if c2 ≤ max µi
                                           1≤i≤d
        σ positive definite and feasible region non-empty
        −→ unique solution (even if one security riskless)




                                                                      17 / 477
Relations between the formulations (i) and (ii)


Theorem
Assume:
    σ positive definite
                    min µi ≤ c2 ≤ max µi                              c2 ∈ R+
                                                                            0
                    1≤i≤d                  1≤i≤d

            min             σ 2 (π) ≤ c1 ≤            max             σ 2 (π) c1 ∈ R+
                                                                                    0
   πi ≥0,   1≤i≤d   πi =1                    πi ≥0,   1≤i≤d   πi =1

Then
                                       ∗
(1) π ∗ solves (i) with Var R π            = c1        =⇒         π ∗ solves (ii) with
                  ∗
    c2 := E R π
(2) π solves (ii) with E R π = c2                     =⇒      π solves (i) with
    c1 := Var R π


                                                                                         18 / 477
The diversification effect–example


Holding different Securities reduces Variance
Both security prices fluctuate
    randomly
                                  σ11 , σ22 > 0
    independent
                                 σ12 = σ21 = 0
                                0.5
Then for the Portfolio π =             we get
                                0.5
                                                       σ11 σ22
           Var (R π ) = Var (0.5 · R1 + 0.5 · R2 ) =      +
                                                        4   4



                                                                 19 / 477
The diversification effect–example



Holding different Securities reduces Variance
                                                 0.5
−→ If σ11 = σ22 then the Variance of Portfolio         is half as big
                                                 0.5
                 1          0
    as that of        or
                 0          1

−→ Reduction of Variance . . . Diversification Effect depends on
   number of traded securities




                                                                  20 / 477
Example

Mean-Variance Criterion
Investing into seemingly bad security can be optimal. Let be

                         1                       0.1 −0.1
                µ=                 ,    σ=
                        0.9                     −0.1 0.15


    Formulation (ii) becomes (II)

          min Var (R π ) = min                2           2
                                       0.1 · π1 + 0.15 · π2 − 0.2 · π1 π2
            π                  π
                              
                                         π1 , π2 ≥ 0
                subject to                π1 + π2 = 1
                              
                                E (R π ) = π1 + 0.9 · π2 ≥ 0.96



                                                                            21 / 477
Example




                             1             0.5
   Consider Portfolios              and          (does not satify
                             0             0.5
   expectation constraint)
                     T                               T
          Var R (1,0)       = 0.1         , E R (1,0)      =1
                         T                               T
          Var R (0.5,0.5)        = 0.125 , E R (0.5,0.5)     = 0.95




                                                                      22 / 477
Example

   Ignore expectation constraint and remember
   π1 , π2 ≥ 0  π1 + π2 = 1. Hence

          min    0.1 · π1 + 0.15 · (1 − π1 )2 − 0.2 · π1 · (1 − π1 )
                        2
            π
                                  2
                    = min 0.45 · π1 − 0.5 · π1 + 0.15
                         π


                                                                    0.5
   −→ Minimizing Portfolio (No solution of (II) but better than           )
                                                                    0.5

                                        1             5
                                   π=     ·
                                        9             4
                                                      T
   −→ Portfolio Return Variance Var R ( 9 , 9 )
                                                5 4
                                                                ¯
                                                          = 0.001
                                            T
   −→ Portfolio Return Mean E R ( 9 , 9 )
                                      5 4
                                                      ¯
                                                 = 0.95


                                                                          23 / 477
Example



                        1.0




                       π2

                        0.5

                        0.4




                        0.0
                          0.0      0.5   0.6   1.0
                                   π1




   Pairs (π1 , π2 ) satisfying expectation constraint are above the
   dotted line
       Intersect with line π1 + π2 = 1
       −→     Feasible region of MeanVariance Problem (bold line)


                                                                      24 / 477
Example


                                0.15




                                    0.1

                              Var



                                0.05




                                    0
                                          0      0.5 0.6        1.0   1.5
                                                           π1




   Portfolio Return Variance (as function of π1 ) of all pairs satisfying
   π1 + π2 = 1
       Minimum in feasible region π ∈ [0.6, 1] is attained at π = 0.6
            Optimal Portfolio in (II)

              →∗ =
              −         0.6                                           ∗                        ∗
              π                               with Var R π                  = 0.012 ,   E Rπ       = 0.96
                        0.4


                                                                                                       25 / 477
Stock price model




OPM
   No assumption on distribution of security returns
   Solving MV Problem just needed expectations and covariances




                                                           26 / 477
Stock price model


OPM with just one security (price p1 at time t = 0 )
At time T security may have price d · p1 or u · p1
   q:     probability of decreasing by factor d
 1−q :    probability of increasing by factor u      (u > d )

    Mean and Variance of Return
                                 P1 (T )
           E (R1 (T ))   =E                  = q · u + (1 − q) · d
                                  p1
                                   P1 (T )
           Var (R1 (T )) = Var               = q · u 2 + (1 − q) · d 2
                                    p1
                                             − (q · u + (1 − q) · d )2



                                                                         27 / 477
Stock price model




OPM with just one security (price p1 at time t = 0 )
    After n periods the security has price

                       P1 (n · T ) = p1 · u Xn · d n−Xn

    with Xn ∼ B(n, p) number of up-movements of price in
    n periods




                                                           28 / 477
Comments on MVA



   Only trading at initial time t = 0
   No reaction to current price changes possible
   ( −→ static model)
   Risk of investment only modeled by variance of return

Need of Continuous-Time Market Models
   Discrete-time multi-period models
   (many periods −→         no fast algorithms)




                                                           29 / 477
Outline


2   The Continuous-Time Market Model




                                       30 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           31 / 477
Modeling the security prices


Market with d+1 securities
    d risky stocks with
    prices p1 , p2 , . . . , pd at time t = 0 and
    random prices P1 (t), P2 (t), . . . , Pd (t) at times t > 0

    1 bond with
    price p0 at time t = 0 and
    deterministic price P0 (t) at times t > 0.

Assume: Perfectly devisible securities, no transaction costs.

⇒ Modeling of the price development on the time interval [0, T ].



                                                                    32 / 477
The bond price



Assume: Continuous compounding of interest at

    a constant rate r :
           Bond price: P0 (t) = p0 · er ·t for t ∈ [0, T ]

    a non-constant, time-dependent and integrable rate r (t):
                                         t
                                             r (s) ds
           Bond price: P0 (t) = p0 · e 0                for t ∈ [0, T ]




                                                                          33 / 477
The stock price

Stock price = random fluctuations around an intrinsic bond part

                       2


                      1.8


                      1.6


                      1.4


                      1.2


                       1


                      0.8



                            0   0.2   0.4   0.6   0.8   1




log-linear model for a stock price
              ln(Pi (t)) = ln(pi ) + bi · t + ”randomness”


                                                                 34 / 477
The stock price



Randomness is assumed

   to have no tendency, i.e., E("randomness") = 0,
   to be time-dependent,
   to represent the sum of all deviations of
   ln(Pi (t)) from ln(pi ) + bi · t on [0, T ],
   ∼ N (0, σ 2 t) for some σ > 0.




                                                     35 / 477
The stock price



Deviation at time t
                        Y (t) := ln(Pi (t)) − ln(pi ) − bi · t
with
                                Y (t) ∼ N (0, σ 2 t)


Properties:
       E (Y (t)) = 0,
       Y (t) is time-dependent.




                                                                 36 / 477
The stock price




                Y (t) = Y (δ) + (Y (t) − Y (δ)), δ ∈ (0, t)

Distribution of the increments of the deviation Y (t) − Y (δ)

    depends only on the time span t − δ
    is independent of Y (s), s ≤ δ

=⇒ Y (t) − Y (δ) ∼ N 0, σ 2 (t − δ)




                                                                37 / 477
The stock price




Existence and properties of the stochastic process

                            {Y (t)}t∈[0,∞)

will be studied in the excursion on the Brownian motion.




                                                           38 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           39 / 477
General assumptions




General assumptions
Let (Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space with sample space Ω,
σ-field F and probability measure P.




                                                                     40 / 477
Filtration



Definition
Let {Ft }t∈I be a family of sub-σ-fields of F, I be an ordered index set
with Fs ⊂ Ft for s < t, s, t ∈ I. The family {Ft }t∈I is called a filtration.


     A filtration describes flow of information over time.
     Ft models events observable up to time t.
     If a random variable Xt is Ft -measurable, we are able to
     determine its value from the information given at time t.




                                                                          41 / 477
Stochastic process




Definition
A set {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I consisting of a filtration {Ft }t∈I and a family of
Rn -valued random variables {Xt }t∈I with Xt being Ft -measurable is
called a stochastic process with filtration {Ft }t∈I .




                                                                           42 / 477
Remark




Remark
   I = [0, ∞) or I = [0, T ].
   Canoncial filtration (natural filtration) of {Xt }t∈I :

                      Ft := FtX := σ{Xs | s ≤ t, s ∈ I}.

   Notation: {Xt }t∈I = {X (t)}t∈I = X .




                                                           43 / 477
Sample path




Sample path
For fixed ω ∈ Ω the set

                  X .(ω) := {Xt (ω)}t∈I = {X (t, ω)}t∈I

is called a sample path or a realization of the stochastic process.




                                                                      44 / 477
Identification of stochastic processes

Can two stochastic processes be identified with each other?

Definition
Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) and {(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) be two stochastic processes.
Y is a modification of X , if

                 P{ω | Xt (ω) = Yt (ω)} = 1 for all t ≥ 0.

Definition
Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) and {(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) be two stochastic processes.
X and Y are indistinguishable, if

              P{ω | Xt (ω) = Yt (ω) for all t ∈ [0, ∞)} = 1.



                                                                        45 / 477
Identification of stochastic processes



Remark
    X , Y indistinguishable ⇒ Y modification of X .


Theorem
Let the stochastic process Y be a modification of X . If both processes
have continuous sample paths P-almost surely, then X and Y are
indistinguishable.




                                                                   46 / 477
Brownian motion



Definition
The real-valued process {Wt }t≥0 with continuous sample paths and
  i) W0 = 0 P-a.s.
 ii) Wt − Ws ∼ N (0, t − s) for 0 ≤ s < t
     "stationary increments"
 iii) Wt − Ws independent of Wu − Wr for 0 ≤ r ≤ u ≤ s < t
      "independent increments"
is called a one-dimensional Brownian motion.




                                                                47 / 477
Brownian motion




Remark
By an n-dimensional Brownian motion we mean the Rn -valued process

                    W (t) = (W1 (t), . . . , Wn (t)),

with components Wi being independent one-dimensional Brownian
motions.




                                                                48 / 477
Brownian motion and filtration



Brownian motion can be associated with

    natural filtration

                   FtW := σ{Ws | 0 ≤ s ≤ t},   t ∈ [0, ∞)

    P-augmentation of the natural filtration (Brownian filtration)

             Ft := σ{FtW ∪ N | N ∈ F, P(N) = 0},     t ∈ [0, ∞)




                                                                   49 / 477
Brownian motion and filtration

Requirement iii) of a Brownian motion with respect to a filtration
{Ft }t≥0 is often stated as

              iii)∗ Wt − Ws independent of Fs , 0 ≤ s < t.

    {Ft }t≥0 natural filtration (Brownian filtration)
    ⇒ iii) and iii)∗ are equivalent.
    {Ft }t≥0 arbitrary filtration
    ⇒ iii) and iii)∗ are usually not equivalent.

Convention
If we consider a Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t≥0 with an arbitrary
filtration we implicitly assume iii)∗ to be fulfilled.


                                                                     50 / 477
Existence of the Brownian motion




How can we show the existence of a stochastic process satisfying the
requirements of a Brownian motion?

    Construction and existence proofs are long and technical.
    Construction based on weak convergence and approximation by
    random walks [Billingsley 1968].
    Wiener measure, Wiener process.




                                                                  51 / 477
Brownian motion and filtration

Theorem
The Brownian filtration {Ft }t≥0 is right-continuous as well as
left-continuous, i.e., we have

          Ft = Ft+ :=         Ft+ε and Ft = Ft− := σ           Fs .
                        ε>0                              s<t



Definition
A filtration {Gt }t≥0 satifies the usual conditions, if it is right-continuous
and G0 contains all P-null sets of F.


General assumption for this section
Let {Ft }t≥0 be a filtration which satisfies the usual conditions.

                                                                         52 / 477
Martingales

Definition
The real-valued process {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I with E |Xt | < ∞ for all t ∈ I
(where I is an ordered index set), is called
    a super-martingale, if for all s, t ∈ I with s ≤ t we have

                            E (Xt |Fs ) ≤ Xs P-a.s. ,

    a sub-martingale, if for all s, t ∈ I with s ≤ t we have

                            E (Xt |Fs ) ≥ Xs P-a.s. ,

    a martingale, if for all s, t ∈ I with s ≤ t we have

                            E (Xt |Fs ) = Xs P-a.s. .


                                                                         53 / 477
Interpretation of the martingale concept



Example: Modeling games of chance

Xn : Wealth of a gambler after n-th participation in a fair game

Martingale condition: E (Xn+1 |Fn ) = Xn P-a.s.

⇒ "After the game the player is as rich as he was before"

favorable game = sub-martingale
non-favorable game = super-martingale




                                                                   54 / 477
Interpretation of the martingale concept




Example: Tossing a fair coin

"Head": Gambler receives one dollar

"Tail":   Gambler loses one dollar

⇒ Martingale




                                           55 / 477
Interpretation of the martingale concept


Theorem
A one-dimensional Brownian motion Wt is a martingale.

Remark
    Each stochastic process with independent, centered increments is
    a martingale with respect to its natural filtration.
    The Brownian motion with drift µ and volatility σ

                     Xt := µt + σWt ,   µ ∈ R, σ ∈ R

    is a martingale if µ = 0, a super-martingale if µ ≤ 0 and a
    sub-martingale if µ ≥ 0.



                                                                  56 / 477
Interpretation of the martingale concept


Theorem
(1) Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I be a martingale and ϕ : R → R be a convex
    function with E |ϕ(Xt )| < ∞ for all t ∈ I. Then

                             {(ϕ(Xt ), Ft )}t∈I

   is a sub-martingale.
(2) Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I be a sub-martingale and ϕ : R → R a convex,
    non-decreasing function with E |ϕ(Xt )| < ∞ for all t ∈ I. Then

                             {(ϕ(Xt ), Ft )}t∈I

   is a sub-martingale.



                                                                      57 / 477
Interpretation of the martingale concept



Remark
(1) Typical applications are given by

                         ϕ(x) = x 2 ,     ϕ(x) = |x|.

(2) The theorem is also valid for d -dimensional vectors

                         X (t) = (X1 (t), . . . , Xd (t))

   of martingales and convex functions ϕ : Rd → R.




                                                            58 / 477
Stopping time


Definition
A stopping time with respect to a filtration {Ft }t∈[0,∞)
(or {Fn }n∈N ) is an F-measurable random variable

                  τ : Ω → [0, ∞] (or τ : Ω → N ∪ {∞})

with {ω ∈ Ω | τ (ω) ≤ t} ∈ Ft for all t ∈ [0, ∞)
(or {ω ∈ Ω | τ (ω) ≤ n} ∈ Fn for all n ∈ N).

Theorem
If τ1 , τ2 are both stopping times then τ1 ∧ τ2 := min{τ1 , τ2 } is also a
stopping time.



                                                                             59 / 477
The stopped process



The stopped process
Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I be a stochastic process, let I be either N or [0, ∞),
and τ a stopping time. The stopped process {Xt∧τ }t∈I is defined by

                                 Xt (ω)     if t ≤ τ (ω),
                   Xt∧τ (ω) :=
                                 Xτ (ω) (ω) if t > τ (ω).


Example: Wealth of a gambler who participates in a sequence of
games until he is either bankrupt or has reached a given level of
wealth.



                                                                            60 / 477
The stopped filtration



The stopped filtration
Let τ be a stopping time with respect to a filtration {Ft }t∈[0,∞) .
    σ-field of events determined prior to the stopping time τ

              Fτ := {A ∈ F | A ∩ {τ ≤ t} ∈ Ft for all t ∈ [0, ∞)}

    Stopped filtration
                                 {Fτ ∧t }t∈[0,∞) .




                                                                      61 / 477
The stopped filtration


What will happen if we stop a martingale or a sub-martingale?

Theorem: Optional sampling
Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a right-continuous sub-martingale (or
martingale). Let τ1 , τ2 be stopping times with τ1 ≤ τ2 . Then for all
t ∈ [0, ∞) we have

                    E (Xt∧τ2 | Ft∧τ1 ) ≥ Xt∧τ1 P-a.s.

(or
                    E (Xt∧τ2 | Ft∧τ1 ) = Xt∧τ1 P-a.s.).




                                                                         62 / 477
The stopped filtration




Corollary
Let τ be a stopping time and {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) a right-continuous
sub-martingale (or martingale). Then the stopped process
{(Xt∧τ , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) is also a sub-martingale (or martingale).




                                                                      63 / 477
The stopped filtration




Theorem
Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a right-continuous process. Then Xt is a
martingale if and only if for all bounded stopping times τ we have

                              EXτ = EX0 .

→ Characterization of a martingale




                                                                      64 / 477
The stopped filtration


Definition
Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a stochastic process with X0 = 0. If there is a
non-decreasing sequence {τn }n∈N of stopping times with

                          P     lim τn = ∞ = 1,
                                n→∞

such that
                          (n)
                        Xt      := (Xt∧τn , Ft )
                                                   t∈[0,∞)

is a martingale for all n ∈ N, then X is a local martingale. The
sequence {τn }n∈N is called a localizing sequence corresponding to X .




                                                                        65 / 477
The stopped filtration

Remark
(1) Each martingale is a local martingale.
(2) A local martingale with continuous paths is called
    continuous local martingale.
(3) There exist local martingales which are not martingales.
    E (Xt ) need not exist for a local martingale. However, the
    expectation has to exist along the localizing sequence t ∧ τn .
    The local martingale is a martingale on the random time
    intervals [0, τn ].

Theorem
A non-negative local martingale is a super-martingale.


                                                                      66 / 477
The stopped filtration

Theorem: Doob’s inequality
Let {Mt }t≥0 be a martingale with right-continuous paths and
     2
E (MT ) < ∞ or all T > 0. Then, we have
                                     2
                                                   2
                   E     sup |Mt |       ≤ 4 · E (MT ).
                         0≤t≤T


Theorem
Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a non-negative super-martingale with
right-continuous paths. Then, for λ > 0 we obtain

                 λ·P ω      sup Xs (ω) ≥ λ    ≤ E (X0 ).
                           0≤s≤t



                                                                  67 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           68 / 477
Continuation: The stock price




log-linear model for a stock price
               ln(Pi (t)) = ln(pi ) + bi · t + ”randomness”


Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t≥0 is the appropriate stochastic process to
model the "randomness"




                                                                    69 / 477
Continuation: The stock price

Market with one stock and one bond (d=1)
                  ln(P1 (t)) = ln(p1 ) + b1 · t + σ11 Wt
                    P1 (t) = p1 · exp b1 · t + σ11 Wt


Market with d stocks and one bond (d>1)
                                           m
        ln(Pi (t)) = ln(pi ) + bi · t +         σij Wj (t), i = 1, . . . , d
                                          j=1
                                     m
        Pi (t) = pi · exp bi · t +         σij Wj (t) , i = 1, . . . , d
                                     j=1



                                                                               70 / 477
Continuation: The stock price




Distribution of the logarithm of the stock prices
                                                    m
                                                           2
                 ln(Pi (t)) ∼ N ln(pi ) + bi · t,         σij · t
                                                    j=1



⇒ Pi (t) is log-normally distributed.




                                                                    71 / 477
Continuation: The stock price


Lemma
                     m
                 1          2
Let bi := bi +   2         σij for i = 1, . . . , d .
                     j=1


(1) E (Pi (t)) = pi · ebi t .
                                                        m
(2) Var (Pi (t)) = pi2 · exp(2bi t) · exp                      2
                                                              σij t   −1 .
                                                        j=1
                           m
                                            1
(3) Xt := a · exp                cj Wj (t) − cj2 t          with a, cj ∈ R, j = 1, . . . , m
                                            2
                           j=1
    is a martingale.



                                                                                           72 / 477
Interpretation of the stock price model

The stock price model

                                              m
                                                               1 2
           Pi (t) = pi · exp(bi t) · exp           σij Wj (t) − σij t   ,
                                                               2
                                             j=1

          Pi (0) = pi , i = 1, . . . , d .

The stock price is the product of
    the mean stock price pi · exp(bi t) and
    a martingale with expectation 1, namely
                                    m
                                                     1 2
                           exp           σij Wj (t) − σij t
                                                     2
                                   j=1

    which models the stock price around its mean value.
                                                                            73 / 477
Interpretation of the stock price model



   Vector of mean rates of stock returns

                             b = (b1 , . . . , bd )T

   Volatility matrix                      
                             σ11 . . . σ1m
                             .         . 
                          σ= .
                              .
                                 ..
                                     .  . 
                                        .
                             σd1 . . . σdm
   Pi (t) is a geometric Brownian motion with drift bi and volatility
   σi. = (σi1 , . . . , σim )T .




                                                                        74 / 477
Summary: Stock prices




Bond price and stock prices
 P0 (t) = p0 · ert
                                                                Bond price
 P0 (0)= p0
                                    m
                                                         1 2
 Pi (t) = pi · exp(bi t) · exp            σij Wj (t) −    σ t
                                                         2 ij   Stock prices
                                    j=1
 Pi (0) = pi , i = 1, . . . , d .




                                                                             75 / 477
Extension

Extension: Model with non-constant, time-dependent, and integrable
rates of return bi (t) and volatilities σ(t).

Stock prices:
                                       t                 m
                                                    1           2
               Pi (t) = pi · exp           bi (s) −            σij (s) ds
                                                    2
                                   0                     j=1

                                   m        t

                           · exp                σij (s) dWj (s)
                                   j=1 0


           t
Problem:       σij (s) dWj (s)
           0
                         ˆ
⇒ Stochastic integral (Ito integral)

                                                                            76 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           77 / 477
ˆ
The Ito integral




Is it possible to define the stochastic integral
                                 t

                                     Xs (ω) dWs (ω)
                             0

ω-wise in a reasonable way?




                                                      78 / 477
ˆ
The Ito integral



Theorem
P-almost all paths of the Brownian motion {Wt }t∈[0,∞) are nowhere
differentiable.


⇒ A definition of the form
                   t                          t
                                                           dWs (ω)
                       Xs (ω) dWs (ω) =           Xs (ω)           ds
                                                             ds
               0                          0

  is impossible.




                                                                        79 / 477
ˆ
The Ito integral


Theorem
With the definition
                       2n
           Zn (ω) :=         W i (ω) − W i−1 (ω) , n ∈ N, ω ∈ Ω
                               2n         2n
                       i=1

we have
                                    n→∞
                        Zn (ω) − − ∞
                                −→             P-a.s. ,
i.e., the paths Wt (ω) of the Brownian motion admit infinite variation on
the interval [0, 1] P-almost surely.
The paths Wt (ω) of the Brownian motion have infinite variation on each
non-empty finite interval [s1 , s2 ] ⊂ [0, ∞) P-almost surely.


                                                                     80 / 477
General assumptions




General assumptions for this section
Let (Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space equipped with a filtration
{Ft }t satisfying the usual conditions. Further assume that on this
space a Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) with respect to this filtration
is defined.




                                                                       81 / 477
Simple process


Definition
A stochastic process {Xt }t∈[0,T ] is called a simple process if there exist
real numbers 0 = t0 < t1 < . . . < tp = T , p ∈ N, and bounded random
variables Φi : Ω → R, i = 0, 1, . . . , p, with

        Φ0 F0 -measurable,      Φi Fti−1 -measurable, i = 1, . . . , p

such that Xt (ω) has the representation
                                                  p
        Xt (ω) = X (t, ω) = Φ0 (ω) · 1{0} (t) +         Φi (ω) · 1(ti−1 ,ti ] (t)
                                                  i=1

for each ω ∈ Ω.


                                                                                    82 / 477
Simple process

Remark
   Xt is Fti−1 -measurable for all t ∈ (ti−1 , ti ].
   The paths X (., ω) of the simple process Xt are left-continuous step
   functions with height Φi (ω) · 1(ti−1 ,ti ] (t).


                             1

                            0.9

                            0.8

                            0.7

                            0.6

                     X(.,ω) 0.5

                            0.4

                            0.3

                            0.2

                            0.1

                             0
                              0   t   t2       t3      T
                                  1
                                           t




                                                                   83 / 477
Stochastic integral


Definition
For a simple process {Xt }t∈[0,T ] the stochastic integral I.(X ) for
t ∈ (tk , tk +1 ] is defined according to
                     t

    It (X ) :=           Xs dWs :=             Φi (Wti − Wti−1 ) + Φk +1 (Wt − Wtk ),
                 0                     1≤i≤k


or more generally for t ∈ [0, T ]:
                                 t

             It (X ) :=              Xs dWs :=           Φi (Wti ∧t − Wti−1 ∧t ).
                             0                   1≤i≤p




                                                                                        84 / 477
Stochastic integral


Theorem: Elementary properties of the stochastic integral
Let X := {Xt }t∈[0,T ] be a simple process. Then we have

(1) {It (X )}t∈[0,T ] is a continuous martingale with respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] .
    In particular, we have E (It (X )) = 0 for all t ∈ [0, T ].
         t             2        t
(2) E        Xs dWs        =E        2
                                    Xs ds for t ∈ [0, T ].
        0                       0

                 t              2             T
(3) E    sup         Xs dWs         ≤4·E           2
                                                  Xs ds .
        0≤t≤T 0                              0




                                                                            85 / 477
Stochastic integral


Remark
(1) By (2) the stochastic integral is a square-integrable stochastic
    process.
(2) For the simple process X ≡ 1 we obtain
                                         t

                                             1 dWs = Wt
                                     0

    and
                           t                                              t
                                             2
                   E           dWs               =   E (Wt2 )   =t=           ds.
                       0                                              0




                                                                                    86 / 477
Stochastic integral

Remark
(1) Integrals with general boundaries:
                    T               T                  t

                        Xs dWs :=       Xs dWs −           Xs dWs for t ≤ T .
                t                   0              0

   For t ≤ T , A ∈ Ft we have
           T                                                           T

               1A (ω) · Xs (ω) · 1[t,T ] (s) dWs = 1A (ω) ·                Xs (ω) dWs .
          0                                                        t

(2) Let X , Y be simple processes, a, b ∈ R. Then we have

                It (aX + bY ) = a · It (X ) + b · It (Y ) (linearity)

                                                                                          87 / 477
Measurability

Definition
A stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is called measurable if the
mapping

                                     [0, ∞) × Ω → Rn
                                     (s, ω) → Xs (ω)

is B([0, ∞)) ⊗ F-B(Rn )-measurable.

Remark
Measurability of the process X implies that X (., ω) is
B([0, ∞))-B(Rn )-measurable for a fixed ω ∈ Ω. Thus, for all t ∈ [0, ∞),
                                 t
i = 1, . . . , n, the integral       Xi2 (s) ds is defined.
                                 0


                                                                       88 / 477
Measurability




Definition
A stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is called progressively
measurable if for all t ≥ 0 the mapping

                             [0, t] × Ω → Rn
                             (s, ω) → Xs (ω)

is B([0, t]) ⊗ Gt -B(Rn )-measurable.




                                                                   89 / 477
Measurability



Remark
(1) If the real-valued process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is progressively
    measurable and bounded, then for all t ∈ [0, ∞) the integral
    t
        Xs ds is Gt -measurable.
    0

(2) Every progressively measurable process is measurable.
(3) Each measurable process possesses a progressively measurable
    modification.




                                                                      90 / 477
Measurability


Theorem
If all paths of the stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) are
right-continuous (or left-continuous), then the process is progressively
measurable.


Theorem
Let τ be a stopping time with respect to the filtration {Gt }t∈[0,∞) . If the
stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is progressively measurable, then
so is the stopped process {(Xt∧τ , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) . In particular, Xt∧τ is Gt
and Gt∧τ -measurable.




                                                                          91 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes

Definition

   L2 [0, T ] := L2 [0, T ], Ω, F, {Ft }t∈[0,T ] , P

             :=    {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] real-valued stochastic process
                                                           T

                  {Xt }t progressively measurable, E           Xt2 dt < ∞
                                                          0

                                     T
Norm on L2 [0, T ]: X     2
                          T   := E       Xt2 dt .
                                     0



                                                                            92 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes




     ·   2   L2 -norm on the probability space
         T
             [0, T ] × Ω, B([0, T ]) ⊗ F, λ ⊗ P .

     ·   2   semi-norm     ( X −Y    2   = 0 ⇒ X = Y ).
         T                           T


   X equivalent to Y        :⇔    X = Y a.s. λ ⊗ P.




                                                          93 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes


  ˆ
Ito isometry
Let X be a simple process. The mapping X → I.(X ) induces by
                               T                     T
                                            2
                   2                                      2            2
          I.(X )   LT   := E       Xs dWs       =E       Xs ds   = X   T
                               0                     0

a norm on the space of stochastic integrals.

⇒ I.(X ) linear, norm-preserving (= isometry)
           ˆ
⇒ I.(X ) Ito isometry


                                                                           94 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes



   Use processes X ∈ L2 [0, T ] approximated by a sequence X (n) of
   simple processes.
   I.(X (n) ) is a Cauchy-sequence with respect to     ·   LT .

   To show: I.(X (n) ) is convergent, limit independent of X (n) .
   Denote limit by
                             I(X ) =    Xs dWs .




                                                                     95 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes



                                 J(.)
                                                    C
             X ∈ L2 [0, T ] _ _ _ _ _ _ _/ J(X ) ∈ M2
                        O                         O
                ·   T                                 ·   LT


                    X (n)                    / I(X (n) )
                                I(.)



         simple process                stochastic integral
                                       for simple processes




                                                               96 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes



Theorem
An arbitrary X ∈ L2 [0, T ] can be approximated by a sequence of
simple processes X (n) .
More precisely: There exists a sequence X (n) of simple processes with
                             T
                                       (n) 2
                     lim E       Xs − Xs       ds = 0.
                    n→∞
                             0




                                                                   97 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes




Lemma
Let {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) be a martingale where the filtration {Gt }t∈[0,∞)
satisfies the usual conditions. Then the process Xt possesses a
right-continuous modification {(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) such that
{(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is a martingale.




                                                                           98 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes


                      ˆ
Construction of the Ito integral for processes in L2 [0, T ]
There exists a unique linear mapping J from L2 [0, T ] into the space of
continuous martingales on [0, T ] with respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] satisfying
(1) X = {Xt }t∈[0,T ] simple process
    ⇒ P Jt (X ) = It (X ) for all t ∈ [0, T ] = 1
                        t
(2) E Jt (X )2 = E           2      ˆ
                            Xs ds Ito isometry
                        0


Uniqueness: If J, J ′ satisfy (1) and (2), then for all X ∈ L2 [0, T ] the
processes J ′ (X ) and J(X ) are indistinguishable.


                                                                             99 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes



Definition
For X ∈ L2 [0, T ] and J as before we define by
                                t

                                    Xs dWs := Jt (X )
                            0

                              ˆ
the stochastic integral (or Ito integral) of X with respect to W .




                                                                     100 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes




Theorem: Special case of Doob’s inequality
Let X ∈ L2 [0, T ]. Then we have
                              t                       T
                                           2
                                                           2
              E   sup             Xs dWs       ≤4·E       Xs ds .
                  0≤t≤T
                          0                           0




                                                                    101 / 477
Extension of the stochastic integral to
L2 [0, T ]-processes
Multi-dimensional generalization of the stochastic integral
{(W (t), Ft )}t : m-dimensional Brownian motion
                  with W (t) = (W1 (t), . . . , Wm (t))
{(X (t), Ft )}t : Rn,m -valued progressively measurable process with
                  Xij ∈ L2 [0, T ].
  ˆ
Ito integral of X with respect to W :
                                              t                
                                      m
                                                  X1j (s) dWj (s)
                                                                 
               t                    j=1                          
                                          0                      
                                                      .
                                                       .          
                   X (s) dW (s) :=                    .          ,   t ∈ [0, T ]
                                                                 
           0                        m         t                  
                                                                 
                                                  Xnj (s) dWj (s)
                                      j=1 0

                                                                                     102 / 477
Further extension of the stochastic integral


Definition

    H 2 [0, T ] := H 2 [0, T ], Ω, F, {Ft }t∈[0,T ] , P

              :=    {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] real-valued stochastic process

                     {Xt }t progressively measurable,
                      T

                          Xt2 dt < ∞ P-a.s.
                     0




                                                                          103 / 477
Further extension of the stochastic integral
Processes X ∈ H 2 [0, T ]
    do not necessarily have a finite T -norm
    → no approximation by simple processes as for
       processes in L2 [0, T ]
    can be localized with suitable sequences of stopping times
Stopping times (with respect to {Ft }t ):
                                            t
                                                 2
         τn (ω) := T ∧ inf 0 ≤ t ≤ T            Xs (ω) ds ≥ n , n ∈ N
                                        0

Sequence of stopped processes:
                         (n)
                       Xt (ω) := Xt (ω) · 1{τn (ω)≥t}

⇒ X (n) ∈ L2 [0, T ] ⇒ Stochastic integral already defined.
                                                                        104 / 477
Further extension of the stochastic integral



Stochastic integral:

                       It (X ) := It (X (n) ) for 0 ≤ t ≤ τn

Consistence property:

             It (X ) = It (X (m) ) for 0 ≤ t ≤ τn (≤ τm ), m ≥ n


⇒ It (X ) well-defined for X ∈ H 2 [0, T ]




                                                                   105 / 477
Further extension of the stochastic integral




Stopping times:
                             n→∞
                         τn − − +∞ P-a.s.
                             −→

⇒ It (X ) local martingale with localizing sequence τn .

⇒ Stochastic integral is linear and possesses continuous paths.




                                                                  106 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           107 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula




General assumptions for this section
Let (Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space equipped with a filtration
{Ft }t satisfying the usual conditions. Further, assume that on this
space a Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) with respect to this filtration
is defined.




                                                                      108 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula


Definition
Let {(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be an m-dimensional Brownian motion.
                                             ˆ
(1) {(X (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) is a real-valued Ito process if for all t ≥ 0 it
     admits the representation
                                 t                    t

           X (t) = X (0) +           K (s) ds +           H(s) dW (s)
                             0                    0
                                 t                m         t

                = X (0) +            K (s) ds +                 Hj (s) dWj (s) P-a.s.
                             0                    j=1 0




                                                                                        109 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula



    X (0) F0 -measurable,
    {K (t)}t∈[0,∞) , {H(t)}t∈[0,∞) progressively measurable with

                t                          t

                    |K (s)| ds < ∞,            Hi2 (s) ds < ∞ P-a.s.
            0                          0

    for all t ≥ 0, i = 1, . . . , m.

(2) n-dimensional Ito process X = (X (1) , . . . , X (n) )
                    ˆ
                                                         ˆ
    = vector with components being real-valued Ito processes.




                                                                       110 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula




Remark
   Hj ∈ H 2 [0, T ] for all T > 0.
                                 ˆ
   The representation of an Ito process is unique up to
   indistinguishability of the representing integrands Kt , Ht .
   Symbolic differential notation:

                             dXt = Kt dt + Ht dWt




                                                                   111 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula

Definition
                                 ˆ
Let X and Y be two real-valued Ito processes with
                                   t                       t

             X (t) = X (0) +           K (s) ds +              H(s) dW (s),
                               0                      0
                                   t                   t

             Y (t) = Y (0) +           L(s) ds +               M(s) dW (s).
                               0                     0

Quadratic covariation of X and Y :

                                       m   t

                    X,Y   t   :=               Hi (s) · Mi (s) ds.
                                   i=1 0


                                                                              112 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula

Definition
Quadratic variation of X

                                           X   t   := X , X t .


Notation
                         ˆ
Let X be a real-valued Ito process, and Y a real-valued, progressively
measurable process. We set
           t                         t                                t

               Y (s) dX (s) :=           Y (s) · K (s) ds +               Y (s) · H(s) dW (s)
       0                         0                                0

if all integrals on the right-hand side are defined.

                                                                                                113 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula
                           ˆ
Theorem: One-dimensional Ito formula
                                                                    ˆ
Let Wt be a one-dimensional Brownian motion, and Xt a real-valued Ito
process with
                                                 t                     t

                                 Xt = X0 +           Ks ds +               Hs dWs .
                                             0                     0

Let f ∈   C 2 (R).   Then, for all t ≥ 0 we have
                             t                             t
                                  ′            1
   f (Xt ) = f (X0 ) +           f (Xs ) dXs +                 f ′′ (Xs ) d X   s
                                               2
                         0                             0
                             t                                                            t
                                                1
           = f (X0 ) +            f (Xs ) · Ks + · f ′′ (Xs ) · Hs ds +
                                      ′                          2
                                                                                              f ′ (Xs )Hs dWs
                                                2
                         0                                                            0




                                                                                                            114 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula


Remark
         ˆ
   The Ito formula differs from the fundamental theorem of calculus
   by the additional term
                                      t
                              1
                                          f ′′ (Xs ) d X s .
                              2
                                  0

   The quadratic variation X      t               ˆ
                                          is an Ito process.
   Differential notation:
                                                   1 ′′
                  df (Xt ) = f ′ (Xt ) dXt +         · f (Xt ) d X t .
                                                   2



                                                                         115 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula


Lemma
Let X be a martingale with |Xs | ≤ C for all s ∈ [0, t] P-a.s.
Let π = {t0 , t1 , . . . , tm }, t0 = 0, tm = t, be a partition of [0, t] with

                               π := max |tk − tk −1 |.
                                            1≤k ≤m

Then we have
          m                          2
                               2
(1) E           Xtk − Xtk −1              ≤ 48 · C 4
         k =1
                                    m
                                                          4    π →0
(2) X continuous ⇒ E                       Xtk − Xtk −1       − − → 0.
                                                               −−
                                   k =1




                                                                                 116 / 477
′
                       ˆ
Some applications of Ito s formula

                          ′
                       ˆ
Some applications of Ito s formula I
(1) Xt = t :
    Representation:
                                       t                   t

                       Xt = 0 +            1 ds +              0 dWs .
                                   0                   0

    For f ∈ C 2 (R) we have
                                                  t

                         f (t) = f (0) +              f ′ (s) ds.
                                              0

    ⇒ Fundamental theorem of calculus is a special case of
      Ito′ s formula.
        ˆ

                                                                         117 / 477
′
                       ˆ
Some applications of Ito s formula II


                       ˆ′
Some applications of Ito s formula
(2) Xt = h(t) :
    For h ∈ C 1 (R) Ito′ s formula implies the chain rule
                      ˆ

                                        t                       t
                                             ′
                     Xt = h(0) +            h (s) ds +              0 dWs
                                    0                       0

                                                     t

              ⇒ (f ◦ h)(t) = (f ◦ h)(0) +                f ′ (h(s)) · h′ (s) ds.
                                                 0




                                                                                   118 / 477
′
                       ˆ
Some applications of Ito s formula III

                                  ′
                       ˆ
Some applications of Ito s formula
(3) Xt = Wt , f (x) = x 2 :
    Due to
                                              t                   t

                               Wt = 0 +           0 ds +              1 dWs
                                          0                   0

    we obtain
                         t                             t                     t
                                         1
             Wt2 =           2 · Ws dWs + ·                2 ds = 2 ·            Ws dWs + t
                                         2
                     0                             0                     0

    ⇒ Additional term "t"
      (→ nonvanishing quadratic variation of Wt ).

                                                                                              119 / 477
ˆ
The Ito formula
                             ˆ
Theorem: Multi-dimensional Ito formula
                                               ˆ
X (t) = X1 (t), . . . , Xn (t) n-dimensional Ito process with

                                          t                 m       t

        Xi (t) = Xi (0) +                     Ki (s) ds +                   Hij (s) dWj (s), i = 1, . . . , n
                                      0                     j=1 0


where W (t) = W1 (t), . . . , Wm (t) is an m-dimensional Brownian motion.
Let f : [0, ∞) × Rn → R be a C 1,2 -function. Then, we have

   f (t, X1 (t), . . . , Xn (t)) = f (0, X1 (0), . . . , Xn (0))
            t                                                n          t

    +           ft (s, X1 (s), . . . , Xn (s)) ds +                         fxi (s, X1 (s), . . . , Xn (s)) dXi (s)
        0                                                   i=1 0

                  n       t
     1
    + ·                       fxi xj (s, X1 (s), . . . , Xn (s)) d Xi , Xj s .
     2
                i,j=1 0

                                                                                                                      120 / 477
Product rule or partial integration
Corollary: Product rule or partial integration
                                 ˆ
Let Xt , Yt be one-dimensional Ito processes with
                                                     t                     t

                               Xt = X0 +                 Ks ds +               Hs dWs ,
                                                 0                     0
                                                     t                     t

                               Yt = Y0 +                 µs ds +               σs dWs .
                                                 0                 0

Then we have              t                  t                     t

Xt · Yt = X0 · Y0 +           Xs dYs +           Ys dXs +                  d X,Y          s
                      0                  0                     0
                          t                                                          t

       = X0 · Y0 +            Xs µs + Ys Ks + Hs σs ds +                                 Xs σs + Ys Hs dWs .
                      0                                                          0

                                                                                                               121 / 477
The stock price equation
Simple continuous-time market model (1 bond, one stock).
Stock price influenced by a one-dimensional Brownian motion
    Price of the stock at time t:

                            P(t) = p · exp        b − 1 σ 2 t + σWt
                                                      2

    Choose
                                t                         t
                                         1 2
          Xt = 0 +                  b−   2σ    ds +           σ dWs ,        f (x) = p · ex
                            0                         0

      ˆ
    Ito formula implies
                        t                                                             t
                                           1 2     1                   2
    f (Xt ) = p +           f (Xs )(b −    2 σ ) + 2 f (Xs )      ·σ       ds +           f (Xs ) · σ dWs
                    0                                                             0

                                                                                                    122 / 477
The stock price equation


The stock price equation
                                   t                       t

              P(t) = p +               P(s) · b ds +           P(s) · σ dWs
                               0                       0



Remark
The stock price equation is valid for time-dependent b and σ, if
                         t                                         t
                                         1 2
              Xt =           b(s) −      2 σ (s)   ds +                σ(s) dWs .
                     0                                         0




                                                                                    123 / 477
The stock price equation




The stock price equation in differential form

                    dP(t) = P(t) b dt + σ dWt

                     P(0) = p




                                                124 / 477
The stock price equation


Theorem: Variation of constants
Let {(W (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be an m-dimensional Brownian motion.
Let x ∈ R and A, a, Sj , σj be progressively measurable, real-valued
processes with
               t

                   |A(s)| + |a(s)| ds < ∞     for all t ≥ 0 P-a.s.
           0
               t

                   Sj2 (s) + σj2 (s) ds < ∞   for all t ≥ 0 P-a.s. .
           0




                                                                       125 / 477
The stock price equation

Theorem: Variation of constants
Then the stochastic differential equation
                                                  m
    dX (t) = A(t) · X (t) + a(t) dt +                  Sj (t)X (t) + σj (t) dWj (t)
                                                 j=1
     X (0) = x

possesses a unique solution with respect to λ ⊗ P :
                                       t                  m
                                             1
        X (t) = Z (t) · x +                      a(u) −         Sj (u)σj (u) du
                                           Z (u)
                                   0                      j=1

                 m       t
                             σj (u)
             +                      dWj (u)
                             Z (u)
                 j=1 0


                                                                                      126 / 477
The stock price equation


Theorem: Variation of constants
Hereby is
                         t                                        t
                                      1            2
      Z (t) = exp            A(u) −   2   · S(u)       du +           S(u) dW (u)
                     0                                        0

the unique solution of the homogeneous equation

                dZ (t) = Z (t) A(t) dt + S(t)T dW (t)
                    Z (0) = 1.




                                                                                    127 / 477
The stock price equation


Remark
The process {(X (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) solves the stochastic differential
equation in the sense that X (t) satisfies
                                  t

                X (t) = x +           A(s) · X (s) + a(s) ds
                              0
                         m    t

                     +                Sj (s) X (s) + σj (s) dWj (s)
                         j=1 0


for all t ≥ 0 P-almost surely.



                                                                       128 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           129 / 477
General assumptions

General assumptions for this section
(Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space,
{(W (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) m-dimensional Brownian motion.
Dynamics of bond and stock prices:
                                            t

             P0 (t) = p0 · exp                  r (s) ds                           bond
                                        0
                                         t                      m
                                                            1          2
             Pi (t) = pi · exp                   bi (s) −             σij (s) ds
                                                            2
                                        0                       j=1

                         m       t

                     +               σij (s) dWj (s)                               stock
                         j=1 0
for t ∈ [0, T ], T > 0, i = 1, . . . , d .

                                                                                           130 / 477
General assumptions (continued)

General assumptions for this section (continued)
    r (t), b(t) = (b1 (t), . . . , bd (t))T , σ(t) = (σij (t))ij
    progressively measurable processes with respect to {Ft }t ,
    component-wise uniformly bounded in (t, ω).

    σ(t)σ(t)T uniformly positive definite,
    i.e., it exists K > 0 with

                            x T σ(t)σ(t)T x ≥ Kx T x

    for all x ∈ Rd and all t ∈ [0, T ] P-a.s.

    Deterministic rate of return r (t) is not required
    r (t) can be a stochastic process
    ⇒ bond is no longer riskless.

                                                                   131 / 477
Bond and stock prices

Bond and stock prices are unique solutions of the stochastic
differential equations

    dP0 (t) = P0 (t) · r (t) dt                                                bond
      P0 (t) = p0



                                    m
     dPi (t) = Pi (t) bi (t) dt +         σij (t) dWj (t) , i = 1, . . . , d
                                    j=1

     Pi (0) = pi                                                               stock

                                 ˆ
⇒ Representations of prices as Ito processes


                                                                                       132 / 477
Possible actions of investors




(1) Investor can rebalance his holdings
    → sell some securities
    → invest in securities
    ⇒ Portfolio process / trading strategy.

(2) Investor is allowed to consume parts of his wealth
    ⇒ Consumption process.




                                                         133 / 477
Requirements on a market model



(1) Investor should not be able to foresee events
    → no knowledge of future prices.
(2) Actions of a single investor have no impact on the stock prices
    (small investor hypothesis).
(3) Each investor has a fixed initial capital at time t = 0.
(4) Money which is not invested into stocks has to be invested in
    bonds.
(5) Investors act in a self-financing way
    (no secret source or sink for money).




                                                                      134 / 477
Requirements on a market model




(6) Securities are perfectly divisible.
(7) Negative positions in securities are possible
    bond → credit
    stock → we sold some stock short.
(8) No transaction costs.




                                                    135 / 477
Negative bond positions and credit interest rates



Negative bond positions and credit interest rates


    Assume: Interest rate r (t) is constant
    Negative bond position = it is possible to borrow money for the
    same rate as we would get for investing in bonds.
    Interest depends on the market situation ((t, ω) ∈ [0, T ] × Ω), but
    not on positive or negative bond position.




                                                                      136 / 477
Mathematical realizations of some requirements

Market with 1 bond and d stocks

    Time t = 0:   – Initial capital of investor: x > 0
                  – Buy a selection of securities
                                                            T
                    ϕ(0) = ϕ0 (0), ϕ1 (0), . . . , ϕd (0)

    Time t > 0:   – Trading strategy: ϕ(t)


    (1) ⇒ trading strategy is progressively measurable
          with respect to {Ft }t
    Decisions on buying and selling are made on basis of information
    available at time t (→ modelled by {Ft }t )
    (5) ⇒ only self-financing trading strategies should be used.


                                                                  137 / 477
Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy


Market with 1 riskless bond and 1 stock

Two-period model for time points t = 0, 1, 2.
    Number of shares of bond and stock at time t:

                              (ϕ0 (t), ϕ1 (t))T ∈ R2

    Consumption of investor at time t: C(t)
    Wealth at time t: X (t)
    Bond/stock prices at time t: P0 (t), P1 (t)
    Initial conditions: C(0) = 0, X (0) = x




                                                       138 / 477
Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy




t =0
Investor uses initial capital to buy shares of bond and stock


               X (0) = x = ϕ0 (0) · P0 (0) + ϕ1 (0) · P1 (0).




                                                                139 / 477
Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy

t =1
Security prices have changed, investor consumes parts of his wealth

Current wealth:

             X (1) = ϕ0 (0) · P0 (1) + ϕ1 (0) · P1 (1) − C(1).

Total:

 X (1) = x + ϕ0 (0) · P0 (1) − P0 (0) + ϕ1 (0) · P1 (1) − P1 (0) − C(1)

         Wealth = initial wealth + gains/losses - consumption

Invest remaining capital at the market:

                  X (1) = ϕ0 (1) · P0 (1) + ϕ1 (1) · P1 (1).

                                                                    140 / 477
Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy
t =2
Invest remaining capital at the market

Wealth:
                 X (2) = ϕ0 (2) · P0 (2) + ϕ1 (2) · P1 (2).

                 Wealth = total wealth of shares held

Total:
                          2
           X (2) = x +           ϕ0 (i − 1) · (P0 (i) − P0 (i − 1))
                         i=1
                               +ϕ1 (i − 1) · (P1 (i) − P1 (i − 1))
                          2
                     −         C(i).
                         i=1

                                                                      141 / 477
Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy


Self-financing trading strategy:
    wealth before rebalancing - consumption = wealth after rebalancing


Condition:

        ϕ0 (i) · P0 (i) + ϕ1 (i) · P1 (i)
                    = ϕ0 (i − 1) · P0 (i) + ϕ1 (i − 1) · P1 (i) − C(i)


⇒ Useless in continuous-time setting
   (securities can be traded at each time instant /
   "before" and "after" cannot be distinguished)


                                                                         142 / 477
Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy



Continuous-time setting

Wealth process corresponding to strategy ϕ(t):
                        t                          t                          t

      X (t) = x +           ϕ0 (s) dP0 (s) +           ϕ1 (s) dP1 (s) −           c(s) ds
                    0                          0                          0

                        ˆ
⇒ Price processes are Ito processes.




                                                                                            143 / 477
Trading strategy and wealth processes

Definition
(1) A trading strategy ϕ with
                                                                   T
                          ϕ(t) := ϕ0 (t), ϕ1 (t), . . . , ϕd (t)

   is an Rd+1 -valued progressively measurable process with respect
   to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] satisfying

                                T

                                      |ϕ0 (t)| dt < ∞ P-a.s.
                               0

            d   T
                                      2
                    ϕi (t) · Pi (t)       dt < ∞   P-a.s.    for i = 1, . . . , d .
         j=1 0


                                                                                      144 / 477
Trading strategy and wealth processes

Definition
    The value
                                    d
                           x :=           ϕi (0) · pi
                                    i=0

    is called initial value of ϕ.


(2) Let ϕ be a trading strategy with initial value x > 0.
    The process
                                             d
                             X (t) :=            ϕi (t)Pi (t)
                                           i=0

    is called wealth process corresponding to ϕ with
    initial wealth x.

                                                                145 / 477
Trading strategy and wealth processes



Definition
(3) A non-negative progressively measurable process c(t) with
    respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] with

                         T

                             c(t) dt < ∞ P-a.s.
                        0

   is called consumption (rate) process.




                                                                146 / 477
Trading strategy and wealth processes


Definition
A pair (ϕ, c) consisting of a trading strategy ϕ and a consumption rate
process c is called self-financing if the corresponding wealth process
X (t) satisfies

                        d       t                          t

          X (t) = x +               ϕi (s) dPi (s) −           c(s) ds P-a.s.
                        i=0 0                          0




      current wealth = initial wealth + gains/losses - consumption




                                                                                147 / 477
Trading strategy and wealth processes


Remark
We have
       t                          t

           ϕ0 (s) dP0 (s) =           ϕ0 (s) P0 (s) r (s) ds
   0                          0
       t                          t

           ϕi (s) dPi (s) =           ϕi (s) Pi (s) bi (s) ds
   0                          0
                              m         t

                        +                   ϕi (s) Pi (s) σij (s) dWj (s), i = 1, . . . , d .
                              j=1 0




                                                                                                148 / 477
Self-financing portfolio process



Definition
Let (ϕ, c) be a self-financing pair consisting of a trading strategy and a
consumption process with corresponding wealth process X (t) > 0
P-a.s. for all t ∈ [0, T ]. Then the Rd -valued process

                                            T                   ϕi (t) · Pi (t)
            π(t) = π1 (t), . . . , πd (t)       with πi (t) =
                                                                    X (t)

is called a self-financing portfolio process corresponding to the
pair (ϕ, c).




                                                                                  149 / 477
Portfolio processes


Remark
(1) The portfolio process denotes the fractions of total wealth invested
    in the different stocks.
(2) The fraction of wealth invested in the bond is given by

                         ϕ0 (t) · P0 (t)
         1 − π(t)T 1 =                   , where 1 := (1, . . . , 1)T ∈ Rd .
                             X (t)

(3) Given knowledge of wealth X (t) and prices Pi (t), it is possible for
    an investor to describe his activities via a self-financing pair (π, c).
    → Portfolio process and trading strategy are
       equivalent descriptions of the same action.



                                                                           150 / 477
The wealth equation




The wealth equation

        dX (t) = [r (t) X (t) − c(t)] dt

               + X (t) π(t)T (b(t) − r (t) 1) dt + σ(t) dW (t)

         X (0) = x




                                                                 151 / 477
Alternative definition of a portfolio process



Definition
The progressively measurable Rd -valued process π(t) is called a
self-financing portfolio process corresponding to the consumption
process c(t) if the corresponding wealth equation possesses a unique
solution X (t) = X π,c (t) with
            T
                                 2
                X (t) · πi (t)       dt < ∞ P-a.s.   for i = 1, . . . , d .
         0




                                                                              152 / 477
Admissibility



Definition
A self-financing pair (ϕ, c) or (π, c) consisting of a trading strategy ϕ or
a portfolio process π and a consumption process c will be called
admissible for the initial wealth x > 0, if the corresponding wealth
process satisfies

                  X (t) ≥ 0 P-a.s.    for all t ∈ [0, T ].

The set of admissible pairs will be denoted by A(x).




                                                                      153 / 477
An example

Portfolio process:
                       π(t) ≡ π ∈ Rd constant
Consumption rate:
                        c(t) = γ · X (t), γ > 0
Wealth process corresponding to (π, c) :

                                 X (t)

    Investor rebalances his holdings in such a way that the fractions of
    wealth invested in the different stocks and in the bond remain
    constant over time.
    Consumption rate is proportional to the current wealth of the
    investor.


                                                                    154 / 477
An example

   Wealth equation:

                    dX (t) = [r (t) − γ] X (t) dt
                           + X (t)π T (b(t) − r (t) 1) dt + σ(t) dW (t)
                    X (0) = 0

   Wealth process:
                               t
                                                                        1 T
   X (t) = x · exp                 r (s) − γ + π T b(s) − r (s) · 1 −     π σ(s)   2
                                                                                       ds
                                                                        2
                           0
                t

        +           π T σ(s) dW (s)
            0


                                                                                   155 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           156 / 477
Properties of the continuous-time market model



Assumptions:
    Dimension of the underlying Brownian motion
    = number of stocks
    Past and present prices are the only sources of information for the
    investors
    ⇒ Choose Brownian filtration {Ft }t∈[0,T ]

Aim: Final wealths X (T ) when starting with initial capital of x.




                                                                     157 / 477
General assumption / notation

General assumption for this section
                                        d =m


Notation
                                t

           γ(t) := exp −            r (s) ds
                            0
           θ(t) := σ −1 (t) b(t) − r (t) 1
                                t                         t
                                        T         1                  2
           Z (t) := exp −           θ(s) dW (s) −             θ(s)       ds
                                                  2
                            0                         0
           H(t) := γ(t) · Z (t)

                                                                              158 / 477
Properties of the continuous-time market model


   b, r uniformly bounded
   σσ T uniformly positive definite
   ⇒ θ(t) 2 uniformly bounded
   Interpretation of θ(t): Relative risk premium for stock investment.
   Process H(t) is important for option pricing.
   H(t) is positive, continuous, and progressively measurable with
   respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] .
   H(t) is the unique solution of the SDE

                 dH(t) = −H(t) r (t) dt + θ(t)T dW (t)
                  H(0) = 1.



                                                                   159 / 477
Completeness of the market



Theorem: Completeness of the market
(1) Let the self-financing pair (π, c) consisting of a portfolio process π
    and a consumption process c be admissible for an initial wealth of
    x ≥ 0, i.e.,
                               (π, c) ∈ A(x).
    Then the corresponding wealth process X (t) satisfies
                                t

           E H(t) X (t) +           H(s)c(s) ds   ≤ x for all t ∈ [0, T ].
                            0




                                                                             160 / 477
Completeness of the market


Theorem: Completeness of the market
(2) Let B ≥ 0 be an FT -measurable random variable and c(t) a
    consumption process satisfying
                                   T

                x := E H(T ) B +        H(s)c(s) ds   < ∞.
                                   0

   Then there exists a portfolio process π(t) with (π, c) ∈ A(x) and
   the corresponding wealth process X (t) satisfies

                           X (T ) = B    P-a.s.



                                                                  161 / 477
Completeness of the market

   H(t) can be regarded as the appropriate discounting process that
   determines the initial wealth at time t = 0
                       T

                  E        H(s) · c(s) ds + E (H(T ) · B)
                      0

   which is necessary to attain future aims.
   (1) puts bounds on the desires of an investor given his initial
   capital x ≥ 0.
   (2) proves that future aims which are feasible in the sense of part
   (1) can be realized.
   (2) says that each desired final wealth in t = T can be attained
   exactly via trading according to an appropriate self-financing pair
   (π, c) if one possesses sufficient initial capital
   (completeness/complete model).
                                                                     162 / 477
Completeness of the market




Remark
   1/H(t) is the wealth process corresponding to the pair

                          π(t), c(t) = σ −1 (t)T θ(t), 0

    with initial wealth    x := 1/H(0) = 1
    and final wealth        B:= 1/H(T ).




                                                            163 / 477
Outline

2   The Continuous-Time Market Model
      Modeling the Security Prices
      Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales
      Continuation: Modeling the Security prices
                         ˆ
      Excursion 2: The Ito Integral
                         ˆ
      Excursion 3: The Ito Formula
      Trading Strategy and Wealth Process
      Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model
      Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem




                                                           164 / 477
Excursion 4: The martingale representation theorem



General assumptions
(Ω, F, P) complete probability space.
{(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) m-dimensional Brownian motion.
{Ft }t Brownian filtration.


Definition
A real-valued martingale {(Mt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] with respect to the Brownian
filtration {Ft }t is called a Brownian martingale.




                                                                      165 / 477
The martingale representation theorem

Martingale representation theorem
Let {(Mt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] be a square-integrable Brownian martingale, i.e.,

                        EMt2 < ∞ for all t ∈ [0, T ].

Then there exists a progressively measurable Rm -valued process Ψ(t)
with
                              T
                                                2
                         E               Ψ(t)       dt   <∞
                             0

and
                                     t

                  Mt = M0 +              Ψ(s)T dW (s) P-a.s. .
                                 0



                                                                        166 / 477
The martingale representation theorem


Corollary
Let {(Mt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] be a local martingale with respect to the Brownian
filtration {Ft }t . Then there exists a progressively measurable
Rm -valued process Ψ(t) with
                             T
                                            2
                                     Ψ(t)       dt < ∞
                            0

and
                                     t

                  Mt = M0 +              Ψ(s)T dW (s) P-a.s.
                                 0




                                                                       167 / 477
The martingale representation theorem




Remark
    Each local martingale with respect to the Brownian filtration can
                           ˆ
    be represented as an Ito process.
                                                        ˆ
    Each Brownian martingale can be represented as an Ito process.


⇒ Quadratic variation and quadratic covariation are defined.




                                                                  168 / 477
Outline




3   Option Pricing




                     169 / 477
Outline



3   Option Pricing
      Introduction
      Examples
      The Replication Principle
      Arbitrage Opportunity
      Continuation
      Partial Differential Approach (PDA)
      Arbitrage & Option Pricing




                                            170 / 477
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization
Portfolio Optimization

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Was ist angesagt?

Risk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility Theory
Risk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility TheoryRisk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility Theory
Risk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility TheoryAshwin Rao
 
A Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation Problem
A Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation ProblemA Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation Problem
A Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation ProblemErika G. G.
 
Optimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generation
Optimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generationOptimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generation
Optimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generationDelta Pi Systems
 
Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...
  Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...  Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...
Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...LARCA UPC
 
Topological Inference via Meshing
Topological Inference via MeshingTopological Inference via Meshing
Topological Inference via MeshingDon Sheehy
 
NIPS2007: learning using many examples
NIPS2007: learning using many examplesNIPS2007: learning using many examples
NIPS2007: learning using many exampleszukun
 
Ada boost brown boost performance with noisy data
Ada boost brown boost performance with noisy dataAda boost brown boost performance with noisy data
Ada boost brown boost performance with noisy dataShadhin Rahman
 
Gradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introduction
Gradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introductionGradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introduction
Gradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introductionChristian Perone
 

Was ist angesagt? (16)

Slides edf-1
Slides edf-1Slides edf-1
Slides edf-1
 
Risk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility Theory
Risk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility TheoryRisk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility Theory
Risk-Aversion, Risk-Premium and Utility Theory
 
HFTperformEvalPRES
HFTperformEvalPRESHFTperformEvalPRES
HFTperformEvalPRES
 
Fuzzy logic in ATM
Fuzzy logic in ATMFuzzy logic in ATM
Fuzzy logic in ATM
 
Midterm I Review
Midterm I ReviewMidterm I Review
Midterm I Review
 
A Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation Problem
A Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation ProblemA Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation Problem
A Maximum Entropy Approach to the Loss Data Aggregation Problem
 
Optimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generation
Optimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generationOptimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generation
Optimal control of coupled PDE networks with automated code generation
 
Lecture1
Lecture1Lecture1
Lecture1
 
Jsm09 talk
Jsm09 talkJsm09 talk
Jsm09 talk
 
Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...
  Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...  Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...
Spectral Learning Methods for Finite State Machines with Applications to Na...
 
Topological Inference via Meshing
Topological Inference via MeshingTopological Inference via Meshing
Topological Inference via Meshing
 
Mountain Range Options
Mountain Range OptionsMountain Range Options
Mountain Range Options
 
Slides brussels
Slides brusselsSlides brussels
Slides brussels
 
NIPS2007: learning using many examples
NIPS2007: learning using many examplesNIPS2007: learning using many examples
NIPS2007: learning using many examples
 
Ada boost brown boost performance with noisy data
Ada boost brown boost performance with noisy dataAda boost brown boost performance with noisy data
Ada boost brown boost performance with noisy data
 
Gradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introduction
Gradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introductionGradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introduction
Gradient-based optimization for Deep Learning: a short introduction
 

Andere mochten auch

User interface Design
User interface DesignUser interface Design
User interface DesignSSA KPI
 
Coalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A Survey
Coalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A SurveyCoalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A Survey
Coalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A SurveySSA KPI
 
Human Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary Approach
Human Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary ApproachHuman Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary Approach
Human Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary ApproachSSA KPI
 
From Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea waves
From Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea wavesFrom Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea waves
From Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea wavesSSA KPI
 
Talking with money
Talking with moneyTalking with money
Talking with moneySSA KPI
 
AACIMP 2011 Computer Science
AACIMP 2011 Computer ScienceAACIMP 2011 Computer Science
AACIMP 2011 Computer ScienceSSA KPI
 
Introduction to Non-cooperative Game Theory
Introduction to Non-cooperative Game TheoryIntroduction to Non-cooperative Game Theory
Introduction to Non-cooperative Game TheorySSA KPI
 
Engineering role in sustainability
Engineering role in sustainabilityEngineering role in sustainability
Engineering role in sustainabilitySSA KPI
 
Grand challenges in energy
Grand challenges in energyGrand challenges in energy
Grand challenges in energySSA KPI
 
Germany presentation
Germany presentationGermany presentation
Germany presentationSSA KPI
 

Andere mochten auch (10)

User interface Design
User interface DesignUser interface Design
User interface Design
 
Coalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A Survey
Coalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A SurveyCoalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A Survey
Coalitional Games with Interval-Type Payoffs: A Survey
 
Human Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary Approach
Human Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary ApproachHuman Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary Approach
Human Reproduction and Utility Functions: An Evolutionary Approach
 
From Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea waves
From Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea wavesFrom Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea waves
From Huygens odd sympathy to the energy Huygens' extraction from the sea waves
 
Talking with money
Talking with moneyTalking with money
Talking with money
 
AACIMP 2011 Computer Science
AACIMP 2011 Computer ScienceAACIMP 2011 Computer Science
AACIMP 2011 Computer Science
 
Introduction to Non-cooperative Game Theory
Introduction to Non-cooperative Game TheoryIntroduction to Non-cooperative Game Theory
Introduction to Non-cooperative Game Theory
 
Engineering role in sustainability
Engineering role in sustainabilityEngineering role in sustainability
Engineering role in sustainability
 
Grand challenges in energy
Grand challenges in energyGrand challenges in energy
Grand challenges in energy
 
Germany presentation
Germany presentationGermany presentation
Germany presentation
 

Ähnlich wie Portfolio Optimization

Multi risk factor model
Multi risk factor model Multi risk factor model
Multi risk factor model Stefan Duprey
 
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysisThe Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysisDaniel Bruggisser
 
Portfolio theory and capm
Portfolio theory and capmPortfolio theory and capm
Portfolio theory and capmBhaskar T
 
L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18
L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18
L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18analystbuddy
 

Ähnlich wie Portfolio Optimization (8)

2005 f c49_note04
2005 f c49_note042005 f c49_note04
2005 f c49_note04
 
Capm 1
Capm 1Capm 1
Capm 1
 
Ch05
Ch05Ch05
Ch05
 
Captum Palisades UC 2011
Captum Palisades UC 2011Captum Palisades UC 2011
Captum Palisades UC 2011
 
Multi risk factor model
Multi risk factor model Multi risk factor model
Multi risk factor model
 
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysisThe Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
 
Portfolio theory and capm
Portfolio theory and capmPortfolio theory and capm
Portfolio theory and capm
 
L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18
L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18
L2 flash cards portfolio management - SS 18
 

Mehr von SSA KPI

Consensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable development
Consensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable developmentConsensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable development
Consensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable developmentSSA KPI
 
Competences in sustainability in engineering education
Competences in sustainability in engineering educationCompetences in sustainability in engineering education
Competences in sustainability in engineering educationSSA KPI
 
Introducatio SD for enginers
Introducatio SD for enginersIntroducatio SD for enginers
Introducatio SD for enginersSSA KPI
 
DAAD-10.11.2011
DAAD-10.11.2011DAAD-10.11.2011
DAAD-10.11.2011SSA KPI
 
'Green' startup investment
'Green' startup investment'Green' startup investment
'Green' startup investmentSSA KPI
 
Dynamics of dice games
Dynamics of dice gamesDynamics of dice games
Dynamics of dice gamesSSA KPI
 
Energy Security Costs
Energy Security CostsEnergy Security Costs
Energy Security CostsSSA KPI
 
Naturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environments
Naturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environmentsNaturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environments
Naturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environmentsSSA KPI
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5SSA KPI
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4SSA KPI
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3SSA KPI
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2SSA KPI
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1SSA KPI
 
Fluorescent proteins in current biology
Fluorescent proteins in current biologyFluorescent proteins in current biology
Fluorescent proteins in current biologySSA KPI
 
Neurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functions
Neurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functionsNeurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functions
Neurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functionsSSA KPI
 
Elements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal Systems
Elements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal SystemsElements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal Systems
Elements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal SystemsSSA KPI
 
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2SSA KPI
 
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1SSA KPI
 
A biomathematical model for Phoma tracheiphila Citrus resistance screening
A biomathematical model  for Phoma tracheiphila  Citrus resistance screeningA biomathematical model  for Phoma tracheiphila  Citrus resistance screening
A biomathematical model for Phoma tracheiphila Citrus resistance screeningSSA KPI
 
Phytopathology Modelling. Introduction
Phytopathology Modelling. IntroductionPhytopathology Modelling. Introduction
Phytopathology Modelling. IntroductionSSA KPI
 

Mehr von SSA KPI (20)

Consensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable development
Consensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable developmentConsensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable development
Consensus and interaction on a long term strategy for sustainable development
 
Competences in sustainability in engineering education
Competences in sustainability in engineering educationCompetences in sustainability in engineering education
Competences in sustainability in engineering education
 
Introducatio SD for enginers
Introducatio SD for enginersIntroducatio SD for enginers
Introducatio SD for enginers
 
DAAD-10.11.2011
DAAD-10.11.2011DAAD-10.11.2011
DAAD-10.11.2011
 
'Green' startup investment
'Green' startup investment'Green' startup investment
'Green' startup investment
 
Dynamics of dice games
Dynamics of dice gamesDynamics of dice games
Dynamics of dice games
 
Energy Security Costs
Energy Security CostsEnergy Security Costs
Energy Security Costs
 
Naturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environments
Naturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environmentsNaturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environments
Naturally Occurring Radioactivity (NOR) in natural and anthropic environments
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 5
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 4
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 3
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 2
 
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1
Advanced energy technology for sustainable development. Part 1
 
Fluorescent proteins in current biology
Fluorescent proteins in current biologyFluorescent proteins in current biology
Fluorescent proteins in current biology
 
Neurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functions
Neurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functionsNeurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functions
Neurotransmitter systems of the brain and their functions
 
Elements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal Systems
Elements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal SystemsElements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal Systems
Elements of Theory for Multi-Neuronal Systems
 
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 2
 
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1
Molecular Mechanisms of Pain. Part 1
 
A biomathematical model for Phoma tracheiphila Citrus resistance screening
A biomathematical model  for Phoma tracheiphila  Citrus resistance screeningA biomathematical model  for Phoma tracheiphila  Citrus resistance screening
A biomathematical model for Phoma tracheiphila Citrus resistance screening
 
Phytopathology Modelling. Introduction
Phytopathology Modelling. IntroductionPhytopathology Modelling. Introduction
Phytopathology Modelling. Introduction
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen

Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...EduSkills OECD
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesFatimaKhan178732
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionSafetyChain Software
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Krashi Coaching
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxGaneshChakor2
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxSayali Powar
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Celine George
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting DataJhengPantaleon
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxVS Mahajan Coaching Centre
 
Micromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of Powders
Micromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of PowdersMicromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of Powders
Micromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of PowdersChitralekhaTherkar
 
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3JemimahLaneBuaron
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Sapana Sha
 
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website AppURLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website AppCeline George
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxheathfieldcps1
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfchloefrazer622
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfsanyamsingh5019
 
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityParis 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityGeoBlogs
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdfssuser54595a
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsanshu789521
 

Kürzlich hochgeladen (20)

Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
Presentation by Andreas Schleicher Tackling the School Absenteeism Crisis 30 ...
 
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and ActinidesSeparation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
Separation of Lanthanides/ Lanthanides and Actinides
 
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory InspectionMastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
Mastering the Unannounced Regulatory Inspection
 
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
Kisan Call Centre - To harness potential of ICT in Agriculture by answer farm...
 
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptxCARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
CARE OF CHILD IN INCUBATOR..........pptx
 
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptxPOINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
POINT- BIOCHEMISTRY SEM 2 ENZYMES UNIT 5.pptx
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
 
Micromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of Powders
Micromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of PowdersMicromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of Powders
Micromeritics - Fundamental and Derived Properties of Powders
 
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
Call Girls in Dwarka Mor Delhi Contact Us 9654467111
 
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website AppURLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
URLs and Routing in the Odoo 17 Website App
 
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptxThe basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
The basics of sentences session 2pptx copy.pptx
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
 
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activityParis 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
Paris 2024 Olympic Geographies - an activity
 
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
18-04-UA_REPORT_MEDIALITERAСY_INDEX-DM_23-1-final-eng.pdf
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
 

Portfolio Optimization

  • 1. Portfolio Optimization Gerhard-Wilhelm Weber1 Erik Kropat2 Zafer-Korcan Görgülü3 1 Institute of Applied Mathematics Middle East Technical University Ankara, Turkey 2 Department of Mathematics University of Erlangen-Nuremberg Erlangen, Germany 3 University of the Federal Armed Forces Munich, Germany 2008 1 / 477
  • 2. Outline I 1 The Mean-Variance Approach in a One-Period Model Introduction 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 2 / 477
  • 3. Outline II 3 Option Pricing Introduction Examples The Replication Principle Arbitrage Opportunity Continuation Partial Differential Approach (PDA) Arbitrage & Option Pricing 3 / 477
  • 4. Outline III 4 Pricing of Exotic Options and Numerical Algorithms Introduction Examples Examples Equivalent Martingale Measure Exotic Options with Explicit Pricing Formulae Weak Convergence of Stochastic Processes Monte-Carlo Simulation Approximation via Binomial Trees The Pathwise Binomial Approach of Rogers and Stapleton 4 / 477
  • 5. Outline IV 5 Optimal Portfolios Introduction and Formulation of the Problem The martingale method Optimal Option Portfolios Excursion 8: Stochastic Control Maximize expected value in presence of quadratic control costs Introduction Portfolio Optimization via Stochastic Control Method 5 / 477
  • 6. Outline 1 The Mean-Variance Approach in a One-Period Model 6 / 477
  • 7. Outline 1 The Mean-Variance Approach in a One-Period Model Introduction 7 / 477
  • 8. Introduction MVA Based on H. M ARKOWITZ OPM • Decisions on investment strategies only at the beginning of the period • Consequences of these decisions will be observed at the end of the period (−→ no action in between: static model) 8 / 477
  • 9. The one-period model Market with d traded securities d different securities with positive prices p1 , . . . , pd at time t = 0 Security prices P1 (T ), . . . , Pd (T ) at final time t = T not foreseeable −→ modeled as non-negative random variables on probability space (Ω, F , P) 9 / 477
  • 10. Securities in a OPM Returns of Securities Pi (T ) Ri (T ) := pi (1 ≤ i ≤ d ) Estimated Means, Variances and Covariances E (Ri (T )) = µi , Cov Ri (T ), Rj (T ) = σij (1 ≤ i ≤ d ) Remark The matrix σ := σij i,j∈{1,...,d} is positive semi-definite as it is a variance-covariance matrix. 10 / 477
  • 11. Securities in a OPM Each security perfectly divisable Hold ϕi ∈ R shares of security i (1 ≤ i ≤ d ) Negative position (ϕi < 0 for some i) corresponds to a selling −→ Not allowed in OPM −→ No negative positions: pi ≥ 0 (1 ≤ i ≤ d) −→ No transaction costs 11 / 477
  • 12. Budget equation and portfolio return The Budget Equation Investor with initial wealth x > 0 holds ϕi ≥ 0 shares of security i with ϕi · pi = x 1≤i≤d The Portfolio Vector π := (π1 , . . . , πd )T ϕi · pi πi := (1 ≤ i ≤ d ) x Portfolio Return R π := πi · Ri (T ) = π T R 1≤i≤d 12 / 477
  • 13. Budget equation and portfolio return Remark πi . . . fraction of total wealth invested in security i ϕi · pi 1≤i≤d x πi = = =1 x x 1≤i≤d X π (T ) . . . final wealth corresponding to x and π X π (T ) = ϕi · Pi (T ) 1≤i≤d 13 / 477
  • 14. Budget equation and portfolio return Remark (continued) Portfolio Return ϕi · pi Pi (T ) X π (T ) Rπ = πi · Ri (T ) = · = x pi x 1≤i≤d 1≤i≤d Portfolio Mean and Portfolio Variance E (R π ) = πi · µi , Var (R π ) = πi · σij · πj 1≤i≤d 1≤i,j≤d 14 / 477
  • 15. Selection of a portfolio–criterion (i) Maximize mean return (choose security of highest mean return) −→ risky, big fluctuations of return (ii) Minimize risk of fluction 15 / 477
  • 16. Selection of a portfolio–approach by Markowitz (MVA) Balance Risk (Portfolio Variance) and Return (Portfolio Mean) (i) Maximize E (R π ) under given upper bound c1 for Var (R π )   πi ≥ 0 (1 ≤ i ≤ d )    π πi = 1 max E (R ) subject to π∈Rd  1≤i≤d    Var (R π ) ≤ c1 (ii) Minimize Var (R π ) under given lower bound c2 for E (R π )   πi ≥ 0  (1 ≤ i ≤ d )  min Var (R π ) subject to πi = 1 π∈Rd   1≤i≤d  E (R π ) ≥ c2 16 / 477
  • 17. Solution methods (i) Linear Optimization Problem with quadratic constraint −→ No standard algorithms, numerical inefficient (ii) Quadratic Optimization Problem with positive semidefinite objective matrix σ −→ efficient algorithms (i.e., G OLDFARB/I DNANI, G ILL/M URRAY) Feasible region non-empty if c2 ≤ max µi 1≤i≤d σ positive definite and feasible region non-empty −→ unique solution (even if one security riskless) 17 / 477
  • 18. Relations between the formulations (i) and (ii) Theorem Assume: σ positive definite min µi ≤ c2 ≤ max µi c2 ∈ R+ 0 1≤i≤d 1≤i≤d min σ 2 (π) ≤ c1 ≤ max σ 2 (π) c1 ∈ R+ 0 πi ≥0, 1≤i≤d πi =1 πi ≥0, 1≤i≤d πi =1 Then ∗ (1) π ∗ solves (i) with Var R π = c1 =⇒ π ∗ solves (ii) with ∗ c2 := E R π (2) π solves (ii) with E R π = c2 =⇒ π solves (i) with c1 := Var R π 18 / 477
  • 19. The diversification effect–example Holding different Securities reduces Variance Both security prices fluctuate randomly σ11 , σ22 > 0 independent σ12 = σ21 = 0 0.5 Then for the Portfolio π = we get 0.5 σ11 σ22 Var (R π ) = Var (0.5 · R1 + 0.5 · R2 ) = + 4 4 19 / 477
  • 20. The diversification effect–example Holding different Securities reduces Variance 0.5 −→ If σ11 = σ22 then the Variance of Portfolio is half as big 0.5 1 0 as that of or 0 1 −→ Reduction of Variance . . . Diversification Effect depends on number of traded securities 20 / 477
  • 21. Example Mean-Variance Criterion Investing into seemingly bad security can be optimal. Let be 1 0.1 −0.1 µ= , σ= 0.9 −0.1 0.15 Formulation (ii) becomes (II) min Var (R π ) = min 2 2 0.1 · π1 + 0.15 · π2 − 0.2 · π1 π2 π π   π1 , π2 ≥ 0 subject to π1 + π2 = 1  E (R π ) = π1 + 0.9 · π2 ≥ 0.96 21 / 477
  • 22. Example 1 0.5 Consider Portfolios and (does not satify 0 0.5 expectation constraint) T T Var R (1,0) = 0.1 , E R (1,0) =1 T T Var R (0.5,0.5) = 0.125 , E R (0.5,0.5) = 0.95 22 / 477
  • 23. Example Ignore expectation constraint and remember π1 , π2 ≥ 0 π1 + π2 = 1. Hence min 0.1 · π1 + 0.15 · (1 − π1 )2 − 0.2 · π1 · (1 − π1 ) 2 π 2 = min 0.45 · π1 − 0.5 · π1 + 0.15 π 0.5 −→ Minimizing Portfolio (No solution of (II) but better than ) 0.5 1 5 π= · 9 4 T −→ Portfolio Return Variance Var R ( 9 , 9 ) 5 4 ¯ = 0.001 T −→ Portfolio Return Mean E R ( 9 , 9 ) 5 4 ¯ = 0.95 23 / 477
  • 24. Example 1.0 π2 0.5 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.6 1.0 π1 Pairs (π1 , π2 ) satisfying expectation constraint are above the dotted line Intersect with line π1 + π2 = 1 −→ Feasible region of MeanVariance Problem (bold line) 24 / 477
  • 25. Example 0.15 0.1 Var 0.05 0 0 0.5 0.6 1.0 1.5 π1 Portfolio Return Variance (as function of π1 ) of all pairs satisfying π1 + π2 = 1 Minimum in feasible region π ∈ [0.6, 1] is attained at π = 0.6 Optimal Portfolio in (II) →∗ = − 0.6 ∗ ∗ π with Var R π = 0.012 , E Rπ = 0.96 0.4 25 / 477
  • 26. Stock price model OPM No assumption on distribution of security returns Solving MV Problem just needed expectations and covariances 26 / 477
  • 27. Stock price model OPM with just one security (price p1 at time t = 0 ) At time T security may have price d · p1 or u · p1 q: probability of decreasing by factor d 1−q : probability of increasing by factor u (u > d ) Mean and Variance of Return P1 (T ) E (R1 (T )) =E = q · u + (1 − q) · d p1 P1 (T ) Var (R1 (T )) = Var = q · u 2 + (1 − q) · d 2 p1 − (q · u + (1 − q) · d )2 27 / 477
  • 28. Stock price model OPM with just one security (price p1 at time t = 0 ) After n periods the security has price P1 (n · T ) = p1 · u Xn · d n−Xn with Xn ∼ B(n, p) number of up-movements of price in n periods 28 / 477
  • 29. Comments on MVA Only trading at initial time t = 0 No reaction to current price changes possible ( −→ static model) Risk of investment only modeled by variance of return Need of Continuous-Time Market Models Discrete-time multi-period models (many periods −→ no fast algorithms) 29 / 477
  • 30. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model 30 / 477
  • 31. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 31 / 477
  • 32. Modeling the security prices Market with d+1 securities d risky stocks with prices p1 , p2 , . . . , pd at time t = 0 and random prices P1 (t), P2 (t), . . . , Pd (t) at times t > 0 1 bond with price p0 at time t = 0 and deterministic price P0 (t) at times t > 0. Assume: Perfectly devisible securities, no transaction costs. ⇒ Modeling of the price development on the time interval [0, T ]. 32 / 477
  • 33. The bond price Assume: Continuous compounding of interest at a constant rate r : Bond price: P0 (t) = p0 · er ·t for t ∈ [0, T ] a non-constant, time-dependent and integrable rate r (t): t r (s) ds Bond price: P0 (t) = p0 · e 0 for t ∈ [0, T ] 33 / 477
  • 34. The stock price Stock price = random fluctuations around an intrinsic bond part 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 log-linear model for a stock price ln(Pi (t)) = ln(pi ) + bi · t + ”randomness” 34 / 477
  • 35. The stock price Randomness is assumed to have no tendency, i.e., E("randomness") = 0, to be time-dependent, to represent the sum of all deviations of ln(Pi (t)) from ln(pi ) + bi · t on [0, T ], ∼ N (0, σ 2 t) for some σ > 0. 35 / 477
  • 36. The stock price Deviation at time t Y (t) := ln(Pi (t)) − ln(pi ) − bi · t with Y (t) ∼ N (0, σ 2 t) Properties: E (Y (t)) = 0, Y (t) is time-dependent. 36 / 477
  • 37. The stock price Y (t) = Y (δ) + (Y (t) − Y (δ)), δ ∈ (0, t) Distribution of the increments of the deviation Y (t) − Y (δ) depends only on the time span t − δ is independent of Y (s), s ≤ δ =⇒ Y (t) − Y (δ) ∼ N 0, σ 2 (t − δ) 37 / 477
  • 38. The stock price Existence and properties of the stochastic process {Y (t)}t∈[0,∞) will be studied in the excursion on the Brownian motion. 38 / 477
  • 39. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 39 / 477
  • 40. General assumptions General assumptions Let (Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space with sample space Ω, σ-field F and probability measure P. 40 / 477
  • 41. Filtration Definition Let {Ft }t∈I be a family of sub-σ-fields of F, I be an ordered index set with Fs ⊂ Ft for s < t, s, t ∈ I. The family {Ft }t∈I is called a filtration. A filtration describes flow of information over time. Ft models events observable up to time t. If a random variable Xt is Ft -measurable, we are able to determine its value from the information given at time t. 41 / 477
  • 42. Stochastic process Definition A set {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I consisting of a filtration {Ft }t∈I and a family of Rn -valued random variables {Xt }t∈I with Xt being Ft -measurable is called a stochastic process with filtration {Ft }t∈I . 42 / 477
  • 43. Remark Remark I = [0, ∞) or I = [0, T ]. Canoncial filtration (natural filtration) of {Xt }t∈I : Ft := FtX := σ{Xs | s ≤ t, s ∈ I}. Notation: {Xt }t∈I = {X (t)}t∈I = X . 43 / 477
  • 44. Sample path Sample path For fixed ω ∈ Ω the set X .(ω) := {Xt (ω)}t∈I = {X (t, ω)}t∈I is called a sample path or a realization of the stochastic process. 44 / 477
  • 45. Identification of stochastic processes Can two stochastic processes be identified with each other? Definition Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) and {(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) be two stochastic processes. Y is a modification of X , if P{ω | Xt (ω) = Yt (ω)} = 1 for all t ≥ 0. Definition Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) and {(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) be two stochastic processes. X and Y are indistinguishable, if P{ω | Xt (ω) = Yt (ω) for all t ∈ [0, ∞)} = 1. 45 / 477
  • 46. Identification of stochastic processes Remark X , Y indistinguishable ⇒ Y modification of X . Theorem Let the stochastic process Y be a modification of X . If both processes have continuous sample paths P-almost surely, then X and Y are indistinguishable. 46 / 477
  • 47. Brownian motion Definition The real-valued process {Wt }t≥0 with continuous sample paths and i) W0 = 0 P-a.s. ii) Wt − Ws ∼ N (0, t − s) for 0 ≤ s < t "stationary increments" iii) Wt − Ws independent of Wu − Wr for 0 ≤ r ≤ u ≤ s < t "independent increments" is called a one-dimensional Brownian motion. 47 / 477
  • 48. Brownian motion Remark By an n-dimensional Brownian motion we mean the Rn -valued process W (t) = (W1 (t), . . . , Wn (t)), with components Wi being independent one-dimensional Brownian motions. 48 / 477
  • 49. Brownian motion and filtration Brownian motion can be associated with natural filtration FtW := σ{Ws | 0 ≤ s ≤ t}, t ∈ [0, ∞) P-augmentation of the natural filtration (Brownian filtration) Ft := σ{FtW ∪ N | N ∈ F, P(N) = 0}, t ∈ [0, ∞) 49 / 477
  • 50. Brownian motion and filtration Requirement iii) of a Brownian motion with respect to a filtration {Ft }t≥0 is often stated as iii)∗ Wt − Ws independent of Fs , 0 ≤ s < t. {Ft }t≥0 natural filtration (Brownian filtration) ⇒ iii) and iii)∗ are equivalent. {Ft }t≥0 arbitrary filtration ⇒ iii) and iii)∗ are usually not equivalent. Convention If we consider a Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t≥0 with an arbitrary filtration we implicitly assume iii)∗ to be fulfilled. 50 / 477
  • 51. Existence of the Brownian motion How can we show the existence of a stochastic process satisfying the requirements of a Brownian motion? Construction and existence proofs are long and technical. Construction based on weak convergence and approximation by random walks [Billingsley 1968]. Wiener measure, Wiener process. 51 / 477
  • 52. Brownian motion and filtration Theorem The Brownian filtration {Ft }t≥0 is right-continuous as well as left-continuous, i.e., we have Ft = Ft+ := Ft+ε and Ft = Ft− := σ Fs . ε>0 s<t Definition A filtration {Gt }t≥0 satifies the usual conditions, if it is right-continuous and G0 contains all P-null sets of F. General assumption for this section Let {Ft }t≥0 be a filtration which satisfies the usual conditions. 52 / 477
  • 53. Martingales Definition The real-valued process {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I with E |Xt | < ∞ for all t ∈ I (where I is an ordered index set), is called a super-martingale, if for all s, t ∈ I with s ≤ t we have E (Xt |Fs ) ≤ Xs P-a.s. , a sub-martingale, if for all s, t ∈ I with s ≤ t we have E (Xt |Fs ) ≥ Xs P-a.s. , a martingale, if for all s, t ∈ I with s ≤ t we have E (Xt |Fs ) = Xs P-a.s. . 53 / 477
  • 54. Interpretation of the martingale concept Example: Modeling games of chance Xn : Wealth of a gambler after n-th participation in a fair game Martingale condition: E (Xn+1 |Fn ) = Xn P-a.s. ⇒ "After the game the player is as rich as he was before" favorable game = sub-martingale non-favorable game = super-martingale 54 / 477
  • 55. Interpretation of the martingale concept Example: Tossing a fair coin "Head": Gambler receives one dollar "Tail": Gambler loses one dollar ⇒ Martingale 55 / 477
  • 56. Interpretation of the martingale concept Theorem A one-dimensional Brownian motion Wt is a martingale. Remark Each stochastic process with independent, centered increments is a martingale with respect to its natural filtration. The Brownian motion with drift µ and volatility σ Xt := µt + σWt , µ ∈ R, σ ∈ R is a martingale if µ = 0, a super-martingale if µ ≤ 0 and a sub-martingale if µ ≥ 0. 56 / 477
  • 57. Interpretation of the martingale concept Theorem (1) Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I be a martingale and ϕ : R → R be a convex function with E |ϕ(Xt )| < ∞ for all t ∈ I. Then {(ϕ(Xt ), Ft )}t∈I is a sub-martingale. (2) Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I be a sub-martingale and ϕ : R → R a convex, non-decreasing function with E |ϕ(Xt )| < ∞ for all t ∈ I. Then {(ϕ(Xt ), Ft )}t∈I is a sub-martingale. 57 / 477
  • 58. Interpretation of the martingale concept Remark (1) Typical applications are given by ϕ(x) = x 2 , ϕ(x) = |x|. (2) The theorem is also valid for d -dimensional vectors X (t) = (X1 (t), . . . , Xd (t)) of martingales and convex functions ϕ : Rd → R. 58 / 477
  • 59. Stopping time Definition A stopping time with respect to a filtration {Ft }t∈[0,∞) (or {Fn }n∈N ) is an F-measurable random variable τ : Ω → [0, ∞] (or τ : Ω → N ∪ {∞}) with {ω ∈ Ω | τ (ω) ≤ t} ∈ Ft for all t ∈ [0, ∞) (or {ω ∈ Ω | τ (ω) ≤ n} ∈ Fn for all n ∈ N). Theorem If τ1 , τ2 are both stopping times then τ1 ∧ τ2 := min{τ1 , τ2 } is also a stopping time. 59 / 477
  • 60. The stopped process The stopped process Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈I be a stochastic process, let I be either N or [0, ∞), and τ a stopping time. The stopped process {Xt∧τ }t∈I is defined by Xt (ω) if t ≤ τ (ω), Xt∧τ (ω) := Xτ (ω) (ω) if t > τ (ω). Example: Wealth of a gambler who participates in a sequence of games until he is either bankrupt or has reached a given level of wealth. 60 / 477
  • 61. The stopped filtration The stopped filtration Let τ be a stopping time with respect to a filtration {Ft }t∈[0,∞) . σ-field of events determined prior to the stopping time τ Fτ := {A ∈ F | A ∩ {τ ≤ t} ∈ Ft for all t ∈ [0, ∞)} Stopped filtration {Fτ ∧t }t∈[0,∞) . 61 / 477
  • 62. The stopped filtration What will happen if we stop a martingale or a sub-martingale? Theorem: Optional sampling Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a right-continuous sub-martingale (or martingale). Let τ1 , τ2 be stopping times with τ1 ≤ τ2 . Then for all t ∈ [0, ∞) we have E (Xt∧τ2 | Ft∧τ1 ) ≥ Xt∧τ1 P-a.s. (or E (Xt∧τ2 | Ft∧τ1 ) = Xt∧τ1 P-a.s.). 62 / 477
  • 63. The stopped filtration Corollary Let τ be a stopping time and {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) a right-continuous sub-martingale (or martingale). Then the stopped process {(Xt∧τ , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) is also a sub-martingale (or martingale). 63 / 477
  • 64. The stopped filtration Theorem Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a right-continuous process. Then Xt is a martingale if and only if for all bounded stopping times τ we have EXτ = EX0 . → Characterization of a martingale 64 / 477
  • 65. The stopped filtration Definition Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a stochastic process with X0 = 0. If there is a non-decreasing sequence {τn }n∈N of stopping times with P lim τn = ∞ = 1, n→∞ such that (n) Xt := (Xt∧τn , Ft ) t∈[0,∞) is a martingale for all n ∈ N, then X is a local martingale. The sequence {τn }n∈N is called a localizing sequence corresponding to X . 65 / 477
  • 66. The stopped filtration Remark (1) Each martingale is a local martingale. (2) A local martingale with continuous paths is called continuous local martingale. (3) There exist local martingales which are not martingales. E (Xt ) need not exist for a local martingale. However, the expectation has to exist along the localizing sequence t ∧ τn . The local martingale is a martingale on the random time intervals [0, τn ]. Theorem A non-negative local martingale is a super-martingale. 66 / 477
  • 67. The stopped filtration Theorem: Doob’s inequality Let {Mt }t≥0 be a martingale with right-continuous paths and 2 E (MT ) < ∞ or all T > 0. Then, we have 2 2 E sup |Mt | ≤ 4 · E (MT ). 0≤t≤T Theorem Let {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be a non-negative super-martingale with right-continuous paths. Then, for λ > 0 we obtain λ·P ω sup Xs (ω) ≥ λ ≤ E (X0 ). 0≤s≤t 67 / 477
  • 68. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 68 / 477
  • 69. Continuation: The stock price log-linear model for a stock price ln(Pi (t)) = ln(pi ) + bi · t + ”randomness” Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t≥0 is the appropriate stochastic process to model the "randomness" 69 / 477
  • 70. Continuation: The stock price Market with one stock and one bond (d=1) ln(P1 (t)) = ln(p1 ) + b1 · t + σ11 Wt P1 (t) = p1 · exp b1 · t + σ11 Wt Market with d stocks and one bond (d>1) m ln(Pi (t)) = ln(pi ) + bi · t + σij Wj (t), i = 1, . . . , d j=1 m Pi (t) = pi · exp bi · t + σij Wj (t) , i = 1, . . . , d j=1 70 / 477
  • 71. Continuation: The stock price Distribution of the logarithm of the stock prices m 2 ln(Pi (t)) ∼ N ln(pi ) + bi · t, σij · t j=1 ⇒ Pi (t) is log-normally distributed. 71 / 477
  • 72. Continuation: The stock price Lemma m 1 2 Let bi := bi + 2 σij for i = 1, . . . , d . j=1 (1) E (Pi (t)) = pi · ebi t . m (2) Var (Pi (t)) = pi2 · exp(2bi t) · exp 2 σij t −1 . j=1 m 1 (3) Xt := a · exp cj Wj (t) − cj2 t with a, cj ∈ R, j = 1, . . . , m 2 j=1 is a martingale. 72 / 477
  • 73. Interpretation of the stock price model The stock price model m 1 2 Pi (t) = pi · exp(bi t) · exp σij Wj (t) − σij t , 2 j=1 Pi (0) = pi , i = 1, . . . , d . The stock price is the product of the mean stock price pi · exp(bi t) and a martingale with expectation 1, namely m 1 2 exp σij Wj (t) − σij t 2 j=1 which models the stock price around its mean value. 73 / 477
  • 74. Interpretation of the stock price model Vector of mean rates of stock returns b = (b1 , . . . , bd )T Volatility matrix   σ11 . . . σ1m  . .  σ= . . .. . .  . σd1 . . . σdm Pi (t) is a geometric Brownian motion with drift bi and volatility σi. = (σi1 , . . . , σim )T . 74 / 477
  • 75. Summary: Stock prices Bond price and stock prices P0 (t) = p0 · ert Bond price P0 (0)= p0 m 1 2 Pi (t) = pi · exp(bi t) · exp σij Wj (t) − σ t 2 ij Stock prices j=1 Pi (0) = pi , i = 1, . . . , d . 75 / 477
  • 76. Extension Extension: Model with non-constant, time-dependent, and integrable rates of return bi (t) and volatilities σ(t). Stock prices: t m 1 2 Pi (t) = pi · exp bi (s) − σij (s) ds 2 0 j=1 m t · exp σij (s) dWj (s) j=1 0 t Problem: σij (s) dWj (s) 0 ˆ ⇒ Stochastic integral (Ito integral) 76 / 477
  • 77. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 77 / 477
  • 78. ˆ The Ito integral Is it possible to define the stochastic integral t Xs (ω) dWs (ω) 0 ω-wise in a reasonable way? 78 / 477
  • 79. ˆ The Ito integral Theorem P-almost all paths of the Brownian motion {Wt }t∈[0,∞) are nowhere differentiable. ⇒ A definition of the form t t dWs (ω) Xs (ω) dWs (ω) = Xs (ω) ds ds 0 0 is impossible. 79 / 477
  • 80. ˆ The Ito integral Theorem With the definition 2n Zn (ω) := W i (ω) − W i−1 (ω) , n ∈ N, ω ∈ Ω 2n 2n i=1 we have n→∞ Zn (ω) − − ∞ −→ P-a.s. , i.e., the paths Wt (ω) of the Brownian motion admit infinite variation on the interval [0, 1] P-almost surely. The paths Wt (ω) of the Brownian motion have infinite variation on each non-empty finite interval [s1 , s2 ] ⊂ [0, ∞) P-almost surely. 80 / 477
  • 81. General assumptions General assumptions for this section Let (Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space equipped with a filtration {Ft }t satisfying the usual conditions. Further assume that on this space a Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) with respect to this filtration is defined. 81 / 477
  • 82. Simple process Definition A stochastic process {Xt }t∈[0,T ] is called a simple process if there exist real numbers 0 = t0 < t1 < . . . < tp = T , p ∈ N, and bounded random variables Φi : Ω → R, i = 0, 1, . . . , p, with Φ0 F0 -measurable, Φi Fti−1 -measurable, i = 1, . . . , p such that Xt (ω) has the representation p Xt (ω) = X (t, ω) = Φ0 (ω) · 1{0} (t) + Φi (ω) · 1(ti−1 ,ti ] (t) i=1 for each ω ∈ Ω. 82 / 477
  • 83. Simple process Remark Xt is Fti−1 -measurable for all t ∈ (ti−1 , ti ]. The paths X (., ω) of the simple process Xt are left-continuous step functions with height Φi (ω) · 1(ti−1 ,ti ] (t). 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 X(.,ω) 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0 t t2 t3 T 1 t 83 / 477
  • 84. Stochastic integral Definition For a simple process {Xt }t∈[0,T ] the stochastic integral I.(X ) for t ∈ (tk , tk +1 ] is defined according to t It (X ) := Xs dWs := Φi (Wti − Wti−1 ) + Φk +1 (Wt − Wtk ), 0 1≤i≤k or more generally for t ∈ [0, T ]: t It (X ) := Xs dWs := Φi (Wti ∧t − Wti−1 ∧t ). 0 1≤i≤p 84 / 477
  • 85. Stochastic integral Theorem: Elementary properties of the stochastic integral Let X := {Xt }t∈[0,T ] be a simple process. Then we have (1) {It (X )}t∈[0,T ] is a continuous martingale with respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] . In particular, we have E (It (X )) = 0 for all t ∈ [0, T ]. t 2 t (2) E Xs dWs =E 2 Xs ds for t ∈ [0, T ]. 0 0 t 2 T (3) E sup Xs dWs ≤4·E 2 Xs ds . 0≤t≤T 0 0 85 / 477
  • 86. Stochastic integral Remark (1) By (2) the stochastic integral is a square-integrable stochastic process. (2) For the simple process X ≡ 1 we obtain t 1 dWs = Wt 0 and t t 2 E dWs = E (Wt2 ) =t= ds. 0 0 86 / 477
  • 87. Stochastic integral Remark (1) Integrals with general boundaries: T T t Xs dWs := Xs dWs − Xs dWs for t ≤ T . t 0 0 For t ≤ T , A ∈ Ft we have T T 1A (ω) · Xs (ω) · 1[t,T ] (s) dWs = 1A (ω) · Xs (ω) dWs . 0 t (2) Let X , Y be simple processes, a, b ∈ R. Then we have It (aX + bY ) = a · It (X ) + b · It (Y ) (linearity) 87 / 477
  • 88. Measurability Definition A stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is called measurable if the mapping [0, ∞) × Ω → Rn (s, ω) → Xs (ω) is B([0, ∞)) ⊗ F-B(Rn )-measurable. Remark Measurability of the process X implies that X (., ω) is B([0, ∞))-B(Rn )-measurable for a fixed ω ∈ Ω. Thus, for all t ∈ [0, ∞), t i = 1, . . . , n, the integral Xi2 (s) ds is defined. 0 88 / 477
  • 89. Measurability Definition A stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is called progressively measurable if for all t ≥ 0 the mapping [0, t] × Ω → Rn (s, ω) → Xs (ω) is B([0, t]) ⊗ Gt -B(Rn )-measurable. 89 / 477
  • 90. Measurability Remark (1) If the real-valued process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is progressively measurable and bounded, then for all t ∈ [0, ∞) the integral t Xs ds is Gt -measurable. 0 (2) Every progressively measurable process is measurable. (3) Each measurable process possesses a progressively measurable modification. 90 / 477
  • 91. Measurability Theorem If all paths of the stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) are right-continuous (or left-continuous), then the process is progressively measurable. Theorem Let τ be a stopping time with respect to the filtration {Gt }t∈[0,∞) . If the stochastic process {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is progressively measurable, then so is the stopped process {(Xt∧τ , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) . In particular, Xt∧τ is Gt and Gt∧τ -measurable. 91 / 477
  • 92. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes Definition L2 [0, T ] := L2 [0, T ], Ω, F, {Ft }t∈[0,T ] , P := {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] real-valued stochastic process T {Xt }t progressively measurable, E Xt2 dt < ∞ 0 T Norm on L2 [0, T ]: X 2 T := E Xt2 dt . 0 92 / 477
  • 93. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes · 2 L2 -norm on the probability space T [0, T ] × Ω, B([0, T ]) ⊗ F, λ ⊗ P . · 2 semi-norm ( X −Y 2 = 0 ⇒ X = Y ). T T X equivalent to Y :⇔ X = Y a.s. λ ⊗ P. 93 / 477
  • 94. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes ˆ Ito isometry Let X be a simple process. The mapping X → I.(X ) induces by T T 2 2 2 2 I.(X ) LT := E Xs dWs =E Xs ds = X T 0 0 a norm on the space of stochastic integrals. ⇒ I.(X ) linear, norm-preserving (= isometry) ˆ ⇒ I.(X ) Ito isometry 94 / 477
  • 95. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes Use processes X ∈ L2 [0, T ] approximated by a sequence X (n) of simple processes. I.(X (n) ) is a Cauchy-sequence with respect to · LT . To show: I.(X (n) ) is convergent, limit independent of X (n) . Denote limit by I(X ) = Xs dWs . 95 / 477
  • 96. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes J(.) C X ∈ L2 [0, T ] _ _ _ _ _ _ _/ J(X ) ∈ M2 O O · T · LT X (n) / I(X (n) ) I(.) simple process stochastic integral for simple processes 96 / 477
  • 97. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes Theorem An arbitrary X ∈ L2 [0, T ] can be approximated by a sequence of simple processes X (n) . More precisely: There exists a sequence X (n) of simple processes with T (n) 2 lim E Xs − Xs ds = 0. n→∞ 0 97 / 477
  • 98. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes Lemma Let {(Xt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) be a martingale where the filtration {Gt }t∈[0,∞) satisfies the usual conditions. Then the process Xt possesses a right-continuous modification {(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) such that {(Yt , Gt )}t∈[0,∞) is a martingale. 98 / 477
  • 99. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes ˆ Construction of the Ito integral for processes in L2 [0, T ] There exists a unique linear mapping J from L2 [0, T ] into the space of continuous martingales on [0, T ] with respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] satisfying (1) X = {Xt }t∈[0,T ] simple process ⇒ P Jt (X ) = It (X ) for all t ∈ [0, T ] = 1 t (2) E Jt (X )2 = E 2 ˆ Xs ds Ito isometry 0 Uniqueness: If J, J ′ satisfy (1) and (2), then for all X ∈ L2 [0, T ] the processes J ′ (X ) and J(X ) are indistinguishable. 99 / 477
  • 100. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes Definition For X ∈ L2 [0, T ] and J as before we define by t Xs dWs := Jt (X ) 0 ˆ the stochastic integral (or Ito integral) of X with respect to W . 100 / 477
  • 101. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes Theorem: Special case of Doob’s inequality Let X ∈ L2 [0, T ]. Then we have t T 2 2 E sup Xs dWs ≤4·E Xs ds . 0≤t≤T 0 0 101 / 477
  • 102. Extension of the stochastic integral to L2 [0, T ]-processes Multi-dimensional generalization of the stochastic integral {(W (t), Ft )}t : m-dimensional Brownian motion with W (t) = (W1 (t), . . . , Wm (t)) {(X (t), Ft )}t : Rn,m -valued progressively measurable process with Xij ∈ L2 [0, T ]. ˆ Ito integral of X with respect to W :  t  m  X1j (s) dWj (s)   t  j=1   0   . .  X (s) dW (s) :=  . , t ∈ [0, T ]   0  m t     Xnj (s) dWj (s) j=1 0 102 / 477
  • 103. Further extension of the stochastic integral Definition H 2 [0, T ] := H 2 [0, T ], Ω, F, {Ft }t∈[0,T ] , P := {(Xt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] real-valued stochastic process {Xt }t progressively measurable, T Xt2 dt < ∞ P-a.s. 0 103 / 477
  • 104. Further extension of the stochastic integral Processes X ∈ H 2 [0, T ] do not necessarily have a finite T -norm → no approximation by simple processes as for processes in L2 [0, T ] can be localized with suitable sequences of stopping times Stopping times (with respect to {Ft }t ): t 2 τn (ω) := T ∧ inf 0 ≤ t ≤ T Xs (ω) ds ≥ n , n ∈ N 0 Sequence of stopped processes: (n) Xt (ω) := Xt (ω) · 1{τn (ω)≥t} ⇒ X (n) ∈ L2 [0, T ] ⇒ Stochastic integral already defined. 104 / 477
  • 105. Further extension of the stochastic integral Stochastic integral: It (X ) := It (X (n) ) for 0 ≤ t ≤ τn Consistence property: It (X ) = It (X (m) ) for 0 ≤ t ≤ τn (≤ τm ), m ≥ n ⇒ It (X ) well-defined for X ∈ H 2 [0, T ] 105 / 477
  • 106. Further extension of the stochastic integral Stopping times: n→∞ τn − − +∞ P-a.s. −→ ⇒ It (X ) local martingale with localizing sequence τn . ⇒ Stochastic integral is linear and possesses continuous paths. 106 / 477
  • 107. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 107 / 477
  • 108. ˆ The Ito formula General assumptions for this section Let (Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space equipped with a filtration {Ft }t satisfying the usual conditions. Further, assume that on this space a Brownian motion {(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) with respect to this filtration is defined. 108 / 477
  • 109. ˆ The Ito formula Definition Let {(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be an m-dimensional Brownian motion. ˆ (1) {(X (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) is a real-valued Ito process if for all t ≥ 0 it admits the representation t t X (t) = X (0) + K (s) ds + H(s) dW (s) 0 0 t m t = X (0) + K (s) ds + Hj (s) dWj (s) P-a.s. 0 j=1 0 109 / 477
  • 110. ˆ The Ito formula X (0) F0 -measurable, {K (t)}t∈[0,∞) , {H(t)}t∈[0,∞) progressively measurable with t t |K (s)| ds < ∞, Hi2 (s) ds < ∞ P-a.s. 0 0 for all t ≥ 0, i = 1, . . . , m. (2) n-dimensional Ito process X = (X (1) , . . . , X (n) ) ˆ ˆ = vector with components being real-valued Ito processes. 110 / 477
  • 111. ˆ The Ito formula Remark Hj ∈ H 2 [0, T ] for all T > 0. ˆ The representation of an Ito process is unique up to indistinguishability of the representing integrands Kt , Ht . Symbolic differential notation: dXt = Kt dt + Ht dWt 111 / 477
  • 112. ˆ The Ito formula Definition ˆ Let X and Y be two real-valued Ito processes with t t X (t) = X (0) + K (s) ds + H(s) dW (s), 0 0 t t Y (t) = Y (0) + L(s) ds + M(s) dW (s). 0 0 Quadratic covariation of X and Y : m t X,Y t := Hi (s) · Mi (s) ds. i=1 0 112 / 477
  • 113. ˆ The Ito formula Definition Quadratic variation of X X t := X , X t . Notation ˆ Let X be a real-valued Ito process, and Y a real-valued, progressively measurable process. We set t t t Y (s) dX (s) := Y (s) · K (s) ds + Y (s) · H(s) dW (s) 0 0 0 if all integrals on the right-hand side are defined. 113 / 477
  • 114. ˆ The Ito formula ˆ Theorem: One-dimensional Ito formula ˆ Let Wt be a one-dimensional Brownian motion, and Xt a real-valued Ito process with t t Xt = X0 + Ks ds + Hs dWs . 0 0 Let f ∈ C 2 (R). Then, for all t ≥ 0 we have t t ′ 1 f (Xt ) = f (X0 ) + f (Xs ) dXs + f ′′ (Xs ) d X s 2 0 0 t t 1 = f (X0 ) + f (Xs ) · Ks + · f ′′ (Xs ) · Hs ds + ′ 2 f ′ (Xs )Hs dWs 2 0 0 114 / 477
  • 115. ˆ The Ito formula Remark ˆ The Ito formula differs from the fundamental theorem of calculus by the additional term t 1 f ′′ (Xs ) d X s . 2 0 The quadratic variation X t ˆ is an Ito process. Differential notation: 1 ′′ df (Xt ) = f ′ (Xt ) dXt + · f (Xt ) d X t . 2 115 / 477
  • 116. ˆ The Ito formula Lemma Let X be a martingale with |Xs | ≤ C for all s ∈ [0, t] P-a.s. Let π = {t0 , t1 , . . . , tm }, t0 = 0, tm = t, be a partition of [0, t] with π := max |tk − tk −1 |. 1≤k ≤m Then we have m 2 2 (1) E Xtk − Xtk −1 ≤ 48 · C 4 k =1 m 4 π →0 (2) X continuous ⇒ E Xtk − Xtk −1 − − → 0. −− k =1 116 / 477
  • 117. ˆ Some applications of Ito s formula ′ ˆ Some applications of Ito s formula I (1) Xt = t : Representation: t t Xt = 0 + 1 ds + 0 dWs . 0 0 For f ∈ C 2 (R) we have t f (t) = f (0) + f ′ (s) ds. 0 ⇒ Fundamental theorem of calculus is a special case of Ito′ s formula. ˆ 117 / 477
  • 118. ˆ Some applications of Ito s formula II ˆ′ Some applications of Ito s formula (2) Xt = h(t) : For h ∈ C 1 (R) Ito′ s formula implies the chain rule ˆ t t ′ Xt = h(0) + h (s) ds + 0 dWs 0 0 t ⇒ (f ◦ h)(t) = (f ◦ h)(0) + f ′ (h(s)) · h′ (s) ds. 0 118 / 477
  • 119. ˆ Some applications of Ito s formula III ′ ˆ Some applications of Ito s formula (3) Xt = Wt , f (x) = x 2 : Due to t t Wt = 0 + 0 ds + 1 dWs 0 0 we obtain t t t 1 Wt2 = 2 · Ws dWs + · 2 ds = 2 · Ws dWs + t 2 0 0 0 ⇒ Additional term "t" (→ nonvanishing quadratic variation of Wt ). 119 / 477
  • 120. ˆ The Ito formula ˆ Theorem: Multi-dimensional Ito formula ˆ X (t) = X1 (t), . . . , Xn (t) n-dimensional Ito process with t m t Xi (t) = Xi (0) + Ki (s) ds + Hij (s) dWj (s), i = 1, . . . , n 0 j=1 0 where W (t) = W1 (t), . . . , Wm (t) is an m-dimensional Brownian motion. Let f : [0, ∞) × Rn → R be a C 1,2 -function. Then, we have f (t, X1 (t), . . . , Xn (t)) = f (0, X1 (0), . . . , Xn (0)) t n t + ft (s, X1 (s), . . . , Xn (s)) ds + fxi (s, X1 (s), . . . , Xn (s)) dXi (s) 0 i=1 0 n t 1 + · fxi xj (s, X1 (s), . . . , Xn (s)) d Xi , Xj s . 2 i,j=1 0 120 / 477
  • 121. Product rule or partial integration Corollary: Product rule or partial integration ˆ Let Xt , Yt be one-dimensional Ito processes with t t Xt = X0 + Ks ds + Hs dWs , 0 0 t t Yt = Y0 + µs ds + σs dWs . 0 0 Then we have t t t Xt · Yt = X0 · Y0 + Xs dYs + Ys dXs + d X,Y s 0 0 0 t t = X0 · Y0 + Xs µs + Ys Ks + Hs σs ds + Xs σs + Ys Hs dWs . 0 0 121 / 477
  • 122. The stock price equation Simple continuous-time market model (1 bond, one stock). Stock price influenced by a one-dimensional Brownian motion Price of the stock at time t: P(t) = p · exp b − 1 σ 2 t + σWt 2 Choose t t 1 2 Xt = 0 + b− 2σ ds + σ dWs , f (x) = p · ex 0 0 ˆ Ito formula implies t t 1 2 1 2 f (Xt ) = p + f (Xs )(b − 2 σ ) + 2 f (Xs ) ·σ ds + f (Xs ) · σ dWs 0 0 122 / 477
  • 123. The stock price equation The stock price equation t t P(t) = p + P(s) · b ds + P(s) · σ dWs 0 0 Remark The stock price equation is valid for time-dependent b and σ, if t t 1 2 Xt = b(s) − 2 σ (s) ds + σ(s) dWs . 0 0 123 / 477
  • 124. The stock price equation The stock price equation in differential form dP(t) = P(t) b dt + σ dWt P(0) = p 124 / 477
  • 125. The stock price equation Theorem: Variation of constants Let {(W (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) be an m-dimensional Brownian motion. Let x ∈ R and A, a, Sj , σj be progressively measurable, real-valued processes with t |A(s)| + |a(s)| ds < ∞ for all t ≥ 0 P-a.s. 0 t Sj2 (s) + σj2 (s) ds < ∞ for all t ≥ 0 P-a.s. . 0 125 / 477
  • 126. The stock price equation Theorem: Variation of constants Then the stochastic differential equation m dX (t) = A(t) · X (t) + a(t) dt + Sj (t)X (t) + σj (t) dWj (t) j=1 X (0) = x possesses a unique solution with respect to λ ⊗ P : t m 1 X (t) = Z (t) · x + a(u) − Sj (u)σj (u) du Z (u) 0 j=1 m t σj (u) + dWj (u) Z (u) j=1 0 126 / 477
  • 127. The stock price equation Theorem: Variation of constants Hereby is t t 1 2 Z (t) = exp A(u) − 2 · S(u) du + S(u) dW (u) 0 0 the unique solution of the homogeneous equation dZ (t) = Z (t) A(t) dt + S(t)T dW (t) Z (0) = 1. 127 / 477
  • 128. The stock price equation Remark The process {(X (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) solves the stochastic differential equation in the sense that X (t) satisfies t X (t) = x + A(s) · X (s) + a(s) ds 0 m t + Sj (s) X (s) + σj (s) dWj (s) j=1 0 for all t ≥ 0 P-almost surely. 128 / 477
  • 129. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 129 / 477
  • 130. General assumptions General assumptions for this section (Ω, F, P) be a complete probability space, {(W (t), Ft )}t∈[0,∞) m-dimensional Brownian motion. Dynamics of bond and stock prices: t P0 (t) = p0 · exp r (s) ds bond 0 t m 1 2 Pi (t) = pi · exp bi (s) − σij (s) ds 2 0 j=1 m t + σij (s) dWj (s) stock j=1 0 for t ∈ [0, T ], T > 0, i = 1, . . . , d . 130 / 477
  • 131. General assumptions (continued) General assumptions for this section (continued) r (t), b(t) = (b1 (t), . . . , bd (t))T , σ(t) = (σij (t))ij progressively measurable processes with respect to {Ft }t , component-wise uniformly bounded in (t, ω). σ(t)σ(t)T uniformly positive definite, i.e., it exists K > 0 with x T σ(t)σ(t)T x ≥ Kx T x for all x ∈ Rd and all t ∈ [0, T ] P-a.s. Deterministic rate of return r (t) is not required r (t) can be a stochastic process ⇒ bond is no longer riskless. 131 / 477
  • 132. Bond and stock prices Bond and stock prices are unique solutions of the stochastic differential equations dP0 (t) = P0 (t) · r (t) dt bond P0 (t) = p0 m dPi (t) = Pi (t) bi (t) dt + σij (t) dWj (t) , i = 1, . . . , d j=1 Pi (0) = pi stock ˆ ⇒ Representations of prices as Ito processes 132 / 477
  • 133. Possible actions of investors (1) Investor can rebalance his holdings → sell some securities → invest in securities ⇒ Portfolio process / trading strategy. (2) Investor is allowed to consume parts of his wealth ⇒ Consumption process. 133 / 477
  • 134. Requirements on a market model (1) Investor should not be able to foresee events → no knowledge of future prices. (2) Actions of a single investor have no impact on the stock prices (small investor hypothesis). (3) Each investor has a fixed initial capital at time t = 0. (4) Money which is not invested into stocks has to be invested in bonds. (5) Investors act in a self-financing way (no secret source or sink for money). 134 / 477
  • 135. Requirements on a market model (6) Securities are perfectly divisible. (7) Negative positions in securities are possible bond → credit stock → we sold some stock short. (8) No transaction costs. 135 / 477
  • 136. Negative bond positions and credit interest rates Negative bond positions and credit interest rates Assume: Interest rate r (t) is constant Negative bond position = it is possible to borrow money for the same rate as we would get for investing in bonds. Interest depends on the market situation ((t, ω) ∈ [0, T ] × Ω), but not on positive or negative bond position. 136 / 477
  • 137. Mathematical realizations of some requirements Market with 1 bond and d stocks Time t = 0: – Initial capital of investor: x > 0 – Buy a selection of securities T ϕ(0) = ϕ0 (0), ϕ1 (0), . . . , ϕd (0) Time t > 0: – Trading strategy: ϕ(t) (1) ⇒ trading strategy is progressively measurable with respect to {Ft }t Decisions on buying and selling are made on basis of information available at time t (→ modelled by {Ft }t ) (5) ⇒ only self-financing trading strategies should be used. 137 / 477
  • 138. Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy Market with 1 riskless bond and 1 stock Two-period model for time points t = 0, 1, 2. Number of shares of bond and stock at time t: (ϕ0 (t), ϕ1 (t))T ∈ R2 Consumption of investor at time t: C(t) Wealth at time t: X (t) Bond/stock prices at time t: P0 (t), P1 (t) Initial conditions: C(0) = 0, X (0) = x 138 / 477
  • 139. Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy t =0 Investor uses initial capital to buy shares of bond and stock X (0) = x = ϕ0 (0) · P0 (0) + ϕ1 (0) · P1 (0). 139 / 477
  • 140. Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy t =1 Security prices have changed, investor consumes parts of his wealth Current wealth: X (1) = ϕ0 (0) · P0 (1) + ϕ1 (0) · P1 (1) − C(1). Total: X (1) = x + ϕ0 (0) · P0 (1) − P0 (0) + ϕ1 (0) · P1 (1) − P1 (0) − C(1) Wealth = initial wealth + gains/losses - consumption Invest remaining capital at the market: X (1) = ϕ0 (1) · P0 (1) + ϕ1 (1) · P1 (1). 140 / 477
  • 141. Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy t =2 Invest remaining capital at the market Wealth: X (2) = ϕ0 (2) · P0 (2) + ϕ1 (2) · P1 (2). Wealth = total wealth of shares held Total: 2 X (2) = x + ϕ0 (i − 1) · (P0 (i) − P0 (i − 1)) i=1 +ϕ1 (i − 1) · (P1 (i) − P1 (i − 1)) 2 − C(i). i=1 141 / 477
  • 142. Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy Self-financing trading strategy: wealth before rebalancing - consumption = wealth after rebalancing Condition: ϕ0 (i) · P0 (i) + ϕ1 (i) · P1 (i) = ϕ0 (i − 1) · P0 (i) + ϕ1 (i − 1) · P1 (i) − C(i) ⇒ Useless in continuous-time setting (securities can be traded at each time instant / "before" and "after" cannot be distinguished) 142 / 477
  • 143. Discrete-time example: self-financing strategy Continuous-time setting Wealth process corresponding to strategy ϕ(t): t t t X (t) = x + ϕ0 (s) dP0 (s) + ϕ1 (s) dP1 (s) − c(s) ds 0 0 0 ˆ ⇒ Price processes are Ito processes. 143 / 477
  • 144. Trading strategy and wealth processes Definition (1) A trading strategy ϕ with T ϕ(t) := ϕ0 (t), ϕ1 (t), . . . , ϕd (t) is an Rd+1 -valued progressively measurable process with respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] satisfying T |ϕ0 (t)| dt < ∞ P-a.s. 0 d T 2 ϕi (t) · Pi (t) dt < ∞ P-a.s. for i = 1, . . . , d . j=1 0 144 / 477
  • 145. Trading strategy and wealth processes Definition The value d x := ϕi (0) · pi i=0 is called initial value of ϕ. (2) Let ϕ be a trading strategy with initial value x > 0. The process d X (t) := ϕi (t)Pi (t) i=0 is called wealth process corresponding to ϕ with initial wealth x. 145 / 477
  • 146. Trading strategy and wealth processes Definition (3) A non-negative progressively measurable process c(t) with respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] with T c(t) dt < ∞ P-a.s. 0 is called consumption (rate) process. 146 / 477
  • 147. Trading strategy and wealth processes Definition A pair (ϕ, c) consisting of a trading strategy ϕ and a consumption rate process c is called self-financing if the corresponding wealth process X (t) satisfies d t t X (t) = x + ϕi (s) dPi (s) − c(s) ds P-a.s. i=0 0 0 current wealth = initial wealth + gains/losses - consumption 147 / 477
  • 148. Trading strategy and wealth processes Remark We have t t ϕ0 (s) dP0 (s) = ϕ0 (s) P0 (s) r (s) ds 0 0 t t ϕi (s) dPi (s) = ϕi (s) Pi (s) bi (s) ds 0 0 m t + ϕi (s) Pi (s) σij (s) dWj (s), i = 1, . . . , d . j=1 0 148 / 477
  • 149. Self-financing portfolio process Definition Let (ϕ, c) be a self-financing pair consisting of a trading strategy and a consumption process with corresponding wealth process X (t) > 0 P-a.s. for all t ∈ [0, T ]. Then the Rd -valued process T ϕi (t) · Pi (t) π(t) = π1 (t), . . . , πd (t) with πi (t) = X (t) is called a self-financing portfolio process corresponding to the pair (ϕ, c). 149 / 477
  • 150. Portfolio processes Remark (1) The portfolio process denotes the fractions of total wealth invested in the different stocks. (2) The fraction of wealth invested in the bond is given by ϕ0 (t) · P0 (t) 1 − π(t)T 1 = , where 1 := (1, . . . , 1)T ∈ Rd . X (t) (3) Given knowledge of wealth X (t) and prices Pi (t), it is possible for an investor to describe his activities via a self-financing pair (π, c). → Portfolio process and trading strategy are equivalent descriptions of the same action. 150 / 477
  • 151. The wealth equation The wealth equation dX (t) = [r (t) X (t) − c(t)] dt + X (t) π(t)T (b(t) − r (t) 1) dt + σ(t) dW (t) X (0) = x 151 / 477
  • 152. Alternative definition of a portfolio process Definition The progressively measurable Rd -valued process π(t) is called a self-financing portfolio process corresponding to the consumption process c(t) if the corresponding wealth equation possesses a unique solution X (t) = X π,c (t) with T 2 X (t) · πi (t) dt < ∞ P-a.s. for i = 1, . . . , d . 0 152 / 477
  • 153. Admissibility Definition A self-financing pair (ϕ, c) or (π, c) consisting of a trading strategy ϕ or a portfolio process π and a consumption process c will be called admissible for the initial wealth x > 0, if the corresponding wealth process satisfies X (t) ≥ 0 P-a.s. for all t ∈ [0, T ]. The set of admissible pairs will be denoted by A(x). 153 / 477
  • 154. An example Portfolio process: π(t) ≡ π ∈ Rd constant Consumption rate: c(t) = γ · X (t), γ > 0 Wealth process corresponding to (π, c) : X (t) Investor rebalances his holdings in such a way that the fractions of wealth invested in the different stocks and in the bond remain constant over time. Consumption rate is proportional to the current wealth of the investor. 154 / 477
  • 155. An example Wealth equation: dX (t) = [r (t) − γ] X (t) dt + X (t)π T (b(t) − r (t) 1) dt + σ(t) dW (t) X (0) = 0 Wealth process: t 1 T X (t) = x · exp r (s) − γ + π T b(s) − r (s) · 1 − π σ(s) 2 ds 2 0 t + π T σ(s) dW (s) 0 155 / 477
  • 156. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 156 / 477
  • 157. Properties of the continuous-time market model Assumptions: Dimension of the underlying Brownian motion = number of stocks Past and present prices are the only sources of information for the investors ⇒ Choose Brownian filtration {Ft }t∈[0,T ] Aim: Final wealths X (T ) when starting with initial capital of x. 157 / 477
  • 158. General assumption / notation General assumption for this section d =m Notation t γ(t) := exp − r (s) ds 0 θ(t) := σ −1 (t) b(t) − r (t) 1 t t T 1 2 Z (t) := exp − θ(s) dW (s) − θ(s) ds 2 0 0 H(t) := γ(t) · Z (t) 158 / 477
  • 159. Properties of the continuous-time market model b, r uniformly bounded σσ T uniformly positive definite ⇒ θ(t) 2 uniformly bounded Interpretation of θ(t): Relative risk premium for stock investment. Process H(t) is important for option pricing. H(t) is positive, continuous, and progressively measurable with respect to {Ft }t∈[0,T ] . H(t) is the unique solution of the SDE dH(t) = −H(t) r (t) dt + θ(t)T dW (t) H(0) = 1. 159 / 477
  • 160. Completeness of the market Theorem: Completeness of the market (1) Let the self-financing pair (π, c) consisting of a portfolio process π and a consumption process c be admissible for an initial wealth of x ≥ 0, i.e., (π, c) ∈ A(x). Then the corresponding wealth process X (t) satisfies t E H(t) X (t) + H(s)c(s) ds ≤ x for all t ∈ [0, T ]. 0 160 / 477
  • 161. Completeness of the market Theorem: Completeness of the market (2) Let B ≥ 0 be an FT -measurable random variable and c(t) a consumption process satisfying T x := E H(T ) B + H(s)c(s) ds < ∞. 0 Then there exists a portfolio process π(t) with (π, c) ∈ A(x) and the corresponding wealth process X (t) satisfies X (T ) = B P-a.s. 161 / 477
  • 162. Completeness of the market H(t) can be regarded as the appropriate discounting process that determines the initial wealth at time t = 0 T E H(s) · c(s) ds + E (H(T ) · B) 0 which is necessary to attain future aims. (1) puts bounds on the desires of an investor given his initial capital x ≥ 0. (2) proves that future aims which are feasible in the sense of part (1) can be realized. (2) says that each desired final wealth in t = T can be attained exactly via trading according to an appropriate self-financing pair (π, c) if one possesses sufficient initial capital (completeness/complete model). 162 / 477
  • 163. Completeness of the market Remark 1/H(t) is the wealth process corresponding to the pair π(t), c(t) = σ −1 (t)T θ(t), 0 with initial wealth x := 1/H(0) = 1 and final wealth B:= 1/H(T ). 163 / 477
  • 164. Outline 2 The Continuous-Time Market Model Modeling the Security Prices Excursion 1: Brownian Motion and Martingales Continuation: Modeling the Security prices ˆ Excursion 2: The Ito Integral ˆ Excursion 3: The Ito Formula Trading Strategy and Wealth Process Properties of the Continuous-Time Market Model Excursion 4: The Martingale Representation Theorem 164 / 477
  • 165. Excursion 4: The martingale representation theorem General assumptions (Ω, F, P) complete probability space. {(Wt , Ft )}t∈[0,∞) m-dimensional Brownian motion. {Ft }t Brownian filtration. Definition A real-valued martingale {(Mt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] with respect to the Brownian filtration {Ft }t is called a Brownian martingale. 165 / 477
  • 166. The martingale representation theorem Martingale representation theorem Let {(Mt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] be a square-integrable Brownian martingale, i.e., EMt2 < ∞ for all t ∈ [0, T ]. Then there exists a progressively measurable Rm -valued process Ψ(t) with T 2 E Ψ(t) dt <∞ 0 and t Mt = M0 + Ψ(s)T dW (s) P-a.s. . 0 166 / 477
  • 167. The martingale representation theorem Corollary Let {(Mt , Ft )}t∈[0,T ] be a local martingale with respect to the Brownian filtration {Ft }t . Then there exists a progressively measurable Rm -valued process Ψ(t) with T 2 Ψ(t) dt < ∞ 0 and t Mt = M0 + Ψ(s)T dW (s) P-a.s. 0 167 / 477
  • 168. The martingale representation theorem Remark Each local martingale with respect to the Brownian filtration can ˆ be represented as an Ito process. ˆ Each Brownian martingale can be represented as an Ito process. ⇒ Quadratic variation and quadratic covariation are defined. 168 / 477
  • 169. Outline 3 Option Pricing 169 / 477
  • 170. Outline 3 Option Pricing Introduction Examples The Replication Principle Arbitrage Opportunity Continuation Partial Differential Approach (PDA) Arbitrage & Option Pricing 170 / 477