SlideShare ist ein Scribd-Unternehmen logo
1 von 12
Downloaden Sie, um offline zu lesen
REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES:
AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE
Randy I. Anderson
University of Central Florida Orlando and EBS Business School
Henrik Medla
EBS Business School
Nico B. Rottke
EBS Business School and University of Central Florida Orlando
Dirk Schiereck
Tech University Darmstadt and EBS Business School



Abstract
This paper examines the dominant theories, motives, methodologies, and results of
the existing literature on the rationale for real estate related mergers. The literature
review draws on the mainstream corporate governance literature in finance as its base
and highlights the differences in motives between real estate and non-real estate
related merger activity. The studies highlight that the homogeneity of real estate firms,
especially as they pertain to the highly regulated real estate investment trust (REIT)
industry, is expected to reduce the availability of revenue and overall corporate
synergies, but might allow for the ability of some firms to more readily be able to
take advantage of scale efficiencies. In addition to summarizing past studies, the
review concludes with a discussion of the need for continued research in this evolving
literature.


In the finance literature, there exists a plethora of studies that examine both
theoretically and empirically the issues surrounding mergers and acquisitions (M&A).1
The traditional approach has been to examine, utilizing event study methodology, the
wealth implications for the bidder and target firms. The same approach has also been
predominantly applied on real estate related M&A studies. Womack (2012) is the first
to determine the combined firm returns for a sample spanning nearly three decades
of real estate mergers. Prior real estate merger studies analyzed bidder and/or target
returns but did not evaluate the combined wealth effects. Target returns were
consistently found to be positive but relatively small compared to those evidenced in
studies outside the real estate industry. Results concerning bidder returns are less
conclusive and vary greatly depending on the analyzed time frame [i.e., before or
after the Tax Reform Act of 1986 and/or the Real Estate Investment Trust (REIT)
Modernization Act of 1999], as well as on the types of firms (i.e., REITs vs. all real
estate firms, equity REITs vs. all REITs, public targets vs. private and public targets,
etc.) studied in the individual sample of the studies. Most studies, however, show
slightly negative returns to bidding firms around the merger announcement, at least
for mergers with public targets.2
However, as depicted in Ling and Petrova (2011) and Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and
Schiereck (2011), there are very few studies that assess ‘‘why’’ mergers in the real

                                              37
38   JOURNAL   OF   REAL ESTATE LITERATURE

estate industry (or really any other market for that matter) occur. And, perhaps just
as important, the current literature is largely inconclusive or at best inconsistent across
studies and sectors, leaving many unanswered questions. The majority of studies
attempting to determine the rationale behind mergers in the real estate industry mainly
draw on findings from studies analyzing merger motives outside the real estate
industry. More recently, a number of studies build on the observation that hostile
takeovers among real estate firms are extremely rare and use this as the motivation
to exam why mergers then occur. The findings that hostile takeovers among real estate
firms are extremely rare, as well as the many other peculiarities of the real estate
market, cast doubt on the assumption that the reasons for takeovers in the real estate
industry are basically the same as for those outside the industry.
Moreover, the role of synergies as a motive for mergers and acquisitions in the real
estate industry and especially for REIT mergers is a particularly controversial question
among academics and practitioners, even though the size-related benefits in REITs
are well documented in the literature.3 The common skepticism concerning the
relevance and existence of synergies can mainly be ascribed to the observation that
several studies measuring abnormal returns for bidding and target firms in real estate
mergers document wealth effects of materially lower magnitude than those detected
in studies for other sectors. The lower magnitude of returns is thereby regularly
explained by the limited potential for synergistic gains from real estate mergers.
Eichholtz and Kok (2008), for example, argue that the homogeneity of assets of real
estate companies decreases the potential for synergistic profits emerging from merged
operations. They also reason that the homogeneity of operations in real estate mergers
does not allow for large value-creating synergies. Campbell, Ghosh, and Sirmans
(2001) suggest that the required uniformity of REIT asset composition largely
eliminates the potential for vertical integration synergies through mergers. In a recent
study, Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and Schiereck (2011) show that the expected
magnitude of total synergies for REIT mergers is lower than those found in other
sectors. They, however, also find that for the same homogeneity reasons, REITs are
able to find greater synergies than non-REIT firms on the operating cost side and, as
such, can take considerable advantage of economies of scale. The results of their
study therefore challenge the notion that synergies do not play a major role as a
motive for REIT mergers.
This paper provides a detailed review of the literature beginning with the theoretical
background that motivates mergers, followed by a detailed discussion of the real estate
focused studies. Studies that merely analyze wealth effects in real estate mergers are
not covered here and the authors do not attempt to determine the rationale behind
those takeovers, as those effects are already sufficiently documented in a recent study
by Womack (2012). The paper concludes with a brief summary and discussion of the
need for additional research in this emerging literature.
The main findings suggest that it is first and foremost important to study real estate
mergers separately and distinctly from non-real estate related firms. This is even more
relevant when dealing with publically traded REITs that have very specific regulatory
guidelines. These guidelines tend to homogenize REITs making synergistic gains from



VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW        OF THE   LITERATURE   39

mergers more difficult, while at the same time providing opportunities for readily
available greater gains from economies of scale in operating costs.

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND                OF   MERGER MOTIVES
The motives for takeovers can be numerous and true verification is often ambiguous
and/or impossible to fully ascertain. A reasonable and compelling differentiation
between the diverse merger motives is to distinguish between neoclassical theories on
the one hand and agency and behavioral theories on the other (Bernile and Bauguess,
2010). According to neoclassical theories, mergers occur mainly as a result of external
shocks, either in the form of economic, technological, financial, regulatory, or political
shocks (Harford, 1999, 2005) and are made to sustain or create competitive advantages
(Jensen, 1988). Mergers under the neoclassical perspective are mostly motivated by
such shocks and are expected to lead to profit optimization and shareholder value
creation, assuming managers are aligned with shareholders’ interests (Martynova and
Renneboog, 2008). Following this logic, merged firms should be able to operate more
efficiently than the individual standalone entities through the realization of synergies.
In contrast, agency and behavioral theories allow for the possibility that takeovers are
value-destroying transactions. Inherent agency conflicts between firms’ insiders and
investors or biases affecting managers are thereby credited as motives to engage in
M&A transactions (Jensen, 1986; Roll, 1986; Shleifer and Vishny, 1991; Berkovitch
and Naryanan, 1993). According to those theories, managers may seek to build an
empire through vast acquisitions while shareholders want the management to increase
the value of the firm. According to Mueller (1969), management salaries, bonuses,
stock options, and promotions tend to be more associated with corporate size than to
the firm’s profitability. Likewise, the power and prestige of managers are more
associated with the growth and size of the firm than to its profitability. Jensen (1986)
also found that managers have an incentive to grow firms beyond their optimal size
since their compensation is positively related to sales growth. Roll (1986) reasons that
managerial hubris makes overconfident managers overestimate the creation of
synergetic value, thereby tempting them to engage in value-destroying mergers.
Another recently popular theory is market timing, whereby insiders attempt to exploit
temporary market ‘‘misvaluations’’ (Rhodes-Kropf, Robinson, and Viswanathan, 2005;
Dong, Hirshleifer, Richardson, and Teoh, 2006). The theory is based on Myers and
Majluf (1984), who argue that managers take advantage of temporarily overvalued
equity as cheap currency for acquiring real assets.
Prior research reveals that none of those theories are mutually exclusive; meaning
those firms and their insiders may simultaneously have more than one motive when
engaging in takeovers (Berkovitch and Narayanan, 1993). The empirical evidence also
indicates that no single theory can fully explain the occurrence of M&A activity and
the pattern of takeover waves. Martynova and Renneboog (2008) show in a
comprehensive literature review on corporate takeovers of the last century that the
most consistent finding regarding the reasons for takeovers is that they are motivated
differently depending on the stage of the merger wave they are executed in, and that
40   JOURNAL   OF   REAL ESTATE LITERATURE

wealth effects also vary depending on whether they take place in the earlier or later
part of a wave. The combined companies are thereby expected to create synergistic
gains when the merger occurs in the first half of a takeover wave. In contrast, the
majority of value-destroying acquisitions take place in the second half of a wave.
The same theories discussed above are commonly used to explain the occurrence of
M&As among real estate firms. The real estate industry, however, exhibits unique
aspects that cast doubt on whether this approach is reasonable and should be accepted
without in-depth validation. The most relevant difference to other industries is the
dominance of REITs in the real estate market.4 Those firms avoid the double taxation
of typical corporations in exchange for meeting a strict list of ownership, asset,
income, and dividend payout requirements.5 The strict rules REITs have to comply
with in order to obtain and subsequently maintain their status should have an impact
on the relevancy of the individual theories explaining takeover activity in the real
estate industry.
In this context, Allen and Sirmans (1987) propose that some classic corporate merger
motives can be precluded for REITs due to their unique structure and their institutional
environment. As an example, they point out that ‘‘it is unlikely that a business
combination of REITs would create any monopolistic power’’ (p. 177), because the
vast majority of REIT income must come from passive sources such as rents and
mortgages. Moreover, other peculiarities of the real estate market, such as the
coexistence of a large private market that competes directly against firms for the
ownership of real estate assets, are also expected to have various implications. The
fact that hostile takeovers among real estate firms are extremely rare also casts doubt
on the assumption that the reasons for takeovers in the real estate industry are basically
the same than for those outside the industry and that the market for corporate control
works in essentially the same way (Eichholtz and Kok, 2008; Womack, 2012).

LITERATURE REVIEW             OF   REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVE STUDIES
The latest relevant research on real estate mergers mainly builds on the almost entire
absence of hostile takeovers among real estate firms.6 In this context, Womack (2012,
p. 2) raises these questions: ‘‘Does the above [i.e., the fact that hostile takeovers
among real estate firms are extremely rare] imply that management of
underperforming firms are not held accountable for their results? If not, then why do
real estate mergers occur?’’ In order to investigate why real estate mergers occur, he
tests for three merger motives: the empire building hypothesis, the over-valued
information signal hypothesis, and the inefficient management hypothesis. His results
indicate that the motivation for real estate mergers is consistent with the inefficient
management hypothesis. According to this hypothesis, firms with superior
management acquire other firms that possess unexploited opportunities to cut costs
and increase earnings. The study, however, only tests for three popular merger motives
without taking into account other important potential motivations. The methodology
used to test for the motives based solely on abnormal returns around the takeover
announcement only allows for an analysis on the meta level without gaining detailed
insights into the expected sources underlying real estate merger gains.


VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW        OF THE   LITERATURE   41

Womack’s (2012, p. 2) approach builds on the assumption that ‘‘because each merger
theory generates a testable hypothesis about the stock market’s response to the news
of a merger announcement, the returns for each of these firms collectively can be
utilized to test which theory is best supported by the data.’’ Following his argument,
takeovers under the inefficient management hypothesis would generally be wealth-
creating events. The hypothesis predicts the following abnormal returns: target
(positive), bidder (non-negative), and combined firm (non-negative). The applied
experimental design does not allow for controlling whether the inefficient management
hypothesis is really the dominant theory that predicts this kind of announcement
effect. The synergy hypothesis stating that merged firms should be able to operate
more efficiently than individual standalone entities by cutting redundant costs and
additionally increasing earnings, for example, should lead to a similar capital market
reaction. The inference of motivations underlying mergers based exclusively on the
returns around the deal announcement does not enable consideration of the fact that
there may be other theories that predict the same, or at least a very similar return
pattern.7 Some of the other findings that are used to support the inefficient
management hypothesis may be driven by alternative explanations. Womack’s results,
for example, indicate that bidders typically do not seek geographical diversification.
He ascribes this finding to the fact that effective managerial focus is more difficult
when properties are widely spread apart. However, this result could be alternatively
associated with bidders’ aims to generate material cost synergies, which is more likely
to be accomplished in focused mergers where the bidder is located in the same state
as the target and the potential for cutting redundant costs is consequently higher.
Allen and Sirmans (1987) mention tax motivations (i.e., the purchase of operating
losses to offset the acquiring REIT’s capital gains) and the opportunity to replace
inefficient management as potential motives for REIT mergers. Only six out of the
31 events in their study with complete information involves one or the other trust
having experienced an operating loss in a previous period. A differential means test
between the two subsamples does also not reveal any significant differences. They
conclude that on the basis of these observations, tax motivations alone are not
important motives in REIT combinations. However, they find that related mergers
(i.e., bidder and target are both equity/mortgage REITs and/or have the same property
focus or geographic focus) yield statistically significant higher abnormal returns
around the announcement than unrelated combinations. They paraphrase this finding
as evidence for the inefficient management hypothesis. An alternative explanation
would yet be that synergies are likely to be higher for related business combinations.
Elayan and Young (1994) extend Allen and Sirmans’ (1987) examination of the
sources of gains to target shareholders. They note that ‘‘in addition to improved asset
management through a change in control, anticipated operational and financial
synergies may contribute to gains associated with a business combination’’ (p. 169).
In order to partition the gains from these two sources, they examine the wealth effects
of both the targets and bidders when controlling (i.e., acquisitions that result in the
bidder’s control of over 50% of the target’s outstanding shares) and noncontrolling
interests are sought. Their hypothesis builds on the assumption that while a gain based
on synergies could be associated with either form of combination, a gain from a
42   JOURNAL   OF   REAL ESTATE LITERATURE

change in control would exclusively be associated with an acquisition of a controlling
interest. Their results show that the significant positive abnormal returns that accrue
to target shareholders in both cases are significantly larger when a controlling interest
is sought and infer that this is consistent with the realization of greater efficiency
associated with a change in control (i.e., evidence for the inefficient management
hypothesis).
The authors bring a new approach into play and their findings reveal interesting
results. However, the underlying assumption in the study is that synergies can be
(fully) realized in cases only when partial control is obtained in an acquisition is
critical. Savings in many expense categories can only be realized if the two combining
firms are in fact fully integrated. Savings in duplicative public company expenses,
which can be expected to be substantial for the relatively small firms in Elayan and
Young’s (1994) sample period from 1972 to 1987, can for example only be realized
if both companies are fully integrated. Bradley, Desai, and Kim (1993), for example,
use a threshold of 70% as a prerequisite for the generation of potential synergies in
their study examining synergies across multiple industries. They base their selection
of the 70% threshold on the fact that some corporate charters require a two-thirds or
higher majority to effect a formal combination of two firms.
Campbell, Gosh, and Sirmans (1998) infer, based on their finding of negative
announcement returns of acquiring equity REITs, that hubris or self-dealing may be
the rationale behind those mergers. They base this assessment purely on the observed
wealth effect and do not further elaborate on their interpretation.
Eichholtz and Kok (2008) supplement the existing studies by investigating 95
takeovers of property companies all over the world. Especially worth remarking is
that they thereby measure bidder and target performance prior to the takeover
announcement, which had not been done for real estate mergers before. To determine
the effectiveness of the market for corporate control, they study the characteristics of
targets and bidders compared to a control sample using a multinomial logistic
approach. They find that targets are mainly financially underperforming, small target
companies have a low market-to-book value, and that weak operating and stock
performance of real estate companies are positively related to the likelihood of a
takeover. The authors interpret this evidence as in line with the inefficient management
hypothesis. Moreover, they compare their results between REIT takeovers and non-
REIT takeovers, which are mainly takeovers involving non-U.S. entities, and find that
targets in non-REIT mergers have a significantly negative coefficient for market-to-
book value, whereas this result does not hold for REITs. Based on this finding for
the subsample of REITs, one can see that the overall obtained results may not be
representative for REIT M&A deals in general.
Another notable exception to the wealth effect based merger motive studies is a recent
paper by Ling and Petrova (2011). The authors identify the characteristics of publicly-
traded REITs associated with an increased probability of being the target of an
announced takeover. They also examine whether certain target characteristics influence
the probability of a bidder being a private versus a public firm. They find that REITs
that are more likely to become acquisition targets relative to the rest of public REITs


VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW        OF THE   LITERATURE   43

are generally smaller and more cash restricted with relatively high dividend yields
and institutional ownership and no umbrella operating partnership. The differences
between the target firms in public-to-public versus going private acquisitions are also
documented. More precisely, the authors deliver evidence that the targets of private
acquirers have lower leverage, interest coverage ratios, and profitability, but higher
dividend yields. Their results therefore provide evidence for different motivations for
private versus public acquirers. Private bidders tend to focus on profit maximization
and hence are bidding on cash restricted, underlevered, and underperforming target
REITs. Public bidders are eager to increase market power and are therefore more
focused on acquiring profitable and higher levered REITs with higher dividend yields.
Their finding that in the case of acquisitions by private firms, but not by public firms,
targets are typically underperforming with low leverage, deliver important insights
into the merger motives of public real estate acquirers and shows that the inefficient
management hypothesis does not seem to hold unrestrictedly for staying public
mergers.
Most of the recent studies by now focus on the inefficient management hypothesis to
explain takeovers in the real estate industry, thereby mostly neglecting the neoclassical
view that mergers indeed have the potential to create incremental value through the
realization of synergies even in absence of inefficient management of targets. At the
bottom line, a precise separation between gains from synergies on the one hand and
from those from the replacement of inefficient management on the other does not
seem to be always possible. Whether gains simply stem from cutting previously above-
average expenses at the target level or real incremental gains (i.e., synergies) are in
fact generated by the combination of two previously independent entities cannot
always be evaluated from an outsider’s perspective. Even in those mergers where the
management of the bidding firm explicitly forecasts the synergies expected from the
merger, the management could, for example, include cost savings in their forecasts
that also would have been realized without a merger, thereby inflating merger-related
synergistic gains.8 Both sources of merger gains, however, on balance lead to more
efficient operations of the combined entities. The potential complications with
differentiating between the gains from the two sources should therefore not lead to
serious concerns as they both have very similar effects on the performance of the
newly combined firms. From an academic perspective, a precise separation is
nevertheless of interest, since the findings can have important implications for
academics, as well as for practitioners engaged in the field of real estate M&A.
Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and Schiereck (2011) attempt to distinguish between the
gains from the two different sources whenever the data and applied methodology
allow. The authors provide some insights into why REIT mergers occur by analyzing
hand-collected synergy forecasts provided by merging firms’ insiders for a sample of
merger announcements where the bidder is a publically-traded REIT in the U.S. The
neoclassical view that characterizes mergers as firms’ rational, efficiency-enhancing
reaction to a changing environment is thereby a priori accepted as the dominant theory.
The approach to focus on synergies as a merger motive has the advantage that
evidence for, but also against synergies as motive can be interpreted twofold. This
means that if there is no evidence for potential synergies in the takeover, other motives
44   JOURNAL   OF   REAL ESTATE LITERATURE

must have been the decision criterion. They hypothesize that expected synergies are
in fact an important merger motive for REITs and therefore expect that synergies are
quoted and quantified more often in REIT mergers than in mergers in the rest of the
corporate world. Their finding that management forecasts of synergies are publicly
available in 35% of the REIT mergers in their sample and therefore for a materially
higher proportion of deals than evidenced in other studies analyzing synergy forecasts
in samples across multiple industries supports their contention. However, the available
sample size is quite small and thus limits the robustness of the findings.
Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and Schiereck (2011) also investigate the determinants of
insiders’ forecasts of synergies and thereby attempt to explain the variation in the
estimated present value of synergies using the variables that are predicted to influence
those values. The results of their cross-sectional analyses using OLS regressions show
that the factors suggested by the literature to proxy for the potential existence of
synergies explain a considerable share of the variation in the estimated present value
of synergies. Managerial synergy forecasts in REIT mergers therefore seem to be
economically significant and profound. The results are consistent with more general
findings on economies of scale in REITs, demonstrating that general and
administrative (G&A) expenses and to a lesser extent also interest expenses are the
most relevant sources for cost savings. The results of the study also provide additional
insights into the synergy motivation; however, the experimental design is not set-up
to allow for a comprehensive controlling for the potential existence of alternative
theories. The potential (co-)existence of agency and/or behavioral theory based
motivations consequently cannot be assessed.


CONCLUSION

This paper reviews the dominant theories, motives, methodologies, and results of the
existing literature on the rationale for real estate related mergers. The theoretical
background that motivates mergers is presented and neoclassical theories and
behavioral theories thereby discussed, followed by a detailed discussion of the real
estate focused studies. The literature review thereby draws on the mainstream
corporate governance literature in finance as its base and highlights the differences in
motives between real estate and non-real estate related merger activity. The findings
show that the existing literature is largely inconclusive, leaving many unanswered
questions. The majority of studies attempting to determine the rationale behind
mergers in the real estate industry mainly draw on findings from studies analyzing
merger motives outside the real estate industry. More recently, a number of studies
build on the observation that hostile takeovers among real estate firms are extremely
rare and therefore focus on the inefficient management hypothesis to explain takeovers
in the real estate industry. The focus on the inefficient management hypothesis to
explain takeovers in the real estate industry, however, neglects the neoclassical view
that mergers indeed have the potential to create incremental value through the
realization of synergies even in absence of inefficient management of targets. The past
studies also highlight that the homogeneity of real estate firms, especially as they
pertain to the highly regulated REIT industry, is expected to reduce the availability


VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW               OF THE   LITERATURE     45

of revenue and overall corporate synergies, but might allow for the ability of some
firms to more readily be able to take advantage of scale efficiencies.
Future research should ascribe a higher importance to the role of synergies as rationale
to engage in real estate mergers, taking into account the unique characteristics of the
industry and in particular those that the REIT structure inevitably brings along.
Synergies are recognized as a central merger motive in the general finance literature
but have been largely overlooked in real estate M&A research for the sake of focusing
on the inefficient management theory to explain the almost entire absence of hostile
takeovers among real estate firms. Looking forward, the currently rising number of
takeovers in the real estate industry will allow for analyses in the near future not
possible to date due to an insufficient number of observations and time periods that are
too short. Finance studies show that the patterns of takeover activity vary significantly
across takeover waves, with different motives being the dominant rationale to merge
in each wave. Even though the real estate M&A market exhibits the same cyclical
wave pattern, this aspect has not been further analyzed to date. It will be interesting
to see whether the motives differ in the earlier years of the REIT industry compared
to those in the modern REIT era. Potential events that can be expected to have had
an impact on the dominant reasons to merge are the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (REITs
no longer were required to have external management), the establishment of the
‘‘look-through’’ provision in 1993 (allowance concerning the ‘‘five or fewer’’ rule of
REITs with regard to the number of investors represented by a pension or mutual
fund), and the REIT Modernization Act of 1999 (relaxed restrictions on the ancillary
businesses that REITs could be engaged in to some extent).

ENDNOTES
1. The terms ‘‘takeover,’’ ‘‘merger,’’ ‘‘acquisition,’’ and ‘‘M&A’’ are used interchangeably
   throughout this paper.
2. Please refer to Womack (2012) for a comprehensive review of the literature on the wealth
   effects of real estate related mergers and acquisitions.
3. See Anderson, Lewis, and Springer (2000) for a literature review on the operating efficiencies
   in real estate.
4. Real estate firms not structured as REITs, also known as real estate operating companies
   (REOCs), are not constrained by these regulations and are similar in most aspects to firms
   outside of the real estate industry. Their relevance for the publicly-listed real estate market
   in the U.S. is rather small in comparison to REITs.
5. See, for example, Allen and Sirmans (1987) for a summary of the key provisions a REIT
   must meet to be qualified. Please also refer to Feng, Price, and Sirmans (2011) for a
   comprehensive documentation of the publicly-traded equity REIT universe.
6. Allen and Sirmans (1987) find that only one event in their sample of 38 REIT mergers could
   be classified as a hostile takeover. Campbell, Gosh, and Sirmans (1998) find no single
   successful hostile takeover in the 27 transactions studied. Campbell, Gosh, and Sirmans
   (2001) also find none in their sample of 85 REIT mergers. Eichholtz and Kok (2008)
   investigate 95 takeovers of property companies all over the world and find that only two are
   hostile. Womack (2012) finds that only 1 out of the 94 mergers of public real estate firms
   studied can be classified as a hostile takeover.
46   JOURNAL   OF   REAL ESTATE LITERATURE

7. The synergy theory is not controlled for in Womack’s (2012) study. Berkovitch and
   Narayanan (1993) use a similar research design to test for three merger theories in the regular
   corporate world (synergy, agency, and hubris). They additionally design a formal test to
   distinguish between agency and hubris motives for takeovers, thereby allowing for the
   potential coexistence of more than one theory, by analyzing the correlations between target,
   bidder, and total gains.
8. Houston, James, and Ryngaert (2001) point out this complication in their study of large U.S.
   bank mergers and explicitly name one merger for which security analysts note that a material
   fraction of the forecasted cost savings is attributable to a cost-cutting program already under
   way. The authors also note that it is not clear whether management is unaware of the biased
   nature of the forecasts and conclude that these tendencies do on balance tend to exaggerate
   the valuation estimates used in their paper.


REFERENCES

Allen, P., and C.F. Sirmans. An Analysis of Gains to Acquiring Firm’s Shareholders: The Special
Case of REITs. Journal of Financial Economics, 1987, 18, 175–84.
Anderson, R.I., D. Lewis, and T.M. Springer. Operating Efficiencies in Real Estate: A Critical
Review of the Literature. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 2000, 8:1, 3–20.
Anderson, R.I., H. Medla, N.B. Rottke, and D. Schiereck. Why Do REIT Mergers Take Place?
Evidence from Synergistic Forecasts. Working Paper, EBS Business School, 2011.
Berkovitch, E. and M.P. Narayanan. Motives for Takeovers: An Empirical Investigation. Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 1993, 28:3, 347–62.
Bernile, G. and S.W. Bauguess. Do Merger Synergies Exist? Working Paper, University of
Miami. Available at SSRN: http: / / ssrn.com / abstractϭ642322. 2010.
Bradley, M., A. Desai, and E.H. Kim. The Rationale behind Interfirm Tender Offers: Information
or Synergy? Journal of Financial Economics, 1983, 21:1, 3–40.
Campbell, R.D., C. Ghosh, and C.F. Sirmans. The Great REIT Consolidation: Fact or Fancy?
Real Estate Finance, 1998, 15:2, 45–54.
——. The Information Content of Method of Payment in Mergers: Evidence from Real Estate
Investment Trusts (REITs). Real Estate Economics, 2001, 29, 360–87.
Dong, M., D. Hirshleifer, S. Richardson, and S.H. Teoh. Does Investor Misvaluation Drive the
Takeover Market? Journal of Finance, 2006, 61:2, 725–62.
Eichholtz, P.M.A. and N. Kok. How Does the Market for Corporate Control Function for
Property Companies? Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2008, 36:2, 141–63.
Elayan, F.A. and P.J. Young. The Value of Control: Evidence from Full and Partial Acquisitions
in the Real Estate Industry. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1994, 8, 167–82.
Feng, Z., S.M. Price, and C.F. Sirmans. An Overview of Equity Real Estate Investment Trusts
(REITs): 1993–2009. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 2011, 19:2, 307–43.
Harford, J. Corporate Cash Reserves and Acquisitions. Journal of Finance, 1999, 54:6, 1969–
97.
——. What Drives Merger Waves? Journal of Financial Economics, 2005, 77:3, 529–60.
Houston, J., C. James, and M. Ryngaert. Where Do Merger Gains Come From? Bank Mergers
from the Perspective of Insiders and Outsiders. Journal of Financial Economics, 2001, 60, 285–
331.
Jensen, M.C. Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American
Economic Review, 1986, 76:2, 323–29.


VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW           OF THE   LITERATURE   47

——. Takeovers: Their Causes and Consequences. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1988, 2,
21–48.
Ling, D.C. and M.T. Petrova. Why Do REITs go Private? Differences in Target Characteristics,
Acquirer Motivations, and Wealth Effects in Public and Private Acquisitions. Journal of Real
Estate Finance and Economics, 2011, 43:1, 99–129.
Martynova, M. and L. Renneboog. A Century of Corporate Takeovers: What Have We Learned
and Where Do We Stand? Journal of Banking and Finance, 2008, 32:10, 2148–77.
Mueller, D.C. A Theory of Conglomerate Mergers. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1969, 83:
4, 643–59.
Myers, S. and N. Majluf. Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have
Information that Investors Do Not Have. Journal of Financial Economics, 1984, 13, 187–221.
Rhodes-Kropf, M., D. Robinson, and S. Viswanathan. Valuation Waves and Merger Activity:
The Empirical Evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 2005, 77:3, 561–603.
Roll, R. The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers. Journal of Business, 1986, 59, 197–
216.
Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny. Takeovers in the ‘60s and the ‘80s: Evidence and Implications.
Strategic Management Journal, 1991, 12, 51–59.
Womack, K.S. (2012). Real Estate Mergers: Corporate Control & Shareholder Wealth. Journal
of Real Estate Finance and Economics, forthcoming.




Randy I. Anderson, University of Central Florida Orlando, FL 32816-1400 and EBS
Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany or randerson@bus.ucf.edu.
Henrik Medla, EBS Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany or henrik.
medla@ebs-remi.de.
Nico B. Rottke, EBS Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany and University of
Central Florida Orlando, FL 32816-1400 or nico.rottke@ebs.edu.
Dirk Schiereck, Tech University Darmstadt, D-64289 Darmstadt, Germany and EBS
Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany or schiereck@bwl.tu-darmstadt.de.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

Weitere ähnliche Inhalte

Was ist angesagt?

Factors determining capital structure a case study of listed
Factors determining capital structure a case study of listedFactors determining capital structure a case study of listed
Factors determining capital structure a case study of listedAlexander Decker
 
Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...
Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...
Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...Alexander Decker
 
Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...
Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...
Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...Université Internationale de Rabat
 
Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...
Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...
Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...Ronald Girsang
 
Artikel Original Teori Ukuran Perusahaan
Artikel Original Teori Ukuran PerusahaanArtikel Original Teori Ukuran Perusahaan
Artikel Original Teori Ukuran PerusahaanTrisnadi Wijaya
 
Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay Barney
Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay BarneyFirm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay Barney
Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay Barneychitwarnold
 
Towards a social action analysis of organizations
Towards a social action analysis of organizationsTowards a social action analysis of organizations
Towards a social action analysis of organizationsAmir Ghazinoori
 
Abrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey results
Abrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey resultsAbrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey results
Abrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey resultsMurtaza Khan
 
Literature analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...
Literature   analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...Literature   analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...
Literature analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...Top Grade Papers
 
Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...
Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...
Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...Grupo de Economia Política IE-UFRJ
 
Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...
Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...
Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...McRey Banderlipe II
 
The impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendations
The impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendationsThe impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendations
The impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendationslucahearth
 
Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...
Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...
Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...inventionjournals
 

Was ist angesagt? (20)

Factors determining capital structure a case study of listed
Factors determining capital structure a case study of listedFactors determining capital structure a case study of listed
Factors determining capital structure a case study of listed
 
Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...
Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...
Analyzing the impact of firm’s specific factors and macroeconomic factors on ...
 
Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...
Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...
Journal of Business Venturing : Alliance portfolios and shareholder value in ...
 
Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...
Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...
Effective tax rates and the gç£industrial policy gç¥ hypothesis evidence from...
 
Artikel Original Teori Ukuran Perusahaan
Artikel Original Teori Ukuran PerusahaanArtikel Original Teori Ukuran Perusahaan
Artikel Original Teori Ukuran Perusahaan
 
Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay Barney
Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay BarneyFirm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay Barney
Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage by Jay Barney
 
Towards a social action analysis of organizations
Towards a social action analysis of organizationsTowards a social action analysis of organizations
Towards a social action analysis of organizations
 
Ssrn id1534186
Ssrn id1534186Ssrn id1534186
Ssrn id1534186
 
Market concentration measures and investment decisions in mexican manufacturi...
Market concentration measures and investment decisions in mexican manufacturi...Market concentration measures and investment decisions in mexican manufacturi...
Market concentration measures and investment decisions in mexican manufacturi...
 
Non-Linearity in Determinants of Corporate Effective Tax Rate: Further Eviden...
Non-Linearity in Determinants of Corporate Effective Tax Rate: Further Eviden...Non-Linearity in Determinants of Corporate Effective Tax Rate: Further Eviden...
Non-Linearity in Determinants of Corporate Effective Tax Rate: Further Eviden...
 
mrev_1-2_16_Jackson
mrev_1-2_16_Jacksonmrev_1-2_16_Jackson
mrev_1-2_16_Jackson
 
Abrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey results
Abrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey resultsAbrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey results
Abrutyn and turner. taxes and firms'dividend policies survey results
 
Literature analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...
Literature   analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...Literature   analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...
Literature analysis of sudia arabia companies - assignment - www.topgradepa...
 
Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...
Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...
Macro/Micro interactions : Economic and Institutional Uncertainties and Struc...
 
SBA FINAL
SBA FINALSBA FINAL
SBA FINAL
 
Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...
Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...
Article: Influence of Corporate Board Characteristics on Firm Performance of ...
 
The impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendations
The impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendationsThe impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendations
The impact of corporate social responsibility on investment recommendations
 
Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...
Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...
Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure...
 
2011 contribpapercarroll
2011 contribpapercarroll2011 contribpapercarroll
2011 contribpapercarroll
 
10120140506006
1012014050600610120140506006
10120140506006
 

Ähnlich wie Real Estate Mergers Review

Law and Management Bagley
Law and Management BagleyLaw and Management Bagley
Law and Management Bagleyjsheredia
 
A stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firmA stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firmMateus Cozer
 
Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...
Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...
Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...Consiliacapital
 
Capital structure feng ghosh sirman
Capital structure feng ghosh sirmanCapital structure feng ghosh sirman
Capital structure feng ghosh sirmanNO_WAY_OUT
 
07. the determinants of capital structure
07. the determinants of capital structure07. the determinants of capital structure
07. the determinants of capital structurenguyenviet30
 
6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies manageri...
6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies  manageri...6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies  manageri...
6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies manageri...Ann Wera
 
Corporate Diversification
Corporate DiversificationCorporate Diversification
Corporate DiversificationDODODEEP
 
FINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIES
FINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIESFINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIES
FINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIESJulian Swartz
 
Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...
Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...
Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...Alexander Decker
 
30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...
30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH  RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH  RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...
30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...Rhonda Cetnar
 
gupea_2077_52939_1.pdf
gupea_2077_52939_1.pdfgupea_2077_52939_1.pdf
gupea_2077_52939_1.pdfMadushan3
 
The effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on the
The effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on theThe effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on the
The effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on theAlexander Decker
 
Corporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdf
Corporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdfCorporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdf
Corporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdfBalasingamPrahalatha
 
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1Rose Kiprop
 
Ownership and control in multinational joint ventures
Ownership and control in multinational joint venturesOwnership and control in multinational joint ventures
Ownership and control in multinational joint venturesanushreeg0
 
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistanCapital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistanAlexander Decker
 
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistanCapital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistanAlexander Decker
 

Ähnlich wie Real Estate Mergers Review (20)

Law and Management Bagley
Law and Management BagleyLaw and Management Bagley
Law and Management Bagley
 
A stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firmA stakeholder theory of the firm
A stakeholder theory of the firm
 
Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...
Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...
Use of listed real estate securities in asset management - alex moss, consili...
 
IBR5.pdf
IBR5.pdfIBR5.pdf
IBR5.pdf
 
Capital structure feng ghosh sirman
Capital structure feng ghosh sirmanCapital structure feng ghosh sirman
Capital structure feng ghosh sirman
 
07. the determinants of capital structure
07. the determinants of capital structure07. the determinants of capital structure
07. the determinants of capital structure
 
6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies manageri...
6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies  manageri...6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies  manageri...
6 The role of resource-based theory in strategic management studies manageri...
 
10120140503001
1012014050300110120140503001
10120140503001
 
Corporate Diversification
Corporate DiversificationCorporate Diversification
Corporate Diversification
 
FINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIES
FINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIESFINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIES
FINTECH PLATFORMS' STRATEGIC POSSIBILITIES
 
Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...
Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...
Foreign ownership, domestic ownership and capital structure special reference...
 
30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...
30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH  RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH  RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...
30 YEARS OF MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS RESEARCH RECENT ADVANCES AND FUTURE OPP...
 
gupea_2077_52939_1.pdf
gupea_2077_52939_1.pdfgupea_2077_52939_1.pdf
gupea_2077_52939_1.pdf
 
The effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on the
The effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on theThe effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on the
The effects of the intensity of firm’s intangible assets on the
 
Corporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdf
Corporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdfCorporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdf
Corporate_Governance_A_Survey_of_the_Lit.pdf
 
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1A knowledge accessing theory of strategic      alliance pdf1
A knowledge accessing theory of strategic alliance pdf1
 
Ownership and control in multinational joint ventures
Ownership and control in multinational joint venturesOwnership and control in multinational joint ventures
Ownership and control in multinational joint ventures
 
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistanCapital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
 
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistanCapital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
Capital structure determinants evidence from banking sector of pakistan
 
Becoming an Acquirer and Becoming Acquired
Becoming an Acquirer and Becoming AcquiredBecoming an Acquirer and Becoming Acquired
Becoming an Acquirer and Becoming Acquired
 

Mehr von Oscar Gonzales

HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014
HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014
HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014Oscar Gonzales
 
HAR Networking 11.13.2014
HAR Networking 11.13.2014HAR Networking 11.13.2014
HAR Networking 11.13.2014Oscar Gonzales
 
The Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search Behavior
The Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search BehaviorThe Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search Behavior
The Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search BehaviorOscar Gonzales
 
Strategy for the Millennial brokerage
Strategy for the Millennial brokerageStrategy for the Millennial brokerage
Strategy for the Millennial brokerageOscar Gonzales
 
Surviving in the Social Era
 Surviving in the Social Era Surviving in the Social Era
Surviving in the Social EraOscar Gonzales
 
Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013
Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013
Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013Oscar Gonzales
 
Role of Commission Rates Study
Role of Commission Rates StudyRole of Commission Rates Study
Role of Commission Rates StudyOscar Gonzales
 
Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012
Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012
Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012Oscar Gonzales
 
Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?
Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?
Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?Oscar Gonzales
 
Servicing the Multicultural Homebuyer
Servicing the Multicultural HomebuyerServicing the Multicultural Homebuyer
Servicing the Multicultural HomebuyerOscar Gonzales
 
Examining Population Trends
Examining Population TrendsExamining Population Trends
Examining Population TrendsOscar Gonzales
 
The Next Generation of Brokerage
The Next Generation of BrokerageThe Next Generation of Brokerage
The Next Generation of BrokerageOscar Gonzales
 

Mehr von Oscar Gonzales (14)

Staging for Feng Shui
Staging for Feng ShuiStaging for Feng Shui
Staging for Feng Shui
 
HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014
HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014
HAR International 101 Presentation 11/21/2014
 
HAR Networking 11.13.2014
HAR Networking 11.13.2014HAR Networking 11.13.2014
HAR Networking 11.13.2014
 
The Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search Behavior
The Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search BehaviorThe Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search Behavior
The Eyes Have It: Understanding Home Buyer Internet Search Behavior
 
The Era of Social
The Era of SocialThe Era of Social
The Era of Social
 
Strategy for the Millennial brokerage
Strategy for the Millennial brokerageStrategy for the Millennial brokerage
Strategy for the Millennial brokerage
 
Surviving in the Social Era
 Surviving in the Social Era Surviving in the Social Era
Surviving in the Social Era
 
Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013
Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013
Kinder Institute Asian Survey 2013
 
Role of Commission Rates Study
Role of Commission Rates StudyRole of Commission Rates Study
Role of Commission Rates Study
 
Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012
Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012
Homebuyer Internet Search Behavior Study 2.2012
 
Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?
Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?
Are You On The Bullet Train To Irrelevance?
 
Servicing the Multicultural Homebuyer
Servicing the Multicultural HomebuyerServicing the Multicultural Homebuyer
Servicing the Multicultural Homebuyer
 
Examining Population Trends
Examining Population TrendsExamining Population Trends
Examining Population Trends
 
The Next Generation of Brokerage
The Next Generation of BrokerageThe Next Generation of Brokerage
The Next Generation of Brokerage
 

Real Estate Mergers Review

  • 1. REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE Randy I. Anderson University of Central Florida Orlando and EBS Business School Henrik Medla EBS Business School Nico B. Rottke EBS Business School and University of Central Florida Orlando Dirk Schiereck Tech University Darmstadt and EBS Business School Abstract This paper examines the dominant theories, motives, methodologies, and results of the existing literature on the rationale for real estate related mergers. The literature review draws on the mainstream corporate governance literature in finance as its base and highlights the differences in motives between real estate and non-real estate related merger activity. The studies highlight that the homogeneity of real estate firms, especially as they pertain to the highly regulated real estate investment trust (REIT) industry, is expected to reduce the availability of revenue and overall corporate synergies, but might allow for the ability of some firms to more readily be able to take advantage of scale efficiencies. In addition to summarizing past studies, the review concludes with a discussion of the need for continued research in this evolving literature. In the finance literature, there exists a plethora of studies that examine both theoretically and empirically the issues surrounding mergers and acquisitions (M&A).1 The traditional approach has been to examine, utilizing event study methodology, the wealth implications for the bidder and target firms. The same approach has also been predominantly applied on real estate related M&A studies. Womack (2012) is the first to determine the combined firm returns for a sample spanning nearly three decades of real estate mergers. Prior real estate merger studies analyzed bidder and/or target returns but did not evaluate the combined wealth effects. Target returns were consistently found to be positive but relatively small compared to those evidenced in studies outside the real estate industry. Results concerning bidder returns are less conclusive and vary greatly depending on the analyzed time frame [i.e., before or after the Tax Reform Act of 1986 and/or the Real Estate Investment Trust (REIT) Modernization Act of 1999], as well as on the types of firms (i.e., REITs vs. all real estate firms, equity REITs vs. all REITs, public targets vs. private and public targets, etc.) studied in the individual sample of the studies. Most studies, however, show slightly negative returns to bidding firms around the merger announcement, at least for mergers with public targets.2 However, as depicted in Ling and Petrova (2011) and Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and Schiereck (2011), there are very few studies that assess ‘‘why’’ mergers in the real 37
  • 2. 38 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE LITERATURE estate industry (or really any other market for that matter) occur. And, perhaps just as important, the current literature is largely inconclusive or at best inconsistent across studies and sectors, leaving many unanswered questions. The majority of studies attempting to determine the rationale behind mergers in the real estate industry mainly draw on findings from studies analyzing merger motives outside the real estate industry. More recently, a number of studies build on the observation that hostile takeovers among real estate firms are extremely rare and use this as the motivation to exam why mergers then occur. The findings that hostile takeovers among real estate firms are extremely rare, as well as the many other peculiarities of the real estate market, cast doubt on the assumption that the reasons for takeovers in the real estate industry are basically the same as for those outside the industry. Moreover, the role of synergies as a motive for mergers and acquisitions in the real estate industry and especially for REIT mergers is a particularly controversial question among academics and practitioners, even though the size-related benefits in REITs are well documented in the literature.3 The common skepticism concerning the relevance and existence of synergies can mainly be ascribed to the observation that several studies measuring abnormal returns for bidding and target firms in real estate mergers document wealth effects of materially lower magnitude than those detected in studies for other sectors. The lower magnitude of returns is thereby regularly explained by the limited potential for synergistic gains from real estate mergers. Eichholtz and Kok (2008), for example, argue that the homogeneity of assets of real estate companies decreases the potential for synergistic profits emerging from merged operations. They also reason that the homogeneity of operations in real estate mergers does not allow for large value-creating synergies. Campbell, Ghosh, and Sirmans (2001) suggest that the required uniformity of REIT asset composition largely eliminates the potential for vertical integration synergies through mergers. In a recent study, Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and Schiereck (2011) show that the expected magnitude of total synergies for REIT mergers is lower than those found in other sectors. They, however, also find that for the same homogeneity reasons, REITs are able to find greater synergies than non-REIT firms on the operating cost side and, as such, can take considerable advantage of economies of scale. The results of their study therefore challenge the notion that synergies do not play a major role as a motive for REIT mergers. This paper provides a detailed review of the literature beginning with the theoretical background that motivates mergers, followed by a detailed discussion of the real estate focused studies. Studies that merely analyze wealth effects in real estate mergers are not covered here and the authors do not attempt to determine the rationale behind those takeovers, as those effects are already sufficiently documented in a recent study by Womack (2012). The paper concludes with a brief summary and discussion of the need for additional research in this emerging literature. The main findings suggest that it is first and foremost important to study real estate mergers separately and distinctly from non-real estate related firms. This is even more relevant when dealing with publically traded REITs that have very specific regulatory guidelines. These guidelines tend to homogenize REITs making synergistic gains from VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
  • 3. REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 39 mergers more difficult, while at the same time providing opportunities for readily available greater gains from economies of scale in operating costs. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND OF MERGER MOTIVES The motives for takeovers can be numerous and true verification is often ambiguous and/or impossible to fully ascertain. A reasonable and compelling differentiation between the diverse merger motives is to distinguish between neoclassical theories on the one hand and agency and behavioral theories on the other (Bernile and Bauguess, 2010). According to neoclassical theories, mergers occur mainly as a result of external shocks, either in the form of economic, technological, financial, regulatory, or political shocks (Harford, 1999, 2005) and are made to sustain or create competitive advantages (Jensen, 1988). Mergers under the neoclassical perspective are mostly motivated by such shocks and are expected to lead to profit optimization and shareholder value creation, assuming managers are aligned with shareholders’ interests (Martynova and Renneboog, 2008). Following this logic, merged firms should be able to operate more efficiently than the individual standalone entities through the realization of synergies. In contrast, agency and behavioral theories allow for the possibility that takeovers are value-destroying transactions. Inherent agency conflicts between firms’ insiders and investors or biases affecting managers are thereby credited as motives to engage in M&A transactions (Jensen, 1986; Roll, 1986; Shleifer and Vishny, 1991; Berkovitch and Naryanan, 1993). According to those theories, managers may seek to build an empire through vast acquisitions while shareholders want the management to increase the value of the firm. According to Mueller (1969), management salaries, bonuses, stock options, and promotions tend to be more associated with corporate size than to the firm’s profitability. Likewise, the power and prestige of managers are more associated with the growth and size of the firm than to its profitability. Jensen (1986) also found that managers have an incentive to grow firms beyond their optimal size since their compensation is positively related to sales growth. Roll (1986) reasons that managerial hubris makes overconfident managers overestimate the creation of synergetic value, thereby tempting them to engage in value-destroying mergers. Another recently popular theory is market timing, whereby insiders attempt to exploit temporary market ‘‘misvaluations’’ (Rhodes-Kropf, Robinson, and Viswanathan, 2005; Dong, Hirshleifer, Richardson, and Teoh, 2006). The theory is based on Myers and Majluf (1984), who argue that managers take advantage of temporarily overvalued equity as cheap currency for acquiring real assets. Prior research reveals that none of those theories are mutually exclusive; meaning those firms and their insiders may simultaneously have more than one motive when engaging in takeovers (Berkovitch and Narayanan, 1993). The empirical evidence also indicates that no single theory can fully explain the occurrence of M&A activity and the pattern of takeover waves. Martynova and Renneboog (2008) show in a comprehensive literature review on corporate takeovers of the last century that the most consistent finding regarding the reasons for takeovers is that they are motivated differently depending on the stage of the merger wave they are executed in, and that
  • 4. 40 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE LITERATURE wealth effects also vary depending on whether they take place in the earlier or later part of a wave. The combined companies are thereby expected to create synergistic gains when the merger occurs in the first half of a takeover wave. In contrast, the majority of value-destroying acquisitions take place in the second half of a wave. The same theories discussed above are commonly used to explain the occurrence of M&As among real estate firms. The real estate industry, however, exhibits unique aspects that cast doubt on whether this approach is reasonable and should be accepted without in-depth validation. The most relevant difference to other industries is the dominance of REITs in the real estate market.4 Those firms avoid the double taxation of typical corporations in exchange for meeting a strict list of ownership, asset, income, and dividend payout requirements.5 The strict rules REITs have to comply with in order to obtain and subsequently maintain their status should have an impact on the relevancy of the individual theories explaining takeover activity in the real estate industry. In this context, Allen and Sirmans (1987) propose that some classic corporate merger motives can be precluded for REITs due to their unique structure and their institutional environment. As an example, they point out that ‘‘it is unlikely that a business combination of REITs would create any monopolistic power’’ (p. 177), because the vast majority of REIT income must come from passive sources such as rents and mortgages. Moreover, other peculiarities of the real estate market, such as the coexistence of a large private market that competes directly against firms for the ownership of real estate assets, are also expected to have various implications. The fact that hostile takeovers among real estate firms are extremely rare also casts doubt on the assumption that the reasons for takeovers in the real estate industry are basically the same than for those outside the industry and that the market for corporate control works in essentially the same way (Eichholtz and Kok, 2008; Womack, 2012). LITERATURE REVIEW OF REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVE STUDIES The latest relevant research on real estate mergers mainly builds on the almost entire absence of hostile takeovers among real estate firms.6 In this context, Womack (2012, p. 2) raises these questions: ‘‘Does the above [i.e., the fact that hostile takeovers among real estate firms are extremely rare] imply that management of underperforming firms are not held accountable for their results? If not, then why do real estate mergers occur?’’ In order to investigate why real estate mergers occur, he tests for three merger motives: the empire building hypothesis, the over-valued information signal hypothesis, and the inefficient management hypothesis. His results indicate that the motivation for real estate mergers is consistent with the inefficient management hypothesis. According to this hypothesis, firms with superior management acquire other firms that possess unexploited opportunities to cut costs and increase earnings. The study, however, only tests for three popular merger motives without taking into account other important potential motivations. The methodology used to test for the motives based solely on abnormal returns around the takeover announcement only allows for an analysis on the meta level without gaining detailed insights into the expected sources underlying real estate merger gains. VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
  • 5. REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 41 Womack’s (2012, p. 2) approach builds on the assumption that ‘‘because each merger theory generates a testable hypothesis about the stock market’s response to the news of a merger announcement, the returns for each of these firms collectively can be utilized to test which theory is best supported by the data.’’ Following his argument, takeovers under the inefficient management hypothesis would generally be wealth- creating events. The hypothesis predicts the following abnormal returns: target (positive), bidder (non-negative), and combined firm (non-negative). The applied experimental design does not allow for controlling whether the inefficient management hypothesis is really the dominant theory that predicts this kind of announcement effect. The synergy hypothesis stating that merged firms should be able to operate more efficiently than individual standalone entities by cutting redundant costs and additionally increasing earnings, for example, should lead to a similar capital market reaction. The inference of motivations underlying mergers based exclusively on the returns around the deal announcement does not enable consideration of the fact that there may be other theories that predict the same, or at least a very similar return pattern.7 Some of the other findings that are used to support the inefficient management hypothesis may be driven by alternative explanations. Womack’s results, for example, indicate that bidders typically do not seek geographical diversification. He ascribes this finding to the fact that effective managerial focus is more difficult when properties are widely spread apart. However, this result could be alternatively associated with bidders’ aims to generate material cost synergies, which is more likely to be accomplished in focused mergers where the bidder is located in the same state as the target and the potential for cutting redundant costs is consequently higher. Allen and Sirmans (1987) mention tax motivations (i.e., the purchase of operating losses to offset the acquiring REIT’s capital gains) and the opportunity to replace inefficient management as potential motives for REIT mergers. Only six out of the 31 events in their study with complete information involves one or the other trust having experienced an operating loss in a previous period. A differential means test between the two subsamples does also not reveal any significant differences. They conclude that on the basis of these observations, tax motivations alone are not important motives in REIT combinations. However, they find that related mergers (i.e., bidder and target are both equity/mortgage REITs and/or have the same property focus or geographic focus) yield statistically significant higher abnormal returns around the announcement than unrelated combinations. They paraphrase this finding as evidence for the inefficient management hypothesis. An alternative explanation would yet be that synergies are likely to be higher for related business combinations. Elayan and Young (1994) extend Allen and Sirmans’ (1987) examination of the sources of gains to target shareholders. They note that ‘‘in addition to improved asset management through a change in control, anticipated operational and financial synergies may contribute to gains associated with a business combination’’ (p. 169). In order to partition the gains from these two sources, they examine the wealth effects of both the targets and bidders when controlling (i.e., acquisitions that result in the bidder’s control of over 50% of the target’s outstanding shares) and noncontrolling interests are sought. Their hypothesis builds on the assumption that while a gain based on synergies could be associated with either form of combination, a gain from a
  • 6. 42 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE LITERATURE change in control would exclusively be associated with an acquisition of a controlling interest. Their results show that the significant positive abnormal returns that accrue to target shareholders in both cases are significantly larger when a controlling interest is sought and infer that this is consistent with the realization of greater efficiency associated with a change in control (i.e., evidence for the inefficient management hypothesis). The authors bring a new approach into play and their findings reveal interesting results. However, the underlying assumption in the study is that synergies can be (fully) realized in cases only when partial control is obtained in an acquisition is critical. Savings in many expense categories can only be realized if the two combining firms are in fact fully integrated. Savings in duplicative public company expenses, which can be expected to be substantial for the relatively small firms in Elayan and Young’s (1994) sample period from 1972 to 1987, can for example only be realized if both companies are fully integrated. Bradley, Desai, and Kim (1993), for example, use a threshold of 70% as a prerequisite for the generation of potential synergies in their study examining synergies across multiple industries. They base their selection of the 70% threshold on the fact that some corporate charters require a two-thirds or higher majority to effect a formal combination of two firms. Campbell, Gosh, and Sirmans (1998) infer, based on their finding of negative announcement returns of acquiring equity REITs, that hubris or self-dealing may be the rationale behind those mergers. They base this assessment purely on the observed wealth effect and do not further elaborate on their interpretation. Eichholtz and Kok (2008) supplement the existing studies by investigating 95 takeovers of property companies all over the world. Especially worth remarking is that they thereby measure bidder and target performance prior to the takeover announcement, which had not been done for real estate mergers before. To determine the effectiveness of the market for corporate control, they study the characteristics of targets and bidders compared to a control sample using a multinomial logistic approach. They find that targets are mainly financially underperforming, small target companies have a low market-to-book value, and that weak operating and stock performance of real estate companies are positively related to the likelihood of a takeover. The authors interpret this evidence as in line with the inefficient management hypothesis. Moreover, they compare their results between REIT takeovers and non- REIT takeovers, which are mainly takeovers involving non-U.S. entities, and find that targets in non-REIT mergers have a significantly negative coefficient for market-to- book value, whereas this result does not hold for REITs. Based on this finding for the subsample of REITs, one can see that the overall obtained results may not be representative for REIT M&A deals in general. Another notable exception to the wealth effect based merger motive studies is a recent paper by Ling and Petrova (2011). The authors identify the characteristics of publicly- traded REITs associated with an increased probability of being the target of an announced takeover. They also examine whether certain target characteristics influence the probability of a bidder being a private versus a public firm. They find that REITs that are more likely to become acquisition targets relative to the rest of public REITs VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
  • 7. REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 43 are generally smaller and more cash restricted with relatively high dividend yields and institutional ownership and no umbrella operating partnership. The differences between the target firms in public-to-public versus going private acquisitions are also documented. More precisely, the authors deliver evidence that the targets of private acquirers have lower leverage, interest coverage ratios, and profitability, but higher dividend yields. Their results therefore provide evidence for different motivations for private versus public acquirers. Private bidders tend to focus on profit maximization and hence are bidding on cash restricted, underlevered, and underperforming target REITs. Public bidders are eager to increase market power and are therefore more focused on acquiring profitable and higher levered REITs with higher dividend yields. Their finding that in the case of acquisitions by private firms, but not by public firms, targets are typically underperforming with low leverage, deliver important insights into the merger motives of public real estate acquirers and shows that the inefficient management hypothesis does not seem to hold unrestrictedly for staying public mergers. Most of the recent studies by now focus on the inefficient management hypothesis to explain takeovers in the real estate industry, thereby mostly neglecting the neoclassical view that mergers indeed have the potential to create incremental value through the realization of synergies even in absence of inefficient management of targets. At the bottom line, a precise separation between gains from synergies on the one hand and from those from the replacement of inefficient management on the other does not seem to be always possible. Whether gains simply stem from cutting previously above- average expenses at the target level or real incremental gains (i.e., synergies) are in fact generated by the combination of two previously independent entities cannot always be evaluated from an outsider’s perspective. Even in those mergers where the management of the bidding firm explicitly forecasts the synergies expected from the merger, the management could, for example, include cost savings in their forecasts that also would have been realized without a merger, thereby inflating merger-related synergistic gains.8 Both sources of merger gains, however, on balance lead to more efficient operations of the combined entities. The potential complications with differentiating between the gains from the two sources should therefore not lead to serious concerns as they both have very similar effects on the performance of the newly combined firms. From an academic perspective, a precise separation is nevertheless of interest, since the findings can have important implications for academics, as well as for practitioners engaged in the field of real estate M&A. Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and Schiereck (2011) attempt to distinguish between the gains from the two different sources whenever the data and applied methodology allow. The authors provide some insights into why REIT mergers occur by analyzing hand-collected synergy forecasts provided by merging firms’ insiders for a sample of merger announcements where the bidder is a publically-traded REIT in the U.S. The neoclassical view that characterizes mergers as firms’ rational, efficiency-enhancing reaction to a changing environment is thereby a priori accepted as the dominant theory. The approach to focus on synergies as a merger motive has the advantage that evidence for, but also against synergies as motive can be interpreted twofold. This means that if there is no evidence for potential synergies in the takeover, other motives
  • 8. 44 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE LITERATURE must have been the decision criterion. They hypothesize that expected synergies are in fact an important merger motive for REITs and therefore expect that synergies are quoted and quantified more often in REIT mergers than in mergers in the rest of the corporate world. Their finding that management forecasts of synergies are publicly available in 35% of the REIT mergers in their sample and therefore for a materially higher proportion of deals than evidenced in other studies analyzing synergy forecasts in samples across multiple industries supports their contention. However, the available sample size is quite small and thus limits the robustness of the findings. Anderson, Medla, Rottke, and Schiereck (2011) also investigate the determinants of insiders’ forecasts of synergies and thereby attempt to explain the variation in the estimated present value of synergies using the variables that are predicted to influence those values. The results of their cross-sectional analyses using OLS regressions show that the factors suggested by the literature to proxy for the potential existence of synergies explain a considerable share of the variation in the estimated present value of synergies. Managerial synergy forecasts in REIT mergers therefore seem to be economically significant and profound. The results are consistent with more general findings on economies of scale in REITs, demonstrating that general and administrative (G&A) expenses and to a lesser extent also interest expenses are the most relevant sources for cost savings. The results of the study also provide additional insights into the synergy motivation; however, the experimental design is not set-up to allow for a comprehensive controlling for the potential existence of alternative theories. The potential (co-)existence of agency and/or behavioral theory based motivations consequently cannot be assessed. CONCLUSION This paper reviews the dominant theories, motives, methodologies, and results of the existing literature on the rationale for real estate related mergers. The theoretical background that motivates mergers is presented and neoclassical theories and behavioral theories thereby discussed, followed by a detailed discussion of the real estate focused studies. The literature review thereby draws on the mainstream corporate governance literature in finance as its base and highlights the differences in motives between real estate and non-real estate related merger activity. The findings show that the existing literature is largely inconclusive, leaving many unanswered questions. The majority of studies attempting to determine the rationale behind mergers in the real estate industry mainly draw on findings from studies analyzing merger motives outside the real estate industry. More recently, a number of studies build on the observation that hostile takeovers among real estate firms are extremely rare and therefore focus on the inefficient management hypothesis to explain takeovers in the real estate industry. The focus on the inefficient management hypothesis to explain takeovers in the real estate industry, however, neglects the neoclassical view that mergers indeed have the potential to create incremental value through the realization of synergies even in absence of inefficient management of targets. The past studies also highlight that the homogeneity of real estate firms, especially as they pertain to the highly regulated REIT industry, is expected to reduce the availability VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
  • 9. REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 45 of revenue and overall corporate synergies, but might allow for the ability of some firms to more readily be able to take advantage of scale efficiencies. Future research should ascribe a higher importance to the role of synergies as rationale to engage in real estate mergers, taking into account the unique characteristics of the industry and in particular those that the REIT structure inevitably brings along. Synergies are recognized as a central merger motive in the general finance literature but have been largely overlooked in real estate M&A research for the sake of focusing on the inefficient management theory to explain the almost entire absence of hostile takeovers among real estate firms. Looking forward, the currently rising number of takeovers in the real estate industry will allow for analyses in the near future not possible to date due to an insufficient number of observations and time periods that are too short. Finance studies show that the patterns of takeover activity vary significantly across takeover waves, with different motives being the dominant rationale to merge in each wave. Even though the real estate M&A market exhibits the same cyclical wave pattern, this aspect has not been further analyzed to date. It will be interesting to see whether the motives differ in the earlier years of the REIT industry compared to those in the modern REIT era. Potential events that can be expected to have had an impact on the dominant reasons to merge are the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (REITs no longer were required to have external management), the establishment of the ‘‘look-through’’ provision in 1993 (allowance concerning the ‘‘five or fewer’’ rule of REITs with regard to the number of investors represented by a pension or mutual fund), and the REIT Modernization Act of 1999 (relaxed restrictions on the ancillary businesses that REITs could be engaged in to some extent). ENDNOTES 1. The terms ‘‘takeover,’’ ‘‘merger,’’ ‘‘acquisition,’’ and ‘‘M&A’’ are used interchangeably throughout this paper. 2. Please refer to Womack (2012) for a comprehensive review of the literature on the wealth effects of real estate related mergers and acquisitions. 3. See Anderson, Lewis, and Springer (2000) for a literature review on the operating efficiencies in real estate. 4. Real estate firms not structured as REITs, also known as real estate operating companies (REOCs), are not constrained by these regulations and are similar in most aspects to firms outside of the real estate industry. Their relevance for the publicly-listed real estate market in the U.S. is rather small in comparison to REITs. 5. See, for example, Allen and Sirmans (1987) for a summary of the key provisions a REIT must meet to be qualified. Please also refer to Feng, Price, and Sirmans (2011) for a comprehensive documentation of the publicly-traded equity REIT universe. 6. Allen and Sirmans (1987) find that only one event in their sample of 38 REIT mergers could be classified as a hostile takeover. Campbell, Gosh, and Sirmans (1998) find no single successful hostile takeover in the 27 transactions studied. Campbell, Gosh, and Sirmans (2001) also find none in their sample of 85 REIT mergers. Eichholtz and Kok (2008) investigate 95 takeovers of property companies all over the world and find that only two are hostile. Womack (2012) finds that only 1 out of the 94 mergers of public real estate firms studied can be classified as a hostile takeover.
  • 10. 46 JOURNAL OF REAL ESTATE LITERATURE 7. The synergy theory is not controlled for in Womack’s (2012) study. Berkovitch and Narayanan (1993) use a similar research design to test for three merger theories in the regular corporate world (synergy, agency, and hubris). They additionally design a formal test to distinguish between agency and hubris motives for takeovers, thereby allowing for the potential coexistence of more than one theory, by analyzing the correlations between target, bidder, and total gains. 8. Houston, James, and Ryngaert (2001) point out this complication in their study of large U.S. bank mergers and explicitly name one merger for which security analysts note that a material fraction of the forecasted cost savings is attributable to a cost-cutting program already under way. The authors also note that it is not clear whether management is unaware of the biased nature of the forecasts and conclude that these tendencies do on balance tend to exaggerate the valuation estimates used in their paper. REFERENCES Allen, P., and C.F. Sirmans. An Analysis of Gains to Acquiring Firm’s Shareholders: The Special Case of REITs. Journal of Financial Economics, 1987, 18, 175–84. Anderson, R.I., D. Lewis, and T.M. Springer. Operating Efficiencies in Real Estate: A Critical Review of the Literature. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 2000, 8:1, 3–20. Anderson, R.I., H. Medla, N.B. Rottke, and D. Schiereck. Why Do REIT Mergers Take Place? Evidence from Synergistic Forecasts. Working Paper, EBS Business School, 2011. Berkovitch, E. and M.P. Narayanan. Motives for Takeovers: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 1993, 28:3, 347–62. Bernile, G. and S.W. Bauguess. Do Merger Synergies Exist? Working Paper, University of Miami. Available at SSRN: http: / / ssrn.com / abstractϭ642322. 2010. Bradley, M., A. Desai, and E.H. Kim. The Rationale behind Interfirm Tender Offers: Information or Synergy? Journal of Financial Economics, 1983, 21:1, 3–40. Campbell, R.D., C. Ghosh, and C.F. Sirmans. The Great REIT Consolidation: Fact or Fancy? Real Estate Finance, 1998, 15:2, 45–54. ——. The Information Content of Method of Payment in Mergers: Evidence from Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs). Real Estate Economics, 2001, 29, 360–87. Dong, M., D. Hirshleifer, S. Richardson, and S.H. Teoh. Does Investor Misvaluation Drive the Takeover Market? Journal of Finance, 2006, 61:2, 725–62. Eichholtz, P.M.A. and N. Kok. How Does the Market for Corporate Control Function for Property Companies? Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2008, 36:2, 141–63. Elayan, F.A. and P.J. Young. The Value of Control: Evidence from Full and Partial Acquisitions in the Real Estate Industry. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1994, 8, 167–82. Feng, Z., S.M. Price, and C.F. Sirmans. An Overview of Equity Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs): 1993–2009. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 2011, 19:2, 307–43. Harford, J. Corporate Cash Reserves and Acquisitions. Journal of Finance, 1999, 54:6, 1969– 97. ——. What Drives Merger Waves? Journal of Financial Economics, 2005, 77:3, 529–60. Houston, J., C. James, and M. Ryngaert. Where Do Merger Gains Come From? Bank Mergers from the Perspective of Insiders and Outsiders. Journal of Financial Economics, 2001, 60, 285– 331. Jensen, M.C. Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American Economic Review, 1986, 76:2, 323–29. VOLUME 20, NUMBER 1, 2012
  • 11. REAL ESTATE MERGER MOTIVES: AN ANALYTICAL REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 47 ——. Takeovers: Their Causes and Consequences. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1988, 2, 21–48. Ling, D.C. and M.T. Petrova. Why Do REITs go Private? Differences in Target Characteristics, Acquirer Motivations, and Wealth Effects in Public and Private Acquisitions. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2011, 43:1, 99–129. Martynova, M. and L. Renneboog. A Century of Corporate Takeovers: What Have We Learned and Where Do We Stand? Journal of Banking and Finance, 2008, 32:10, 2148–77. Mueller, D.C. A Theory of Conglomerate Mergers. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1969, 83: 4, 643–59. Myers, S. and N. Majluf. Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information that Investors Do Not Have. Journal of Financial Economics, 1984, 13, 187–221. Rhodes-Kropf, M., D. Robinson, and S. Viswanathan. Valuation Waves and Merger Activity: The Empirical Evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 2005, 77:3, 561–603. Roll, R. The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers. Journal of Business, 1986, 59, 197– 216. Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny. Takeovers in the ‘60s and the ‘80s: Evidence and Implications. Strategic Management Journal, 1991, 12, 51–59. Womack, K.S. (2012). Real Estate Mergers: Corporate Control & Shareholder Wealth. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, forthcoming. Randy I. Anderson, University of Central Florida Orlando, FL 32816-1400 and EBS Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany or randerson@bus.ucf.edu. Henrik Medla, EBS Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany or henrik. medla@ebs-remi.de. Nico B. Rottke, EBS Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany and University of Central Florida Orlando, FL 32816-1400 or nico.rottke@ebs.edu. Dirk Schiereck, Tech University Darmstadt, D-64289 Darmstadt, Germany and EBS Business School, Wiesbaden, 65189 Germany or schiereck@bwl.tu-darmstadt.de.
  • 12. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.