SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 62
LECTURE NOTES
                                                in
                       INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS (*)
                                              (I)


                                    (ECON301/331/332)




                                        Cevat Gerni

                              Beykent University/İstanbul
                                        2010




(*) These lecture notes mostly depend on the textbooks of Dominick Salvatore (International
      Economics, 9e), Paul R.Krugman & Maurice Obstfeld (International Economics, 3e) and Halil
      Seyidoğlu (Uluslararası İktisat, 17e), with our own contributions.




                                                                                             1
Contents
 1   Introduction

     1.1   The Scope of International Economics
     1.2   International Economics: Trade and Money
     1.3   Why is some knowledge of international economics required?
     1.4   Historical Development of International Trade Theory (Table 1)

 2 The Law of Comparative Advantage

     2.1   Introduction
     2.2   Mercantilism
     2.3   Trade Based on Absolute Advantage: Adam Smith
     2.4   Trade Based on Comparative Advantage: David Ricardo
     2.5   Critics of Ricardo’s Comparative Advantages
     2.6   Exception to The Law of Comparative Advantage
     2.7   The Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantages (Gottfried
           Haberler)
     2.8   Empirical Tests of Ricardian Model

 3 The Standard Theory of International Trade

     3.1   Introduction
     3.2   The Production Frontier with Increasing Costs
     3.3   Equilibrium in Isolation with Increasing Costs (In a Closed
           Economy)
     3.4   The Basis For and The Gains From Trade with Increasing Costs
     3.5   The Gains From Exchange and From Specialization
     3.6   Trade Based on Differences in Tastes

 4 Offer Curves, Demand and Supply, The Terms of Trade

     4.1   Introduction
     4.2   Illustration of Offer Curves

 5 Factor Endowments and The Heckscher-Ohlin Theory

     5.1   Introduction
     5.2   Illustration of the H-O Theory
     5.3   Corollaries of the H-O Theory

                                                                            2
5.4   Empirical Tests of the Heckscher-Ohlin Model
  5.5   The New Trade Theories
  5.6   Synthesis of Trade Theories
  5.7   Transportation Costs and International Trade
  5.8   Environmental Standards and International Trade

6 Economic Growth and International Trade

  6.1   Introduction
  6.2   Interaction Between Growth and Trade
  6.3   Comparative Advantages and Economic Development




                           Chapter One

                        INTRODUCTION


                                                          3
1.1 The Scope of International Economics

This course deals with the main concepts and methods of International Economics

       Examples for some concepts and subjects of International Economics:

                      Trade between independent nations
                      Tariffs and quotas
                      Exchange rates
                      Balance of payments
                      Economic Integrations
                      Capital inflows and outflows
                         And like…


International Economics uses the ‘same fundamental methods of analysis’ as other branches
of economics, because the ‘motives’ and ‘behavior’ of individuals and firms are the same in
international trade as they are in domestic transactions.



Yet, International Economics involves ‘new and different’ concerns, because international
trade and investment occur between independent nations.

       For example,

    Chine’s toys can become more expensive in Turkey if Turkey sets a quota that limits
       imports.
    If interest rates in Turkey fall, capital outflows may occur and the value of dollar in
       terms of TL may rise.


Then, the subject matter of International Economics consists of issues raised by the special
problems of economic interaction between sovereign states.




                                                                                          4
Seven themes recur throughout the subject:

The Gains From Trade

The Pattern of Trade

Protectionism

The Balance of Payments

Exchange Rate Determination

International Policy Coordination

International Capital Market




                                             5
i.         The Gains From Trade

Probably the most important insight in all of International Economics is the idea that ‘there
are gains from trade.’

That is, that when countries sell goods and services to another, this is almost always ‘to their
mutual benefit.’

Many people are skeptical about the benefits of trade, but the range of circumstances under
which international trade is beneficial is much wider than most people appreciate.

   (will be discussed in detail later.)

   ii.        The Pattern of Trade

‘Who sells what to whom?’ This summarizes the pattern of trade, which have been a major
preoccupation of international economists.

   The reasons behind the trade might be:

    Differences in climate and natural resources
    Differences in labor productivity (D.Ricardo)
    Relative supplies of national resources such as capital, labor, and land on one side and
          relative use of these factors in the production of different goods on the other.
    A random component such as economies of scale, and external economies.
          (will be discussed in detail later.)

   iii.       Protectionism

If the idea of gains from trade is the most important theoretical concept in International
Economics, the seemingly eternal battle between free trade and protection is its most
important policy theme.

Limits on imports and subsidizing exports are devices of protectionist policies.

International Economics analyzes the effects of these protectionist policies. And usually,
though not always, it criticizes protectionism and shows the advantages of freer international
trade. (These devices will be analyzed)




                                                                                                6
iv.      The Balance of Payments

Some countries run large ‘trade surpluses’ -that is, each sells more goods to the rest of the
world than it buys in return, like Japan.

On the other side, some countries run large ‘trade deficits’ -that is, each buy more goods from
the rest of the world than it sells, like Turkey.

What does it mean when a country runs a trade surplus or a trade deficit?

To make sense of numbers like the trade deficit, it is essential to place them in the broader
context of the whole of a nation’s international transactions.

The record of a country’s transactions with the rest of the world is called ‘the balance of
payments.’

Explaining the balance of payments and diagnosing its significance is a main theme of
international economics.

The balance of payments has become a central issue for Turkey because the nation has run
          huge trade deficits for a long time.


    v.       Exchange Rate Determination

In February 2001, a dollar was worth about 1500 Turkish Liras. During the following years a
dollar fell up to TL 1200, and this year fluctuated between 1300 and 1700. These changes
have many effects far beyond financial markets.

Exports, imports, industrial efficiency, foreign direct investments, saving behavior, etc are
affected by the value of Turkish Lira in terms of other currencies.

One of the key differences between International Economics and other areas of Economics
is that countries have different currencies.

Exchange rate can be fixed by government action (fixed Exchange rate regime) or can be
determined in the market place (floating Exchange rate regime)


For the time being, however, some of the world’s most important exchange rates fluctuate
minute by minute and the role of changing exchange rates remains at the center of the
international economics story.


                                                                                                7
vi.      International Policy Coordination

The international economy comprises of sovereign nations, each free to choose its own
economic policies.

Unfortunately, in an integrated world economy, one country’s economic policies usually
affect other countries as well.

            For example:

              When the United States imposed a tariff on imports of lumber during 1986, the
                Canadian Lumber Industry experienced a crisis.

              The FED’s interest rate policy is very important for the policy actions of other
                governments.

Therefore, differences in goals between countries often lead to conflicts of interest. Even
when countries have similar goals, they may suffer losses if they fail to coordinate their
policies.

While cooperation on international trade policies is a well-established tradition, coordination
of international macroeconomic policies is a newer and more uncertain topic.


    vii.     International Capital Market


The debt problems of developing countries (especially Latin Americans) during 1970s, 1980s
and 1990s brought the public attention to the growing importance of the international capital
market.

The growing importance of international trade has been accompanied by the growth in the
‘International Capital Market’ which links the capital markets of individual countries.

‘Some special risks’ are also associated with international capital markets; currency
fluctuations, national default...

    So, the growing importance of international capital markets and their new problems
demand greater attention than even before.




                                                                                                  8
1.2 International Economics: Trade and Money


The economics of international economy can be divided into two broad subfields.

   •   The study of International Trade
   •   The study of International Money



International trade analysis focuses primarily on the ‘real transactions’ in the international
economy (that is, physical movements of goods).

International monetary analysis focuses on the ‘monetary side’ of the international economy
(that is, on financial transactions such as foreign purchases of U.S. dollars on Turkish Lira)

In the real world, there is no simple dividing line between trade and monetary issues. Most
international trade involves monetary transactions, while many monetary events have
important consequences for trade.

Nonetheless, the distinction between international trade and international money is useful.


In accordance with this distinction we will,


   at first, study international trade theories and policies;
   secondly, we will study international monetary theory and policy issues.


Before starting the analysis of international trade theories, it might be useful to have a look at
the historical development of international trade theory as a whole (see Table 1).



1.3 Why is some knowledge of international economics required?

Because, first, it is necessary to understand what goes on in the world today and to be
informed consumers, citizens, and voters.

Second, on a more practical level, the study of international economics is required for
numerous jobs in multinational corporations, international banking, government agencies, and
international organizations.



                                                                                                 9
10
Table 1

                                           1.4 Historical Development of International Trade Theory

    Theory of Absolute               Theory of           Extension of             Factor            Some Theorems          Leontief Paradox         New Theories
       Advantage                    Comparative        Theory With New         Proportions         Depending on H-O
                                     Advantage            Concepts          Theory (Hecksher-           Model
                                                                               Ohlin Model)
-Adam Smith, ‘The Wealth         -David Ricardo        - Opportunity Cost   -Why does a            -Equalization of        -The results of       -Skilled Labor
of Nations’ (1776)               ‘On The Principals                         country have           international factor    Wassily Leontief’s    Hypothesis
                                 of Political          -International       comparative            prices                  Studies (1951) and
-Classical Liberalism            Economy and           relative prices      advantage?                                     others stimulated     -Technological Gap
    • Homoeconomicus             Taxation’(1817)       (Reciprocal                                 -Income Distribution    new theories.         Hypothesis
                                                       Demand               -Resources / Factor    Theorem of Stolper-     (He devised input-
    • Laissez faire                                                                                Samuelson
       laissez passer            -Even if a country    Curves/Offer         Endowments are                                 output analysis and   -Product Cycle
                                                                                                   (Free trade policy is
    • Invisible Hand             has advantage on      Curves)              emphasized.                                    tested H-O Theory)    Model
                                                                                                   in favor of abundant
                                 producing of the
                                                                                                   factor, but
-Advantages of                   two goods, trade      -Economic growth     Eli Hecksher,          protectionism is in                           -Similarity in
specialization and division      can be possible and   and foreign trade    Swedish, his article   favor of scarce                               Preferences
of labor are emphasized.         two sides can gain                         ‘The Effect of         factor.)                                      Hypothesis
                                 from trade.                                Foreign Trade on
-It is not adequate to explain                                              The Distribution of    -Rybczynski                                   -The Theorem of
the trade. But has               -The theory                                Income’(1919);         Theorem                                       Economies of Scale
importance for being the         depends mainly on                                                 (Under full
first attempt.                   the differences of                         Bertil Ohlin’s book,   employment                                    -The Theorem of
                                 labor productivity.                        ‘Inter-regional        conditions, if the                            Monopolistic
-Countries producing more                                                   Trade and              supply of one factor                          Competition
                                 -Has been                                  International          increases, the
efficiently should sell.
                                 developed with the                         Trade’(1933)           production of the
                                 contribution of new                                               good which uses that
-Trade would be                                                                                    factor increases, but
unilateral/one-sided             concepts.
                                                                                                   the production of
                                                                                                   other good
                                                                                                   decreases.)




                                                                                                                                                                   11
Chapter Two

                 THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE


2.1 Introduction

We will start with the simplest model and develop it with extentions and additions.

       The basic questions are:

       1) What is the ‘basis for trade?’
           A nation will voluntarily engage in trade if it benefits from trade.

       2) What are the ‘gains from trade’?
          But, how are gains from trade generated? And, how large are the gains and how
are they divided among the trading nations?

   We will see, successively:
    Mercantilism
    Adam Smith’s theory of ‘Absolute Advantage’
    David Ricardo’s theory of ‘Comparative Advantage’
    Gottfried Haberler’s ‘Opportunity Cost’ Theory, as a contribution to comparative
       advantages.

2.2 Mercantilism
   • During 17th and 18th centuries mercantilism was the popular economic philosophy.
   • Briefly, the mercantilists maintained that the way for a nation to become ‘rich’ and
   ‘powerful’ was to export more than it imported.
   • According to Mercantilists, the source of power and richness was to accumulate
   precious metals, primarily gold and silver.
   • For that reason, the government had to stimulate the nation’s exports and restrict
   imports.
   • Thus, the mercantilists preached ‘economic nationalism’.
   • But, since all nations could not simultaneously have an export surplus and the amount
   of gold and silver was fixed at any particular point in time, one nation could gain only at
   the expense of other nations.


                                                                                             12
• Consequently, trade was a ‘zero-sum game’: one part gains, but the other loses!


2.3 Trade Based on Absolute Advantage: Adam Smith


Economics as an organized science can be said to have originated with the publication in 1776
of ‘The Wealth of Nations’ by Adam Smith.

Smith started with the simple truth that for two nations to trade with each other ‘voluntarily’,
both nations ‘must gain’.

   And the questions:

   •   How does this ‘mutually beneficial trade’ take place? and
   •   From where do these ‘gains from trade’ come?


2.3a Absolute Advantage:

   •   According to Smith, trade between two nations is based on ‘absolute advantage’.
   •   According to the theory of absolute advantage, when one nation is more efficient than
       the other in the production of one commodity, it should specialize in producing this
       commodity and export the surplus over its need.
       In return, this nation can buy (import) the commodity which is the surplus of the other
nation’s production that is generated by the specialization of this nation.

       Thus,

       Two nations allocate their resources so as to produce most efficiently.

       And free trade would cause world resources to be utilized most efficiently and would
       maximize world welfare.

   •   This is the policy of ‘Laissez-faire’ (There were to be only a few exceptions to this
       policy of Laissez-faire and free trade; e.g. the protection of industries important for
       national defense.)




                                                                                                 13
2.3b Illustration of Absolute Advantage
                                  Table 2.1 one hour of labor time
                                                   U.S.                         U.K.

           Wheat (bushels*/man-hour)                    6                       1
           Cloth (yards**/man-hour)                     4                       5
         *bushel: a unit of measure, approximately 8 gallons (36lt); Kile
         **yard: 3 feets/36 inch; or 0.91 m (1 feet: 30.5cm, 1 inch: 2.54 cm)


   From the table, we can see that;

    One hour of labor time produces 6 units of wheat in the U.S., but only 1 unit of wheat
        in the U.K.
    On the other hand, one hour of labor time produces 5 units of cloth in the U.K., but
        only 4 units of cloth in the U.S.
    Thus, the U.S. has an absolute advantage over the U.K. in the production of wheat (or
        is more efficient than the U.K.)
       And, the U.K. has an absolute advantage over the U.S. in the production of cloth (or is
more efficient than the U.S.)

     With trade,

        the U.S. would specialize in the production of wheat, and exchange part of it for
        British cloth. The opposite is true for the U.K.


    Now, let’s assume that the U.S. gives up to produce cloth (C) and specializes in the
        production of wheat (W); producing for example 12 units of wheat.


    If the U.S. exchanges 6 units of W for 6 units of British C, then the U.S. gains 2 C.
       6 C (imported)- 4 C (domestically produced) = 2 C



       Similarly,
                     6 W ( the U.K. receives from the U.S.) = 6 man-hours for the U.K.
                           With 6 man-hours, the U.K. can produce 30 C (=6 man-hours x 5 C).
       So, the U.K. gains 24 C       (30 C- 6C=24 C)




                                                                                             14
 In this example, no matter how much more one nation (the U.K.) gained
                     than the other nation (the U.S.).


What is important is that ‘both’ nations can gain from specialization in production and
trade.


    However, in the example above, if the U.S. was efficient in the production of both
     wheat and cloth, the trade could not be possible because the U.K. could not gain from
     trade.

    Absolute advantage can explain only a very small part of world trade today, such as
     some of the trade between developed and developing countries.

It remained for David Ricardo to explain the basis for and the gains from trade: The Law of
Comparative Advantage.

2.4 Trade Based on Comparative Advantage: David Ricardo

Definition: According to the law of comparative advantage, even if one nation is less efficient
than the other nation in the production of ‘both’ commodities, there is still a basis for
mutually beneficial trade.

In other words, one nation may have an absolute disadvantage with respect to the other
nation, but they can gain from trade.

       Let’s look at the example given by Ricardo:

Table 2.2 Commodities produced with one labor-day
                      Cloth (meter)            Wine (liter)                                The U.K.
                                                                                           has an
 U.K.                    80                              40                                absolute
                                                                                           advantage
 Portugal                10                              20                                for C&W

       But, in cloth, U.K. Labor is 8 times productive; and in wine, U.K. labor is 2 times
productive.

       It is said that Portugal has a comparative advantage in wine and the U.K. has a
comparative advantage in cloth.

       In other words, the U.K.’s absolute advantage is greater in cloth, so the U.K. has a
comparative advantage in cloth.



                                                                                            15
The Gains from Trade:

Now look at the domestic prices. (Note that prices are relative in terms of other commodity:
terms of trade domestically)

        Domestic Prices in the U.K.: 1 unit of cloth= 1/2 units of wine (1C=1/2W)

        Domestic Prices in Portugal: 1 unit of cloth= 2 units of wine (1C=2W)

        Domestic Prices are different. The difference in domestic prices is a base for trade.

        (Assuming no transportation costs)



For example, say, current world price is as follows:

1 unit of cloth= 1 unit of wine (1C=1W)

        Then, how much do the trading nations gain?      = world price- domestic cost

        The U.K. gains ½ W.

Because 1C (Export) is exchanged for 1W (Import), then 1W- ½ W (domestic cost) = 1/2 W

        Portugal gains 1/2 C.

Because 1W (exports) is exchanged for 1C (imports); then 1C-1/2 C (domestic cost) = 1/2C



2.5 Critics of Ricardo’s Comparative Advantages

Of course, although Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage is a very challenging one with
practical applications, it is not perfect.


It has been criticized in some aspects:
     The theory considers only the labor productivity. Whereas, there are other resources
        used in production process such as capital, land, etc.

     The theory does not explain the difference in labor productivities.

     It assumes that labor is domestically mobile, but immobile between countries.

     It is a supply theory. Whereas, the demand side should be considered.


                                                                                                16
 It depends on constant costs and complete specialization. Whereas, increasing costs
       and incomplete specialization are more realistic in the world of today.

    It is a static model. It does not consider the changes over time. This criticism is
       especially important to developing countries.

    It does not take the production processes into consideration in the world of today.
       Trade between industrialized countries is mostly of intra-industry character (not only
       inter-industry). Intra-industry trade means the trade among similar industries.




2.6 Exception to the Law of Comparative Advantage

       There is one exception to the law of comparative advantage but not very common.
This occurs when the absolute disadvantage that one nation has with respect to another nation
is the ‘same’ in both commodities.

       For example, let us reorganize Table 2.2 as below:

Table 2.3 Commodities produced with one labor-day
                           Cloth (meter)         Wine (liter)
 U.K.                      80                    40
 Portugal                  10                    5



If, with one labor day, Portugal produced 5 units of wine, Portugal could be exactly one-eight
         as productive as the U.K. in both cloth and wine.


The U.K. and Portugal would then have a comparative advantage in either commodity, and
no mutually beneficial trade could take place.


       This requires slightly modifying the statement of the law of comparative advantage to
read as follows:




                                                                                           17
Even if one nation has an absolute disadvantage with respect to the other nation in the
  production of both commodities, there is still a basis for mutually beneficial trade, ‘unless
  the absolute disadvantage (that one nation has with respect to the other nation) is in the
  same proportion for the two commodities.’


  While it is important to note this exception in theory, its occurrence is rare and a matter of
  coincidence, so that the applicability of the law of comparative advantage is not much
  affected.


  Furthermore, natural ‘trade barriers’ such as transportation costs can preclude trade even
  when some comparative advantage exists.



  2.7 The Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantages
      (Gottfried Haberler)

  Ricardo based his law of comparative advantage on a number of assumptions:


                 1. Only two nations and two commodities,
                 2. Free trade,
These            3. Perfect mobility of labor within each nation but immobility between the two
assumptions         nations,
can easily
be relaxed!      4. Constant costs of production,
                 5. No transportation costs,
                 6. No technical change,

                 7. The labor theory of value. (But this assumption is not ‘valid’ and should not
                   be used for explaining comparative advantage)



  According to the Labor Theory of Value, the value or price of a commodity depends
  exclusively on the amount of labor going into the production of the commodity.


      This implies:
      1. that either labor is the only factor of production or labor is used in the ‘same’ fixed
          proportion in the production of all commodities.
      2. that labor is homogenous (i.e., of only one type)



                                                                                                    18
Since neither of these assumptions is true, we cannot base the explanation of comparative
advantage on the labor theory of value.


     It was left for Gottfried Haberler in 1936 to explain or base the theory of comparative
advantage on the ‘opportunity cost theory’. In this form, the law of comparative advantage is
sometimes referred to as ‘the law of comparative cost’.


     According to the opportunity cost theory, the cost of a commodity is the amount of a
second commodity that must be given up to release ‘just enough resources’ to produce one
additional unit of the first commodity. ‘Just enough resources’, here, imply some cost!


     In this case, we can write the costs of commodities in terms of national currencies, and
later convert them into relative commodity prices (Table 2.4)


Table 2.4 Domestic Prices (in terms of national currencies)
                              For 1 unit of
                              Steel*                        Wheat*
In Turkey                     10 TL                          1 TL
In the U.S.                   1$                             1$
*: It requires some resources of

          These costs can be stated as relative commodity prices as follows:

Opportunity
                  In Turkey: 1 unit of steel = 10 units of wheat
   cost
                                                                         domestically
                  In the U.S.: 1 unit of steel =1 unit of wheat



          In Turkey, WHEAT is cheap              Turkey specializes in WHEAT

          In U.S., STEEL is cheap                The U.S. specializes in STEEL

In this case they trade and gain from trade!

How do this trade and gains from trade occur? To understand the case, we first should recall
the production possibility frontier.




                                                                                          19
2.7a the Production Possibility Frontier under Constant Returns

(The following explanation is just that of Salvatore, page 44-48)

Definition: ‘The production possibility frontier’ is a curve that shows the alternative
combinations of the two commodities that a nation can produce by fully utilizing all of its
resources with the best technology available to it.

Table 2.5 Production Possibility Schedules for Wheat and Cloth in The U.S. and U.K.
United States                                                   United Kingdom
Wheat                                Cloth                      Wheat                    Cloth
180                                  0                          60                       0
150                                  20                         50                       20
120                                  40                         40                       40
90*                                  60*                        30**                     60**
60                                   80                         20                       80
30                                   100                        10                       100
0                                    120                        0                        120
*: (90, 60) represents Point A in the figure below.
**: (30, 60) represents Point A’ in the figure below.




From figure 2.1 and Table 2.5, we see that the United States should give up 30 units of wheat
Cloth Production




if it wants to increase 20 units of cloth (from 180 W to 150 W, from 0 C to 20 C, from 150 W
             Figure 2.1 Production Frontiers
to 120 W, from 20 Constant Returns
           under C to 40 C, etc.)

                                      U.S.
                     For the U.S., note that for every 20 C it requires 30 W to give up for the U.K. In other
                                                                                                U.S.
                                   1WW,2/3C
                     words, for each 1 = it requires 2/3 C to give up.
                                                                                                1W = 2C
                   120                                                                   120

     100                                                                  100
This means that “the cost of 1 unit of Wheat is 2/3 units of Cloth in the United States.”
                                                                                 Cloth




                    80                                                                    80

                     On                      A
                    60 the other hand, for the U.K., note that for every 40 C it requires 20 W to give up.
                                                                                      60

                                                                                          40
                                                                                                       A’
In the 40
       other words, for each 1 W it requires 2 C to give up.
                    20                                                                    20
This means that “the cost of 1 unit of wheat is 2 units of cloth in The United Kingdom.” (1 W
= 2 C)
                     0         30     60       90    120      150   180                    0     20   40    60
                     This case is called constant opportunity cost, because the cost of 1 W does not
                                           Wheat Production                                       Wheat

change “no matter from which point on its production possibility frontier the Nation

starts.”

                                                                                                                 20
Why do constant opportunity costs arise?

They arise when;

          (1) resources or factors of production are either
                   -   ‘perfect substitutes for each other’ or
                   -     ‘used in fixed proportion in the production of both
                       commodities’.
          (2) all units of the same factor are homogeneous or of exactly the same
              quality.




                                                                                    21
Figure 2.2 Graphical illustrations of the gains from trade under constant returns

        Cloth


 180
                         U.S.                             Cloth              U.K.




                                                      120         B’
 120


                                                      X
                                E
                         A
C2 70                                                             M
C1 60                                               C’2 50                     E’
                          M                         C’1 40
                                                                        A’
                                    X
                                             B
        0                90   110           180
                                                             0         40 60 70      120
                 W1 W2              Wheat
                                                                       W’1   W’2     Wheat




                                                                                      22
Now, to be noted is that by each nation specializing in the production of the commodity it
has comparative advantage the total production of world increases and also the two nations
end up consuming more than before trade (as shown in Table 2.5).




In the absence of trade,                                    In the absence of trade,
Production and consumption point is ;                       Production and consumption point is ;

Production      90W = 0W1     Production & Consumption      Production      40W’ = 0W’1    Production & Consumption
And                           of the nation depend on the   And                          of the nation depend on the
consumption     60C = 0C1    people’s tastes ,or demand     consumption     60C’1 = 0C’1    people’s tastes ,or demand
                              considerations                                              considerations
                            (The Nation chooses point A)                                 (The Nation chooses point A’)

If trade possible for 1 W = 1 C internationally             Similarly, if trade possible for 1W=1C
                                                            internationally
The U.S. might choose point E
( might want to exchange 70 W for 70 C ;                    The U.K. might choose point E`
chooses E )                                                        (might want to exchange 70 W for 70 C );
                                                                    Then,
Production      ; 180 W = 0B ; 0C
(no cloth production )                                      Production ; 120 C =0B`; 0W
                                                            (no wheat production)
Consumption ; 110 W = 0W2 >0W1
              (110 – 90 = 20 W )                            Consumption; 50C=0C2`>0C1` (50-40 = 10C)


Export          ; 70 W (180 – 110 )                         Export ; 120-50 =70C


Import = consumption of cloth;                              Import = consumption wheat;
          70C = 0C2>0C1 (70-60 =10C)                                  70W= 0W2`>0W1` (70-40=30W)


“With trade, The U.S. gained 20 W and 10 C”.                “With trade The U.K. gained 10C and 30W.”


EW2B is called ‘foreign trade triangle.’                    E`C2`B` is the foreign trade triangle of The U.K.
Vertical axis shows import,
Horizontal axis shows export,
                                                                                                              23
Hypotenuse shows “rate of exchange.” /
                        ‘relative prices’ /
                        ‘terms of trade’
Table 2.5 Increases in the World Production and Consumption after Trade
                World Production Before Trade               After Trade
             U.S          U.K         Total      U.S         U.K        Total
Wheat        90           40          130        180           0        180
Cloth        60           40          100          0         120        120

              World Consumption Before Trade                         After Trade
             U.S        U.K         Total              U.S           U.K         Total
Wheat        90         40          130                110           70          180
Cloth        60         40          100                70            50          120




2.8 Empirical Tests of the Ricardian Model


 → Various tests were conducted for the validity of Ricardian simple model.
    G.D.A. Mac Dougall (in1951, 1952), Bela Balassa (in 1963), R.M. Stern (in 1962), S.S.
    Golub (in1995), S.S. Golub and C.T. Hsieh (in 2000) studied the theory empirically.


 → The Ricardian trade model has to a large extent been empirically verified.


 → Despite this, it has a serious shortcoming in that it “assumes” rather than “explains”
    comparative advantage.


 → The model explains NEITHER the reason for the differences in labor productivity across
    nations NOR the effect of international trade on the earnings of factors.


 → By providing answers to both of these important questions, The Hecksher-Ohlin model
    theoretically improves upon Ricardian Model.




                                                                                            24
Chapter Three

              THE STANDARD THEORY of INTERNATIONAL TRADE


3.1 Introduction

    → By ‘The Standard Theory’ we mean the extension of the model with the more realistic
        case of ‘increasing opportunity costs.’

    → We consider ‘tastes or demand preferences’, represented by ‘community
        indifference curves’

    → So, together with production possibility curve (supply force) and community
        preferences (demand force), we will drive the equilibrium relative price in each nation
        in the absence of trade under increasing costs. (This will also indicate the commodity of
        comparative advantage for each nation)

    → Subsequently, we examine how, with trade, each nation gains by specializing in the
        production of the commodity of its comparative advantage.


    → Also, we’ll see a special case; how mutually beneficial trade is possible even when
        two nations are exactly alike except for tastes under increasing costs.

3.2 The Production Frontier with Increasing Costs
It is more realistic for a nation to face increasing rather than constant opportunity costs.

Increasing opportunity costs mean that the nation must give up more and more of one
commodity to release just enough resources to produce each additional unit of another
commodity.
                      Increasing opportunity costs result in a production frontier (production
Figure 3.1 a          possibility curve) that is concave from the origin (Figure 3.1a).
    Nation 1
    Y
                                               Nation 1 incurs increasing opportunity costs in the
              A                                production of both commodities.
     Y1
                      B
          Y2
                               C               For each additional unit of X commodity, Nation 1 must
                      Y3
                                       D
                                               give up more and more Y. ( Y1< Y2< Y3 )

                                           X                                                         25
    0     1       2        3       4
This is also valid when each additional unit of Y is increased.


                 Figure 3.1 b
      Y          Nation 2

                                        Nation 2 incurs increasing costs in the production of Y.
  5

  4         X3                          For each additional unit of Y commodity, Nation 2 must
  3                                     give up more and more X.
                  X2
                                        ( X1< X2< X3 )
  2                    X1

  1

  0                              X


3.2a The Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT)

      → The marginal rate of transformation of X for Y refers to the amount of Y that a nation
          must give up to produce each additional unit of X.

      → Thus, MRT is another name for the opportunity cost of X, and is given by the
          (absolute) slope of the production frontier at the point of production.


In Figure 3.1a, if the slope of the production frontier (MRT) of Nation 1 at point A is 1/4, this
means that Nation 1 must give up 1/4 of a unit of Y to release just enough resources to
produce one additional unit of X at this point.

Similarly, if the slope, or MRT, equals 1 at point B, this means that Nation 1 must give up one
unit of Y to produce one additional unit of X at this point.

      → Thus, a movement from point A down to point B along the production frontier of
          Nation1 involves an increase in the slope and reflects the increasing opportunity costs
          in producing more X.

      → In contrast, in the case of constant opportunity costs the MRT is constant, as seen in
        Figure 2.1.




                                                                                               26
3.2b Reasons for Increasing Opportunity Costs and Different Production
      Frontiers

   → How do increasing costs arise?

   → Why are they more realistic than constant opportunity costs?

Because;
           1) Resources or factors of production are not homogenous. That is, all units of the
               same factor are not identical or of the same equality (no perfect substitution)


           2) Resources or factors of production are not used in the same fixed proportion or
               intensity in the production of all commodities.

       This means that as the nation produces more of a commodity, it must utilize
resources that become progressively ‘less efficient’ or ‘less suited’ for the production of that
commodity.

       For instance, suppose some of a nation’s land is flat and suited for growing wheat, and
some is hilly and better suited for grazing and milk production. The nation originally
specialized in wheat but now wants to concentrate on producing milk. By transferring its hilly
areas from wheat growing to grazing, the nation gives up very little wheat and obtains a great
deal of milk. Thus, the opportunity cost of milk in terms of the amount of wheat given up is
initially small. But if this transfer process continues, eventually flat land, which is better
suited for wheat growing, will have to be used for grazing. As a result, the opportunity cost of
milk will rise and the production frontier will be concave from the origin.

       Note that the production frontiers of Nation 1 and Nation 2 in figure 3.1 have different
factor endowments and / or use different technologies in production.

       In the real world, the production frontiers of different nations will usually differ,
since practically no two nations have identical factor endowments (even if they could
have access to the same technology).




                                                                                                 27
3.2c Community Indifference Curves

So far, we have discussed production, or supply, considerations in a nation.

Now, we introduce the demand considerations (or tastes) in a nation. These are given by
community indifference curves (or social indifference curves).


Definition: ‘A community indifference curve shows the various combinations of two
commodities that yield equal satisfaction to the community or nation.’

        →      Higher curves refer to greater satisfaction, lower curves refer to less
               satisfaction.

        →      Community indifference curves are negatively sloped and convex from the
               origin.

        →      To be useful, they must not cross.

Illustration of Indifference Curves

 Figure 3.2a                                         Figure 3.2b




                                                                                          28
Y


                                                         T
                                                                 E
                                                     N           H               III
                                                             A              II
                                                                        I
                                                                                       X
                                                 0           Nation 1




        Y



                     H’ E’
                A’
                                      III’
                                II’
                     R’
                           I’
                                             X
    0           Nation 2


    Here, tastes (or demand preferences) are different in the two nations.

    Points N and A give equal satisfaction to Nation 1, since they are both on the same
    indifference curve (I).

    Points T and H refer to a higher level of satisfaction, since they are on a higher
    indifference curve (II).

    Even though T involves more of Y but less of X than A, satisfaction is greater at T
    because it is on Indifference Curve II.

    Point E refers to still greater satisfaction, since it is on indifference curve III.


                                                                                           29
Then, N=A<T=H<E;                  and for Nation 2, A`=R`<H`<E`


              → The community indifference curves are negatively sloped. It implies that if the
                nation wants to consume more of X, it must consume less of Y, remaining on
                the same level of satisfaction.

The Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)

          The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of X for Y in consumption refers to the
           amount of Y that a nation could give up for one extra unit of X and still remains on the
           same indifference curve.



          This is given by the (absolute) slope of the community indifference curve at the point
           of consumption and declines as the nation moves down the curve. Because, the
           marginal utility of commodity X decreses more and more as the commodity is used
           more and more.

   Figure 3.2 c

       Y
                                                   tan A> tan B means that the slope at point N is
                                                   higher than the slope at point A.

               N                                                        opposite        rise
                      A                        (Tangent is measured as ˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗ = ˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗ )
                                                                        adjacent       run

              tan A       tan B                (The position of an indifference curve represents
                                         X     for what commodity the society demands more.
                                               The slope represents the degree of substitution.)




          Declining MRS means that community indifference curves are convex from the
           origin.

          Thus, while increasing opportunity cost in production is reflected in concave
           production frontiers; a declining marginal rate of substitution in consumption is
           reflected in convex indifference curves.




                                                                                                   30
      This convexity property of indifference curves is necessary to reach a unique
          equilibrium consumption point for the nation




3.3 Equilibrium in Isolation with Increasing Costs (In a Closed Economy)


Figure 3.3 a                                                  Figure 3.3 b

      Y
                    Nation 1
                    Nation 1

                    A            I
                                 I
 60
                                           PA=1/4
                                           PA=1/4


                                             X
                 50              130         X
                 50              130

                 Y

                         PA’=4             Nation 2




               40                     A’


                                              I’
                                                    X
                                     80




             → Nation 1 is in equilibrium, or maximizes its welfare, in isolation by producing
                 and consuming at point A, where its production frontier reaches, or is tangent
                 to, indifference curve I (the highest possible).

                                                                                            31
→ Similarly, Nation 2 is in equilibrium at point A’, where its production frontier
                is tangent to indifference curve I’.

          → The equilibrium relative price of X in Nation 1 is given by the slope of the
                common tangent to its production frontier and indifference curve I at point A.

               This is PA=1/4 for Nation 1, PA’= 4 for Nation 2


    Since the relative price of X is lower in Nation 1 than in Nation 2, Nation 1 has a
       comparative advantage in commodity X, and Nation 2 has a comparative advantage
       in commodity Y.




3.4 The Basis For and the Gains from Trade with Increasing Costs

Now, suppose that the world (equilibrium) relative price is 1Y=1X

We know that, in Nation 1, 1/4 Y=1X

   → If Nation 1 can exchange 1X for more than 1/4 Y, it wants to specialize in X
     production.

   → But as long as Nation 1 specialize in X production, the opportunity cost of X will
     rise.

   → Nation 1 will specialize in X production up to the point where 1X is exchanged for
       1Y. This point is B in figure 3.4 a.



Figure 3.4 a




                                                                                             32
1) Point A
                                          Nation 1
                                                                                    represents
                                 Y
                                                                                    the


                                                    E
                            (80) Y3                     III
                                            A
                                                    I
                            Y1

                                                C                B
                            (20) Y2
                                                                     PB=1

                                            X1 X3          X2
                            0
                                             (70)        (130)




       equilibrium in isolation. In this case, Nation 1 consumes the amount of X and Y that
       it produces (that is, X1 and Y1).

    2) With trade, Nation 1 moves from point A to point B in production. By then
       exchanging 60X for 60Y with Nation 2, Nation 1 ends up consuming at point E (on
       indifference curve III). It represents a higher welfare level.

       (After trade, Nation 1 changed its production and consumption combinations.)
    3) The trade triangle is ECB.
X
    4) The key point here is that the specialization is incomplete. Nation 1 still produces the
       two goods, but it produces more commodity X (X2) than commodity Y (Y2). It
       consumes some X (X3), and sell the amount not used (X3- X2=CB); in return, it buys
       commodity Y (Y2-Y3=EC).

    Similarly, we can analyze the case of Nation 2, as illustrated in Figure 3.4 b.


    Figure 3.4 b
                     Nation 2




                                                                                            33
Y                                                         1) A’ is the
                                                                                    point where
                                                                                    production
                                      B'                                            and
                                                                                    consumption
                                                                                    of Nation 2
                                                                                    are        in
                                 C'
                                                                                    isolation.
                                                        E'
                                                              III'
                                              A'
                                                                                 2) With trade,
                                                             PB=1
                                                   I'                               production
                           120
                                                                                    moves from
                                                                     X              point A’ to
                                  X2        X1   X3                                 point B’.
                                 (40)      (80) (100)
                           60                                                    3) Consumptio
                           Y1
                           0                                                        n      moves
                                                                                    from point
                                                                                    A’ to point
                                                                                    E’,    which
                                                                                    represents a
                                                                                    higher
   welfare level.

4) The trade triangle is C’E’B’.

5) B’C’ is the export of Nation 2.

6) C’E’ is the import of Nation 2,

7) The hypotenuse of the trade triangle
                                                     (B’E’) represents the world relative
                                                    commodity price.

8) PB is the ‘equilibrium-relative commodity price with trade’.

9) Also note that specialization is ‘incomplete’.

    As the result of these analyses, these two nations want to trade at an equilibrium-
     relative commodity world price that is higher than domestic relative commodity
     prices of these two nations.




                                                                                              34
3.5 The Gains from Exchange and From Specialization

Figure 3.5
                  Nation 1
       A nation’s gains from trade can be broken into two                 components:


                 Y3                      E

                              T                   U10
                 Y2
                                          U7
                 Y1           C A            U5

                                                                 PD=1/4
                                                             B
                 Y4                  F        P*W=1
                                                             PW=1

                 0             X2 X1 X3                 X4




                              1) The gains from ‘exchange’, and
            2) The gains from ‘specialization’.

This breakdown is illustrated in Figure 3.5.

From A to T (Gains from exchange)
From A to E (Gains from specialization)



           → Suppose that, for whatever reason, Nation 1 could not specialize in the
             production of X with the opening of trade but continued to produce at point A.

       - Point A shows both producing and consuming combinations (in isolation)
       - Pd (=1/4) is the relative domestic price.

           → Let us assume that Pw (=1) represents the world relative price.
             Accordingly, Pw* also represents the world relative price.

           → Because Pw (=Pw*=1) is higher than PD (=1/4), Nation 1 can produce at PD and
             sell at Pw.

       That is, Nation 1 can exchange X 2X1 (CA) amount of X for Y1Y2 (CT) amount of Y.
       (Note that preferences do not change, therefore T is the new consuming point)


                                                                                        35
∆ TCA is the trade triangle in the case of without specialization.

    Now, after trade, Nation 1 reduced consumption of X, but increased
     consumption of Y.

      Even though Nation 1 consumes less of X and more of Y at point T in relation to point
      A, ‘it is better off than it was autarchy because T is on higher indifference curve
      U7’.

      The movement from point A to point T in consumption measures the gains from
      exchange.

   → If subsequently Nation 1 also specialized in production of X and produced at Point
   B (at the prevailing relative world price Pw (=1)), then it could exchange X3X4 amount of
   X for Y4Y3 amount of Y and ends up in consuming at point E on indifference curve U 10
   which represents a higher consumption combination (a higher welfare level).

   → Production and consumption points in the case of specialization:

                     B: equilibrium production point.
                     E: equilibrium consumption point.

                 Nation 1 produces X4 units of X,
                         consumes X3 units of X, (X3>X1)
                         exports X3X4 amount of X,
                         imports Y4Y3 amount of Y in exchange of X3X4.
                          Total consumption of Y is OY3, which is the sum of OY4 (its own
                                                  production) and Y3Y4 (its import).

   → Recall that EFB is the trade triangle in the case of specialization.
The movement from T to E in consumption measures ‘the gains from specialization in
production.’


3.6 Trade Based on Differences in Tastes



    Figure 3.6




                                                                                         36
Nation 1 and Nation 2 have identical production frontiers (shown by a single curve)



                               Y
                                       E
                                                    U8
                                               U5               PA = 1/4
                                   A
                                   IMA

                         Y'2                                      B’
                                           C    EXA       B                PA’= 4
                                                                                               PW = 1
                                                         EXA’
                                                                   IMA’             E’
                                                          C’
                                                                                         U’8
                         Y'1                                              A’
                                                                                 U’5
                                                                                         X
                           0                                X'2            X'1




            In the analysis before (in Figure 3.4 a and Figure 3.4 b), we supposed that the
              ‘difference in pretrade relative commodity prices’ was based on the
              ‘differences in the production frontiers and indifference curves’ in two
              nations.

            Whereas, even if two nations have identical production possibility frontiers,
              there will still be a basis for mutually beneficial trade if tastes (i.e. demand
              preferences) in two nations differ.



            The nation with the relatively smaller demand (or preference for a commodity)
              will have a lower relative price for that commodity.




                                                                                                        37
 The process of specialization in production and trade would then follow, as
              described in previous cases (for previous cases see pages 28/ Figure 3.4a and
              29/ Figure 3.4b).



           In figure 3.6, the two nations have the same production possibility curve (DD).


                     → A is the point where Nation 1 is in equilibrium in autarky.
                     → PA represents the autarky price of Nation 1.
                     → In this case, Nation 1 has a comparative advantage in commodity X.
On the other hand,
                 → A’ is the point where Nation 2 is in equilibrium in autarky.
                 → PA’ represents the autarky price of Nation 2.
                 → In this case, Nation 2 has a comparative advantage in commodity Y.


           Note that the two nations have different relative domestic (autarky) prices
              because of different tastes (demand preferences) even though they have the
              same production possibility frontier.

           PW is the world relative commodity price, which is higher than PA (when the
              price of X is measured in terms of Y) and higher than PA’ (when the price of
              Y is measured in terms of X).

           Now, there is a basis for mutually beneficial trade between the two nations at
            world price PW.

           With trade, Nation 1 will move from A to B in production and it will move
            from A to E for consumption.

                      → Nation 1 will consume more X and more Y than the pretrade case (it
                        will export EXA’ amount of X commodity, and import IMA’ amount of
                        Y commodity).

           Also with trade, Nation 2 will move from A’ to B’ in production and it will
            move from A’ to E’ for consumption.




                                                                                         38
→ Nation 2 will consume more Y and more X than the pretrade (it will export
                 EXA amount of Y commodity, import IMA amount of X commodity).



Consequently, mutually beneficial trade became possible though the same production
frontiers, depending on the difference in tastes.




                                       Chapter Four

OFFER CURVES, DEMAND and SUPPLY (Reciprocal Demands), and
                   the TERMS OF TRADE

4.1 Introduction

   •   So far, while analyzing trade between two countries we have assumed a hypothetical
       relative equilibrium (world) price which is higher than domestic relative commodity
       prices.

   •   Then, the question is that how this equilibrium-relative commodity price (P W) is
       determined.

   •   We will make use of ‘offer curves’ (sometimes referred to as ‘reciprocal demand
       curves’).

   •   Offer curves (or reciprocal demand curves) were devised and introduced into
       international economics by Alfred Marshall and Ysidro Edgeword, two British
       economists. Offer curves have been used extensively in international economics,
       especially for pedagogical purposes.

   •   The offer curve of a nation shows how much of its import commodity the nation
       demands for it to be willing to supply various amounts of its export commodity.

       (In other words, how much of its export commodity Nation 1 offers for 1 unit of
       import commodity of Nation 2).

   •   As the definitions indicate, offer curves incorporate elements of both demand and
       supply.

   •   Alternatively, we can say that the offer curve of a nation shows the nation’s
       willingness to import and export at various relative commodity prices.



                                                                                       39
4.2 Illustration of Offer Curves

        •           Suppose that U.S. and Turkey will trade. U.S. has a comparative advantage in machine
                    (M), Turkey has a comparative advantage in wheat (W)
                               → In Turkey; 1W=1/2M
                               → In U.S.            ; 1W=2M (or 1/2W=1M)



Figure 4.1
          Machine




                                                                                            •   Considering Figure 4.1, Turkey
                                                                                                would be neutral if the world price
                              U.S’s relative                                                    was equal to Turkey’s domestic
                              commodity price
                                                                                                price.
                                            PUS
              5                                         Area for mutually
                                                        benefical trade                         But, if Turkey can exchange 1W
              4                                                                                 for more than 1/2M, it wants to
                                                                               PT
              3                                                                                 trade.
                              B                               Turkey’s relative
              2                                               commodity price (Domestic     •   Similarly, the U.S. would be neutral
                                                              price )
              1                                                                                 if the world price was equal to its
              1/2
                                  A                                                             domestic price.
               0               1        2   3       4        5       6   Wheat

                                                                                                But if U.S. can Exchange 1M for
                                                                                          more than 1/2W, it wants to trade.

•         Then, the area between lines showing domestic relative prices of Turkey and U.S. takes
          place for mutually beneficial trade.

                                                                                                      •   Depending on figure 4.2,
                                                                                                          we derive the offer curve
                                                        D (10M=5W)                                        of Turkey.

                                                                  C (10M=10W)
                                                                                                           Figure 4.2

    4          Machine                                                   B (10M=15W)
                                                         C

                                                                     A (10M=20W)
    2                                       B                          (1/2M=1W)


    1                                                                                                                             40
    1/2
                              A
                    0,5   1       1.5   2       3       4        5          Wheat
(The offer curve of Turkey bulges toward X axis).




    According to figure 4.2, Turkey is neutral to trade up to point A, because point A is on
     its domestic (relative) price.

    But, for example, at point B, which is on the world relative commodity price of B,
     Turkey wants to exchange 3W for 2M.

             → That is, Turkey offers (or exports/supplies) 3 units of wheat and demands (or
               imports) 2 units of machine in return.
               At point C, which is on the world relative-commodity price of C, Turkey wants
               to Exchange 4W for 4M

             → That is, for Turkey to import 2 more units of machine it offers less amount of
               wheat.

             → As Turkey consumes more and more units of machine, for one additional unit
               of machine it offers less amount of wheat (because of diminishing marginal
               utility law).

             → If we joint the points A, B, C, D from the origin, we obtain the offer curve of
               Turkey.

     Following the same method, the U.S.’s offer curve can be derived (This is left for the
      students).



        Let us suppose that the offer curve of U.S. is as follows.

Figure 4.3
                       D (10M=5W)
  Machine
                                    C(10M=10W)

    4
                                      B(10M=15W)
    3                                                    The offer curve of U.S. bulges toward
                                                         Y axis.
    2

    1
                                                                                           41
    0        1    2    3   4     Wheat
 The world equilibrium relative commodity price is determined at the point where the
      offer curves of the two nations intersect.




      Figure 4.4

         Machine
                              Turkey   Pw

   (M) 4                                    US
                                   E




                                                                Keep in mind that prices
         1                                                      are    relative-commodity
                                                                prices
                                            Wheat
        0         1               4
                                 (L)




                                                                   → At price PW, Turkey
                                                                     exports 4 units of
                                                                     wheat (OL)
      At price PW, Turkey imports 4 units of machine (EL)

 → At the same price, U.S. exports 4 units of machine (OM=EL)
   At the same price, U.S. imports 4 units of wheat (EM=OL)



     The hypotenuse
   represents the world
                          OLE is the Turkey’s trade triangle
          price              OME is the U.S.’s trade triangle
(Equilibrium relative
 commodity price)



                                                                                      42
 How does the equilibrium relative commodity price change?

             → For various reasons, when the offer curves of the nations shift, the
               equilibrium price changes.

             → The variables which cause supply and demand curves to shift cause the offer
               curves to shift as well.

(Recall that consumer’s income, the price of related goods, tastes, expectations, technology,
and input prices cause the forces of demand and supply to shift).




Figure 4.5 Illustration of a change in equilibrium world price)


                                    T’
       Machine           T                                      •   Let Turkey demands more
                                    P’
                                          US                        of U.S. import good.
                             P

                                                                •   The offer curve of Turkey
                                                                    shifts to the right.

                                                                •   The world price rises from
                                            Wheat                   OP to OP’ (If the United
                                                                    States does not change its
           demand preference).

                    •   The world price changes; it moves toward the relative price of Turkey.


     How does the welfare effect of this change take place?

                 → The welfare effect takes place with the comparison of two opposite
                   changes:

                             The first is the change in the terms of trade ( P)
                             The second is the change in trade volume ( TV)

                                                                                                43
Figure 4.6
          Machine
                            T                                    If   TV> P , the welfare effect is (+)
                                   P’                            If   TV< P, the welfare effect is (-)
                                            A
                        P
                                                                 OPL is the trade voşume in the first case.
0    L                                                           OP’L’ is the trade volume in the second case.
L’



            0            L             L’ Wheat




         4.3 A Special Case: The Importance of Being Unimportant

         Let’s take two nations. The first is large (U.S.), and the second is small (Luxembourg).

            → The U.S.’s offer curve bulges more toward Y axis because its demand for the good
              (say, butter) of Luxembourg is high.

                On the other hand, Luxembourg’s offer curve bulges less toward X axis because its
                demand for the good (say, engine) of U.S. is small.



         Figure 4.7

                Engine             L
                                                    A
                            Pus
                                        P       U.S.’s gains from
                                                trade


                                                  Luxembourg’s
                                                  gains from trade


                    O
                                                    Butter

                       OPUS = The U.S.’s domestic price
                        OP = World relative price

                                                                                                          44
OA = the U.S.’s offer curve
              OL = Luxembourg’s offer curve

           The area between OA and OP represents the U.S.’s gains from trade.

           The area between OL and OP represents the Luxembourg’s gains from trade.

           Because the world price is very high from Luxembourg’s domestic price,
            Luxembourg gains more from trade than U.S.

           This case is called the importance of being unimportant (Marshall’s
            contribution to the theory of trade).




                                     Chapter Four

    FACTOR ENDOWMENTS and the HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY



    5.1 Introduction

• We have seen in previous chapters that the difference in relative commodity prices
   between two nations is evidence of their comparative advantage and forms the basis
   for mutually beneficial trade.

•      We now go one step further and explain the reason, or cause for the difference in
      relative commodity prices and comparative advantage between the two nations.

•      According to classical economists (Smith, Ricardo, Mill), comparative advantage was
       based on the difference in the productivity of labor among nations,
      but they provided no explanation for such a difference in productivity.

•       The Heckscher-Ohlin theory extends the trade theory and examines the basis for
      comparative advantage.

•     The H-O theory is based on the following assumptions (see Salvatore, pp.123-124):


                                                                                          45
1. There are two nations, two commodities, and two factors of production (labor and
            capital). Considering more than two nations, more than two commodities, and more
            than two factors will leave the conclusions of the theory basically unchanged.
        2. Both nations use the same technology in production.
        3. Commodity X is labor intensive and commodity Y is capital intensive in both nations.
        4. Both commodities are produced under constant returns to scale in both nations.
        5. There is incomplete specialization in production in both countries.
        6. Tastes are equal in both nations.
        7. There is perfect competition in both commodities and factor markets in both nations.
        8. There is perfect factor mobility within each nation but no international factor
            mobility.
        9. There are no transportation costs, tariffs, or other obstructions to the free flow of
            international trade.
        10. All recourses are fully employed in both nations.
        11. International trade between the two nations is balanced.

•       The main idea of the H-O is that;

        “Each nation has comparative advantage in the commodity that it can produce in
        accordance with its factor intensity.”

    5.2 Illustration of the H-O Theory

•          According to the Figure 5.1., the U.S. has a comparative advantage in machine
        because machine is a capital intensive good and the U.S. has more capital than labor.
        So, capital is the cheap factor with respect to labor in the U.S.

        Figure 5.1 a                                            Figure 5.1 b

                                                             Machine (Y)
    Machine (Y)
                       Before Trade                                PW              After Trade
    A

                                                                    A’
                                                                   EXUS
                        A
                                                                                        E
    T                                                                       IMUS
                                  T                                                                           U10
                                           U5
                                                                                       IMT
                                                PT
                                      PA
                                                                                                         T’
                                                                                             EXT


    0                         A                 T    Wheat                                             Wheat (X)
                                                      (X)                                          (


                                                                                                       46
• On the other hand, Turkey has a comparative advantage in wheat because wheat is a labor
       intensive good and Turkey has more labor than capital.
       So, labor is the cheap factor with respect to capital in Turkey.

 •       In this case, according to the H-O theory, the U.S. will specialize in the machine
       production and export machine but import wheat. On the other hand, Turkey will
       specialize in wheat production and export wheat but import capital.
 • The analysis is very similar as we did for the cases in this chapter. It is left for you!
       (Proceed the analysis)

 •      In sum, according to H-O theory, “a nation will export the commodity whose
       production requires the intensive use of the nation’s relatively abundant and
       cheap factor and import the commodity whose production requires the intensive
       use of the nation’s relatively scarce and expensive factor.”




5.3 Corollaries of the H-O Theory

Depending on the H-O Theory, various theorems have been developed. We will examine
them briefly in the following.

 1.   The factor-price equalization theorem

 → Paul Samuelson (1976 Nobel Prize in economics) rigorously proved the factor-price
      equalization theorem, which is really a corollary since it follows directly from the H-O
      theory.

 → For this reason, it is sometimes referred to as the Hecksher-Ohlin-Samouelson theorem
       (H-O-S theorem, for short)

 → According to the H-O-S theorem, “International trade will bring about equalization in
      the relative and absolute returns to homogenous factors across nations.”




                                                                                           47
 What this means is that international trade will cause the wages of
      homogenous labor to be same in all trading nations.


            Similarly, international trade will cause the return to homogenous capital
      (i.e. capital of the same productivity and risk) to be the same in all trading nations.


            In this respect, it brings about the same results of international factor mobility.


→ How this process works?

→ Turkey has abundant labor; therefore, the price of labor is relatively cheap.            With
       the opening of trade, as it specializes in wheat production, the demand for labor will
       increase.
       
      The price of labor (wage) will tend to rise.

→ The U.S.A. has abundant capital factor. For this reason, the price of capital (i.e., interest
      rate) is relatively cheap.
       
      With the opening of trade, as it specializes in machine production, the demand for
      capital will increase in the U.S.
       
      The price of capital (interests) will tend to rise.

→     As a result of the movements of factors, the wages in Turkey will tend to be equal to
      the wages in the U.S. and the interest rates in the U.S. will tend to be equal to the
      rates in Turkey.

→     The best example of this theorem is the real hourly wages in manufacturing in leading
      Industrial Countries as a percentage of the U.S. wage (see p. 144 of your textbook,
      Salvatore, Table 5.6 in the 9th edition).

→    Depending on H-O-S theorem, it is expected that, with the increasing of factor mobility
      and trade in European Union, the wages will rise and the interest rates will fall in the
      developing nations who will be integrated with the European Union.


                                                                                              48
2. Stolper- Samuelson Theorem of Income Distribution

         This theorem is the corollary of the H-O-S theorem.

      → According to this theorem, free trade will raise the real income of the factor that is
           abundant in the nation, and reduce the real income of the factor that is scarce in
the
        nation.


      → The protectionist policies of the European Union for the agricultural sector can be
         explained by this theorem.

      3. The Rybczynski Theorem

         This theorem postulates that at constant commodity prices, an increase in the
endowment of one factor will increase by a greater proportion the output of the commodity
which is intensive in that factor and will reduce the output of the other commodity.




         Figure 5.2

                         Machine
                                       Pw=1
                               Pw=1




                        M1                  A

                         M2                                    A’

                                                                             Wheat
                           0               W1 W2



 → The nation experienced economic growth with the increase in the endowment of labor.

                                                                                                 49
→ The world relative price remained the same.

 → The output of the commodity (wheat) which is labor-intensive increased by a greater
     proportion.

 → The Output of the other good decreased.



5.4 Empirical Tests of the Heckscher-Ohlin Model

 →The first empirical test of the H-O model was conducted by Wassily Leontief in 1951
      using U.S. data for the year 1947.

 →Since the U.S was the most capital-abundant nation in the world, Leontief expected to
      find that it exported capital-intensive commodities and imported labor-intensive
      commodities.

 →According to the results, the United States seemed to export labor intensive commodities
      and import capital intensive commodities.

         This was the opposite of what the H-O Model predicted and became known as the
        “Leontief Paradox”.

 →      Hereupon, some explanations were made for this paradox.

 →      Many empirical studies were conducted with data from other countries.

 →      But, the empirical studies give conflicting results.


                  ∴ In consequent, such an explanation has been made:

                     The H-O Model is adequate for the explanation of the trade
                     between the developed and developing nations but not enough to
                     explain the trade between industrial nations.

                  ∴ New theories have been developed...


5.5 The New Trade Theories

 →Heckscher and Ohlin based comparative advantage on the difference in factor
        endowments (labor & capital) among nations. This theory, however, leaves a great

                                                                                       50
deal of today’s international trade unexplained. Because trade among 200 nations
       and trade of thousands of goods are difficult to explain with one model.

→To fill this gap, after 1960s, new international trade theories have been developed.

→In fact, some of these new theories try to explain the source of comparative advantage
       and the difference between factor endowments.

       The new theories are explained briefly in the following.

       1. Skilled Labor Hypothesis:

         The skilled labor-intensive goods are almost the same as capital-intensive
            goods. In general, these two kinds of goods are treated together as “man-
            made”.

         This revision of H-O Model is called “New-factor Endowment Theory”.

         Empirical studies show that the developed nations having skilled labor export
            industrial goods and the developing nations having unskilled labor and
            abundant land export primary agricultural goods.




       2. Technological Gap Model

         According to this model, a great deal of the trade among industrialized
          countries is based on the introduction of new products and new production
          processes.

         These give the innovating firm or nation a “temporary” monopoly in the world
             market. Protected by laws such as patents and copyrights.

         In time, the new technology becomes widespread. The exporting nation
             becomes importing one and vice-versa.

         The industries of textile, electronic equipment, chemistry, steel and iron and
             cement are typical examples.




                                                                                        51
 The model is tested for various countries. According to the empirical results,
     there is a high correlation between the net exports of industries and their
     research and development investments.

  For instance, more than 50 percent of R& D personnel in the world work in the
     United States. This fact can be interpreted that the United States has
     comparative advantages especially in high-tech products.

3. Product Cycle Model

 This model is a generalization and extension of the technological gap model.

 The process is from the innovating to imitating nation:

  Step 1:     Innovation and to meet the domestic consumption.

   Step 2:      The product matures. The amount of production becomes greater than
             the domestic consumption. The nation exports.

    Step 3: * Gradually, the technology and the product become standardized. The
                innovative firm starts to give licenses to the firms of other nations.

               * The production becomes more advantageous in previously importing
              countries with the contribution of other factors.

             * The production in the innovating nation starts to decrease.

   Step 4: * Anyway, the technology and production methods are fully
                  standardized and the legal limitations such as patents and copyrights
               are removed.

                * The innovating nation is eventually in the position of an importing
               nation.

             * The product cycle is completed.

             And the innovating nation, in the meantime, is up to new products.

            In the world of today, the time period of product cycles becomes
             considerably shorten. This fact implies that the innovating nations such


                                                                                         52
as U.S. and Japan have to provide technological improvements to keep
        their competitiveness. As a matter fact, they do so!

4) Preference Similarity Hypothesis

 This hypothesis, different from others, views the demand side of the
    international trade.

 Therefore, it is also named “overlapping demands” hypothesis.

 According to this model, a nation exports those manufactured products for
    which a large domestic market exists.

 These are products that appeal to the majority of the population.

 In the process of satisfying such a market, the nation acquires the necessary
    experience and efficiency to be able subsequently to export these commodities
    to other nations with similar tastes and income levels.

 On the other hand, the nation will import those products that appeal to its low-
    and high-income minorities.

 According to this hypothesis, trade in manufactures is likely to be largest
    among countries with similar tastes and income levels.

 While confirmed for Sweden, this hypothesis has not been confirmed for other
    nations. It cannot explain the goods that a nation produces only for exports.
    For example, why such non-Christian nations as Japan and Korea export
    artificial christmas trees and christmas cards in the absence of a domestic
    market for these products?

5) Economies of Scale and Monopolistic Competition

 These two theories are related to one another.

    The factor endowment theory (H-O Model) makes explanations under
    “constant returns to scale”.




                                                                                53
“Constant returns to scale” refers to the production situation where output
            grows at the same rate with the increase in inputs or factors of production.
            That is, if all inputs are doubled, output is doubled.

         On the other hand, “increasing returns to scale” refers to the situation where
            output grows proportionately more than the increase in intputs or factors of
            production. That is, if all inputs are doubled, output is more than doubled.



         Increasing returns to scale may occur because at a larger scale of operation a
            greater division of labor and specialization becomes possible.

         Therefore, even if two nations are identical in every respect, there is still a
            basis for mutually beneficial trade based on economies of scale.

         Because of “external” and “internal” economies, nations specialize in
            different goods in the same industry. Thus, trade in the same industry becomes
            possible. This is called “intra-industry trade”.

         In addition, the economies of scale stimulate the “differentiated products”
            under the situation of monopolistic competition. The consumers are presented
            a wide range of differentiated products of the same good.

         The automobile industry is the best example of economies of scale,
            differentiated products and intra-industry trade.

         The importance of intra-industry trade became apparent when tariffs and other
            obstructions to the flow of trade among members of the European Union were
            removed in 1958.

         The study made by B. Balassa (in 1967) showed that “The trade volume
            increased very speed among member nations of the E.U., but most of this
            trade was different goods within the same industries.



5.6 Synthesis of Trade Theories


                                                                                           54
The overall conclusions that we can reach regarding the empirical relevance of the trade
theories examined thus far are:

         (1) Most of the trade between developed and developing countries are “inter-
industry trade” based on differences in factor endowments, as postulated by Heckscher-
Ohlin.

         (2)   An increasing proportion of the trade among industrialized countries is
“intra-industry trade” based on economies of scale in differentiated products, as
postulated by the new trade theories.




5.7 Transportation Costs and International Trade

   → So far we have assumed that costs of transportation are zero. We can relax this
         assumption.
   → Costs of transportation affect international trade directly by affecting the price of the
         traded commodity in the exporting and importing countries.
   → Furthermore, costs of transportation affect international trade indirectly by affecting
         the international location of production and industry.
   → Costs of transportation include
          •    Freight charges
          •    Warehouse costs
          •    Costs of loading and unloading
          •    Insurance premiums
          •    Interest charges while goods are in transit


          In sum, the term transport or logistics costs include all the costs of transferring
          goods from one location (country) to another.


               → Logistic costs are affected by the country’s geography, the quality of its
                  infrastructures, and the management techniques of the firms.




                                                                                                55
Int Econ Star
Int Econ Star
Int Econ Star
Int Econ Star
Int Econ Star
Int Econ Star
Int Econ Star

More Related Content

What's hot

international trade presentation
international trade presentationinternational trade presentation
international trade presentationkote abashidze
 
International trade
International tradeInternational trade
International tradeIRFAN BASHIR
 
Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)
Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)
Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)Albina Gaisina
 
International economic ch01
International economic ch01International economic ch01
International economic ch01Judianto Nugroho
 
International Economic Theories
International Economic TheoriesInternational Economic Theories
International Economic Theoriesfathima habeeb
 
20130126 international economics chap1 introduction
20130126 international economics chap1 introduction20130126 international economics chap1 introduction
20130126 international economics chap1 introductionFED事務局
 
TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE
TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADETRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE
TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADESundar B N
 
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fallEcon452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fallsakanor
 
INTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIES
INTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIESINTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIES
INTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIESJAIMOLTHOMAS1
 
Role of trade in development
Role of trade in developmentRole of trade in development
Role of trade in developmentNISHANT KUMAR
 
Lecture 1 introduction to international trade
Lecture 1 introduction to international tradeLecture 1 introduction to international trade
Lecture 1 introduction to international tradettbhavanecon
 
International business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTU
International business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTUInternational business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTU
International business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTUKartikeya Singh
 
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2Pimsat University
 
International Business Environment
International Business EnvironmentInternational Business Environment
International Business Environmentitsvineeth209
 
International trade theories
International trade theoriesInternational trade theories
International trade theoriesvipin25
 
Global interdependence - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt
Global interdependence  - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt Global interdependence  - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt
Global interdependence - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt nazeema khan
 

What's hot (20)

international trade presentation
international trade presentationinternational trade presentation
international trade presentation
 
International trade
International tradeInternational trade
International trade
 
Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)
Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)
Meeting 1 - Introduction to international economics (International Economics)
 
International economic ch01
International economic ch01International economic ch01
International economic ch01
 
International trade
International tradeInternational trade
International trade
 
International Economic Theories
International Economic TheoriesInternational Economic Theories
International Economic Theories
 
20130126 international economics chap1 introduction
20130126 international economics chap1 introduction20130126 international economics chap1 introduction
20130126 international economics chap1 introduction
 
TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE
TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADETRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE
TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE
 
Global trading
Global tradingGlobal trading
Global trading
 
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fallEcon452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 2 - 2020 fall
 
INTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIES
INTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIESINTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIES
INTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW THEORIES
 
Role of trade in development
Role of trade in developmentRole of trade in development
Role of trade in development
 
Introduction of international trade
Introduction of international tradeIntroduction of international trade
Introduction of international trade
 
Lecture 1 introduction to international trade
Lecture 1 introduction to international tradeLecture 1 introduction to international trade
Lecture 1 introduction to international trade
 
International business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTU
International business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTUInternational business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTU
International business environment MB-IB-01-MBA-IIIrd SEM-UPTU
 
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS Chapter 2
 
International Economics
International EconomicsInternational Economics
International Economics
 
International Business Environment
International Business EnvironmentInternational Business Environment
International Business Environment
 
International trade theories
International trade theoriesInternational trade theories
International trade theories
 
Global interdependence - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt
Global interdependence  - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt Global interdependence  - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt
Global interdependence - A level Human Geography - Trade and Debt
 

Viewers also liked (7)

International marketing of Agri-products
International marketing of Agri-productsInternational marketing of Agri-products
International marketing of Agri-products
 
International trade theory
International trade theoryInternational trade theory
International trade theory
 
Trade theory
Trade theoryTrade theory
Trade theory
 
Lecture 4
Lecture 4Lecture 4
Lecture 4
 
Economics 1.216181522
Economics 1.216181522Economics 1.216181522
Economics 1.216181522
 
International Economics: Introduction
International Economics: IntroductionInternational Economics: Introduction
International Economics: Introduction
 
International business: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
International business: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADEInternational business: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
International business: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
 

Similar to Int Econ Star

Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01
Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01
Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01Osama_albashier
 
What Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdf
What Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdfWhat Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdf
What Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdfAiblogtech
 
Financial management
Financial managementFinancial management
Financial managementSunday Olwor
 
Multinational Finance Solutions
Multinational Finance SolutionsMultinational Finance Solutions
Multinational Finance SolutionsBrandonn123
 
604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02
604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02
604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02Hatim100
 
Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...
Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...
Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...Angela Williams
 
A Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business Management
A Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business ManagementA Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business Management
A Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business ManagementYasmin AbdelAziz
 
Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfection
 Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfection Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfection
Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfectionLily Scott
 
International finance1 1
International finance1 1International finance1 1
International finance1 1AaryanAJirde
 
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fallEcon452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fallsakanor
 
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1sakanor
 
Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All
Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All
Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All EstelaJeffery653
 

Similar to Int Econ Star (20)

Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01
Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01
Chap1scopeofintleconomics 110908013834-phpapp01
 
I.E week 1.pptx
I.E week 1.pptxI.E week 1.pptx
I.E week 1.pptx
 
What Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdf
What Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdfWhat Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdf
What Is Global Economy and Its Importance.pdf
 
Financial management
Financial managementFinancial management
Financial management
 
Multinational Finance Solutions
Multinational Finance SolutionsMultinational Finance Solutions
Multinational Finance Solutions
 
604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02
604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02
604 08-17solutionsmanual-130313081430-phpapp02
 
Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...
Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...
Evaluating The Merits And Demerits Of Fixed And Floating...
 
PPT-IFM.pdf
PPT-IFM.pdfPPT-IFM.pdf
PPT-IFM.pdf
 
PPT-IFM.pdf
PPT-IFM.pdfPPT-IFM.pdf
PPT-IFM.pdf
 
PPT-IFM.pdf
PPT-IFM.pdfPPT-IFM.pdf
PPT-IFM.pdf
 
Macroeconomics
MacroeconomicsMacroeconomics
Macroeconomics
 
Chap01
Chap01Chap01
Chap01
 
Presentation1.pptx 2
Presentation1.pptx 2Presentation1.pptx 2
Presentation1.pptx 2
 
Ch01
Ch01Ch01
Ch01
 
A Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business Management
A Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business ManagementA Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business Management
A Theoretical Framework (Modelling) for International Business Management
 
Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfection
 Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfection Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfection
Tips for writing International economics assignment with perfection
 
International finance1 1
International finance1 1International finance1 1
International finance1 1
 
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fallEcon452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fall
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1 - 2020 fall
 
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1
Econ452 Learning Unit 01 - Part 1
 
Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All
Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All
Chapter 1Globalization©McGraw-Hill Education. All
 

Int Econ Star

  • 1. LECTURE NOTES in INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS (*) (I) (ECON301/331/332) Cevat Gerni Beykent University/İstanbul 2010 (*) These lecture notes mostly depend on the textbooks of Dominick Salvatore (International Economics, 9e), Paul R.Krugman & Maurice Obstfeld (International Economics, 3e) and Halil Seyidoğlu (Uluslararası İktisat, 17e), with our own contributions. 1
  • 2. Contents 1 Introduction 1.1 The Scope of International Economics 1.2 International Economics: Trade and Money 1.3 Why is some knowledge of international economics required? 1.4 Historical Development of International Trade Theory (Table 1) 2 The Law of Comparative Advantage 2.1 Introduction 2.2 Mercantilism 2.3 Trade Based on Absolute Advantage: Adam Smith 2.4 Trade Based on Comparative Advantage: David Ricardo 2.5 Critics of Ricardo’s Comparative Advantages 2.6 Exception to The Law of Comparative Advantage 2.7 The Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantages (Gottfried Haberler) 2.8 Empirical Tests of Ricardian Model 3 The Standard Theory of International Trade 3.1 Introduction 3.2 The Production Frontier with Increasing Costs 3.3 Equilibrium in Isolation with Increasing Costs (In a Closed Economy) 3.4 The Basis For and The Gains From Trade with Increasing Costs 3.5 The Gains From Exchange and From Specialization 3.6 Trade Based on Differences in Tastes 4 Offer Curves, Demand and Supply, The Terms of Trade 4.1 Introduction 4.2 Illustration of Offer Curves 5 Factor Endowments and The Heckscher-Ohlin Theory 5.1 Introduction 5.2 Illustration of the H-O Theory 5.3 Corollaries of the H-O Theory 2
  • 3. 5.4 Empirical Tests of the Heckscher-Ohlin Model 5.5 The New Trade Theories 5.6 Synthesis of Trade Theories 5.7 Transportation Costs and International Trade 5.8 Environmental Standards and International Trade 6 Economic Growth and International Trade 6.1 Introduction 6.2 Interaction Between Growth and Trade 6.3 Comparative Advantages and Economic Development Chapter One INTRODUCTION 3
  • 4. 1.1 The Scope of International Economics This course deals with the main concepts and methods of International Economics Examples for some concepts and subjects of International Economics:  Trade between independent nations  Tariffs and quotas  Exchange rates  Balance of payments  Economic Integrations  Capital inflows and outflows And like… International Economics uses the ‘same fundamental methods of analysis’ as other branches of economics, because the ‘motives’ and ‘behavior’ of individuals and firms are the same in international trade as they are in domestic transactions. Yet, International Economics involves ‘new and different’ concerns, because international trade and investment occur between independent nations. For example,  Chine’s toys can become more expensive in Turkey if Turkey sets a quota that limits imports.  If interest rates in Turkey fall, capital outflows may occur and the value of dollar in terms of TL may rise. Then, the subject matter of International Economics consists of issues raised by the special problems of economic interaction between sovereign states. 4
  • 5. Seven themes recur throughout the subject: The Gains From Trade The Pattern of Trade Protectionism The Balance of Payments Exchange Rate Determination International Policy Coordination International Capital Market 5
  • 6. i. The Gains From Trade Probably the most important insight in all of International Economics is the idea that ‘there are gains from trade.’ That is, that when countries sell goods and services to another, this is almost always ‘to their mutual benefit.’ Many people are skeptical about the benefits of trade, but the range of circumstances under which international trade is beneficial is much wider than most people appreciate. (will be discussed in detail later.) ii. The Pattern of Trade ‘Who sells what to whom?’ This summarizes the pattern of trade, which have been a major preoccupation of international economists. The reasons behind the trade might be:  Differences in climate and natural resources  Differences in labor productivity (D.Ricardo)  Relative supplies of national resources such as capital, labor, and land on one side and relative use of these factors in the production of different goods on the other.  A random component such as economies of scale, and external economies. (will be discussed in detail later.) iii. Protectionism If the idea of gains from trade is the most important theoretical concept in International Economics, the seemingly eternal battle between free trade and protection is its most important policy theme. Limits on imports and subsidizing exports are devices of protectionist policies. International Economics analyzes the effects of these protectionist policies. And usually, though not always, it criticizes protectionism and shows the advantages of freer international trade. (These devices will be analyzed) 6
  • 7. iv. The Balance of Payments Some countries run large ‘trade surpluses’ -that is, each sells more goods to the rest of the world than it buys in return, like Japan. On the other side, some countries run large ‘trade deficits’ -that is, each buy more goods from the rest of the world than it sells, like Turkey. What does it mean when a country runs a trade surplus or a trade deficit? To make sense of numbers like the trade deficit, it is essential to place them in the broader context of the whole of a nation’s international transactions. The record of a country’s transactions with the rest of the world is called ‘the balance of payments.’ Explaining the balance of payments and diagnosing its significance is a main theme of international economics. The balance of payments has become a central issue for Turkey because the nation has run huge trade deficits for a long time. v. Exchange Rate Determination In February 2001, a dollar was worth about 1500 Turkish Liras. During the following years a dollar fell up to TL 1200, and this year fluctuated between 1300 and 1700. These changes have many effects far beyond financial markets. Exports, imports, industrial efficiency, foreign direct investments, saving behavior, etc are affected by the value of Turkish Lira in terms of other currencies. One of the key differences between International Economics and other areas of Economics is that countries have different currencies. Exchange rate can be fixed by government action (fixed Exchange rate regime) or can be determined in the market place (floating Exchange rate regime) For the time being, however, some of the world’s most important exchange rates fluctuate minute by minute and the role of changing exchange rates remains at the center of the international economics story. 7
  • 8. vi. International Policy Coordination The international economy comprises of sovereign nations, each free to choose its own economic policies. Unfortunately, in an integrated world economy, one country’s economic policies usually affect other countries as well. For example:  When the United States imposed a tariff on imports of lumber during 1986, the Canadian Lumber Industry experienced a crisis.  The FED’s interest rate policy is very important for the policy actions of other governments. Therefore, differences in goals between countries often lead to conflicts of interest. Even when countries have similar goals, they may suffer losses if they fail to coordinate their policies. While cooperation on international trade policies is a well-established tradition, coordination of international macroeconomic policies is a newer and more uncertain topic. vii. International Capital Market The debt problems of developing countries (especially Latin Americans) during 1970s, 1980s and 1990s brought the public attention to the growing importance of the international capital market. The growing importance of international trade has been accompanied by the growth in the ‘International Capital Market’ which links the capital markets of individual countries. ‘Some special risks’ are also associated with international capital markets; currency fluctuations, national default... So, the growing importance of international capital markets and their new problems demand greater attention than even before. 8
  • 9. 1.2 International Economics: Trade and Money The economics of international economy can be divided into two broad subfields. • The study of International Trade • The study of International Money International trade analysis focuses primarily on the ‘real transactions’ in the international economy (that is, physical movements of goods). International monetary analysis focuses on the ‘monetary side’ of the international economy (that is, on financial transactions such as foreign purchases of U.S. dollars on Turkish Lira) In the real world, there is no simple dividing line between trade and monetary issues. Most international trade involves monetary transactions, while many monetary events have important consequences for trade. Nonetheless, the distinction between international trade and international money is useful. In accordance with this distinction we will, at first, study international trade theories and policies; secondly, we will study international monetary theory and policy issues. Before starting the analysis of international trade theories, it might be useful to have a look at the historical development of international trade theory as a whole (see Table 1). 1.3 Why is some knowledge of international economics required? Because, first, it is necessary to understand what goes on in the world today and to be informed consumers, citizens, and voters. Second, on a more practical level, the study of international economics is required for numerous jobs in multinational corporations, international banking, government agencies, and international organizations. 9
  • 10. 10
  • 11. Table 1 1.4 Historical Development of International Trade Theory Theory of Absolute Theory of Extension of Factor Some Theorems Leontief Paradox New Theories Advantage Comparative Theory With New Proportions Depending on H-O Advantage Concepts Theory (Hecksher- Model Ohlin Model) -Adam Smith, ‘The Wealth -David Ricardo - Opportunity Cost -Why does a -Equalization of -The results of -Skilled Labor of Nations’ (1776) ‘On The Principals country have international factor Wassily Leontief’s Hypothesis of Political -International comparative prices Studies (1951) and -Classical Liberalism Economy and relative prices advantage? others stimulated -Technological Gap • Homoeconomicus Taxation’(1817) (Reciprocal -Income Distribution new theories. Hypothesis Demand -Resources / Factor Theorem of Stolper- (He devised input- • Laissez faire Samuelson laissez passer -Even if a country Curves/Offer Endowments are output analysis and -Product Cycle (Free trade policy is • Invisible Hand has advantage on Curves) emphasized. tested H-O Theory) Model in favor of abundant producing of the factor, but -Advantages of two goods, trade -Economic growth Eli Hecksher, protectionism is in -Similarity in specialization and division can be possible and and foreign trade Swedish, his article favor of scarce Preferences of labor are emphasized. two sides can gain ‘The Effect of factor.) Hypothesis from trade. Foreign Trade on -It is not adequate to explain The Distribution of -Rybczynski -The Theorem of the trade. But has -The theory Income’(1919); Theorem Economies of Scale importance for being the depends mainly on (Under full first attempt. the differences of Bertil Ohlin’s book, employment -The Theorem of labor productivity. ‘Inter-regional conditions, if the Monopolistic -Countries producing more Trade and supply of one factor Competition -Has been International increases, the efficiently should sell. developed with the Trade’(1933) production of the contribution of new good which uses that -Trade would be factor increases, but unilateral/one-sided concepts. the production of other good decreases.) 11
  • 12. Chapter Two THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE 2.1 Introduction We will start with the simplest model and develop it with extentions and additions. The basic questions are: 1) What is the ‘basis for trade?’ A nation will voluntarily engage in trade if it benefits from trade. 2) What are the ‘gains from trade’? But, how are gains from trade generated? And, how large are the gains and how are they divided among the trading nations? We will see, successively:  Mercantilism  Adam Smith’s theory of ‘Absolute Advantage’  David Ricardo’s theory of ‘Comparative Advantage’  Gottfried Haberler’s ‘Opportunity Cost’ Theory, as a contribution to comparative advantages. 2.2 Mercantilism • During 17th and 18th centuries mercantilism was the popular economic philosophy. • Briefly, the mercantilists maintained that the way for a nation to become ‘rich’ and ‘powerful’ was to export more than it imported. • According to Mercantilists, the source of power and richness was to accumulate precious metals, primarily gold and silver. • For that reason, the government had to stimulate the nation’s exports and restrict imports. • Thus, the mercantilists preached ‘economic nationalism’. • But, since all nations could not simultaneously have an export surplus and the amount of gold and silver was fixed at any particular point in time, one nation could gain only at the expense of other nations. 12
  • 13. • Consequently, trade was a ‘zero-sum game’: one part gains, but the other loses! 2.3 Trade Based on Absolute Advantage: Adam Smith Economics as an organized science can be said to have originated with the publication in 1776 of ‘The Wealth of Nations’ by Adam Smith. Smith started with the simple truth that for two nations to trade with each other ‘voluntarily’, both nations ‘must gain’. And the questions: • How does this ‘mutually beneficial trade’ take place? and • From where do these ‘gains from trade’ come? 2.3a Absolute Advantage: • According to Smith, trade between two nations is based on ‘absolute advantage’. • According to the theory of absolute advantage, when one nation is more efficient than the other in the production of one commodity, it should specialize in producing this commodity and export the surplus over its need. In return, this nation can buy (import) the commodity which is the surplus of the other nation’s production that is generated by the specialization of this nation. Thus, Two nations allocate their resources so as to produce most efficiently. And free trade would cause world resources to be utilized most efficiently and would maximize world welfare. • This is the policy of ‘Laissez-faire’ (There were to be only a few exceptions to this policy of Laissez-faire and free trade; e.g. the protection of industries important for national defense.) 13
  • 14. 2.3b Illustration of Absolute Advantage Table 2.1 one hour of labor time U.S. U.K. Wheat (bushels*/man-hour) 6 1 Cloth (yards**/man-hour) 4 5 *bushel: a unit of measure, approximately 8 gallons (36lt); Kile **yard: 3 feets/36 inch; or 0.91 m (1 feet: 30.5cm, 1 inch: 2.54 cm) From the table, we can see that;  One hour of labor time produces 6 units of wheat in the U.S., but only 1 unit of wheat in the U.K.  On the other hand, one hour of labor time produces 5 units of cloth in the U.K., but only 4 units of cloth in the U.S.  Thus, the U.S. has an absolute advantage over the U.K. in the production of wheat (or is more efficient than the U.K.) And, the U.K. has an absolute advantage over the U.S. in the production of cloth (or is more efficient than the U.S.) With trade,  the U.S. would specialize in the production of wheat, and exchange part of it for British cloth. The opposite is true for the U.K.  Now, let’s assume that the U.S. gives up to produce cloth (C) and specializes in the production of wheat (W); producing for example 12 units of wheat.  If the U.S. exchanges 6 units of W for 6 units of British C, then the U.S. gains 2 C. 6 C (imported)- 4 C (domestically produced) = 2 C Similarly,  6 W ( the U.K. receives from the U.S.) = 6 man-hours for the U.K. With 6 man-hours, the U.K. can produce 30 C (=6 man-hours x 5 C). So, the U.K. gains 24 C (30 C- 6C=24 C) 14
  • 15.  In this example, no matter how much more one nation (the U.K.) gained than the other nation (the U.S.). What is important is that ‘both’ nations can gain from specialization in production and trade.  However, in the example above, if the U.S. was efficient in the production of both wheat and cloth, the trade could not be possible because the U.K. could not gain from trade.  Absolute advantage can explain only a very small part of world trade today, such as some of the trade between developed and developing countries. It remained for David Ricardo to explain the basis for and the gains from trade: The Law of Comparative Advantage. 2.4 Trade Based on Comparative Advantage: David Ricardo Definition: According to the law of comparative advantage, even if one nation is less efficient than the other nation in the production of ‘both’ commodities, there is still a basis for mutually beneficial trade. In other words, one nation may have an absolute disadvantage with respect to the other nation, but they can gain from trade. Let’s look at the example given by Ricardo: Table 2.2 Commodities produced with one labor-day Cloth (meter) Wine (liter) The U.K. has an U.K. 80 40 absolute advantage Portugal 10 20 for C&W But, in cloth, U.K. Labor is 8 times productive; and in wine, U.K. labor is 2 times productive. It is said that Portugal has a comparative advantage in wine and the U.K. has a comparative advantage in cloth. In other words, the U.K.’s absolute advantage is greater in cloth, so the U.K. has a comparative advantage in cloth. 15
  • 16. The Gains from Trade: Now look at the domestic prices. (Note that prices are relative in terms of other commodity: terms of trade domestically) Domestic Prices in the U.K.: 1 unit of cloth= 1/2 units of wine (1C=1/2W) Domestic Prices in Portugal: 1 unit of cloth= 2 units of wine (1C=2W) Domestic Prices are different. The difference in domestic prices is a base for trade. (Assuming no transportation costs) For example, say, current world price is as follows: 1 unit of cloth= 1 unit of wine (1C=1W) Then, how much do the trading nations gain? = world price- domestic cost The U.K. gains ½ W. Because 1C (Export) is exchanged for 1W (Import), then 1W- ½ W (domestic cost) = 1/2 W Portugal gains 1/2 C. Because 1W (exports) is exchanged for 1C (imports); then 1C-1/2 C (domestic cost) = 1/2C 2.5 Critics of Ricardo’s Comparative Advantages Of course, although Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage is a very challenging one with practical applications, it is not perfect. It has been criticized in some aspects:  The theory considers only the labor productivity. Whereas, there are other resources used in production process such as capital, land, etc.  The theory does not explain the difference in labor productivities.  It assumes that labor is domestically mobile, but immobile between countries.  It is a supply theory. Whereas, the demand side should be considered. 16
  • 17.  It depends on constant costs and complete specialization. Whereas, increasing costs and incomplete specialization are more realistic in the world of today.  It is a static model. It does not consider the changes over time. This criticism is especially important to developing countries.  It does not take the production processes into consideration in the world of today. Trade between industrialized countries is mostly of intra-industry character (not only inter-industry). Intra-industry trade means the trade among similar industries. 2.6 Exception to the Law of Comparative Advantage There is one exception to the law of comparative advantage but not very common. This occurs when the absolute disadvantage that one nation has with respect to another nation is the ‘same’ in both commodities. For example, let us reorganize Table 2.2 as below: Table 2.3 Commodities produced with one labor-day Cloth (meter) Wine (liter) U.K. 80 40 Portugal 10 5 If, with one labor day, Portugal produced 5 units of wine, Portugal could be exactly one-eight as productive as the U.K. in both cloth and wine. The U.K. and Portugal would then have a comparative advantage in either commodity, and no mutually beneficial trade could take place. This requires slightly modifying the statement of the law of comparative advantage to read as follows: 17
  • 18. Even if one nation has an absolute disadvantage with respect to the other nation in the production of both commodities, there is still a basis for mutually beneficial trade, ‘unless the absolute disadvantage (that one nation has with respect to the other nation) is in the same proportion for the two commodities.’ While it is important to note this exception in theory, its occurrence is rare and a matter of coincidence, so that the applicability of the law of comparative advantage is not much affected. Furthermore, natural ‘trade barriers’ such as transportation costs can preclude trade even when some comparative advantage exists. 2.7 The Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantages (Gottfried Haberler) Ricardo based his law of comparative advantage on a number of assumptions: 1. Only two nations and two commodities, 2. Free trade, These 3. Perfect mobility of labor within each nation but immobility between the two assumptions nations, can easily be relaxed! 4. Constant costs of production, 5. No transportation costs, 6. No technical change, 7. The labor theory of value. (But this assumption is not ‘valid’ and should not be used for explaining comparative advantage) According to the Labor Theory of Value, the value or price of a commodity depends exclusively on the amount of labor going into the production of the commodity. This implies: 1. that either labor is the only factor of production or labor is used in the ‘same’ fixed proportion in the production of all commodities. 2. that labor is homogenous (i.e., of only one type) 18
  • 19. Since neither of these assumptions is true, we cannot base the explanation of comparative advantage on the labor theory of value. It was left for Gottfried Haberler in 1936 to explain or base the theory of comparative advantage on the ‘opportunity cost theory’. In this form, the law of comparative advantage is sometimes referred to as ‘the law of comparative cost’. According to the opportunity cost theory, the cost of a commodity is the amount of a second commodity that must be given up to release ‘just enough resources’ to produce one additional unit of the first commodity. ‘Just enough resources’, here, imply some cost! In this case, we can write the costs of commodities in terms of national currencies, and later convert them into relative commodity prices (Table 2.4) Table 2.4 Domestic Prices (in terms of national currencies) For 1 unit of Steel* Wheat* In Turkey 10 TL 1 TL In the U.S. 1$ 1$ *: It requires some resources of These costs can be stated as relative commodity prices as follows: Opportunity In Turkey: 1 unit of steel = 10 units of wheat cost domestically In the U.S.: 1 unit of steel =1 unit of wheat In Turkey, WHEAT is cheap Turkey specializes in WHEAT In U.S., STEEL is cheap The U.S. specializes in STEEL In this case they trade and gain from trade! How do this trade and gains from trade occur? To understand the case, we first should recall the production possibility frontier. 19
  • 20. 2.7a the Production Possibility Frontier under Constant Returns (The following explanation is just that of Salvatore, page 44-48) Definition: ‘The production possibility frontier’ is a curve that shows the alternative combinations of the two commodities that a nation can produce by fully utilizing all of its resources with the best technology available to it. Table 2.5 Production Possibility Schedules for Wheat and Cloth in The U.S. and U.K. United States United Kingdom Wheat Cloth Wheat Cloth 180 0 60 0 150 20 50 20 120 40 40 40 90* 60* 30** 60** 60 80 20 80 30 100 10 100 0 120 0 120 *: (90, 60) represents Point A in the figure below. **: (30, 60) represents Point A’ in the figure below. From figure 2.1 and Table 2.5, we see that the United States should give up 30 units of wheat Cloth Production if it wants to increase 20 units of cloth (from 180 W to 150 W, from 0 C to 20 C, from 150 W Figure 2.1 Production Frontiers to 120 W, from 20 Constant Returns under C to 40 C, etc.) U.S. For the U.S., note that for every 20 C it requires 30 W to give up for the U.K. In other U.S. 1WW,2/3C words, for each 1 = it requires 2/3 C to give up. 1W = 2C 120 120 100 100 This means that “the cost of 1 unit of Wheat is 2/3 units of Cloth in the United States.” Cloth 80 80 On A 60 the other hand, for the U.K., note that for every 40 C it requires 20 W to give up. 60 40 A’ In the 40 other words, for each 1 W it requires 2 C to give up. 20 20 This means that “the cost of 1 unit of wheat is 2 units of cloth in The United Kingdom.” (1 W = 2 C) 0 30 60 90 120 150 180 0 20 40 60 This case is called constant opportunity cost, because the cost of 1 W does not Wheat Production Wheat change “no matter from which point on its production possibility frontier the Nation starts.” 20
  • 21. Why do constant opportunity costs arise? They arise when; (1) resources or factors of production are either - ‘perfect substitutes for each other’ or - ‘used in fixed proportion in the production of both commodities’. (2) all units of the same factor are homogeneous or of exactly the same quality. 21
  • 22. Figure 2.2 Graphical illustrations of the gains from trade under constant returns Cloth 180 U.S. Cloth U.K. 120 B’ 120 X E A C2 70 M C1 60 C’2 50 E’ M C’1 40 A’ X B 0 90 110 180 0 40 60 70 120 W1 W2 Wheat W’1 W’2 Wheat 22
  • 23. Now, to be noted is that by each nation specializing in the production of the commodity it has comparative advantage the total production of world increases and also the two nations end up consuming more than before trade (as shown in Table 2.5). In the absence of trade, In the absence of trade, Production and consumption point is ; Production and consumption point is ; Production 90W = 0W1 Production & Consumption Production 40W’ = 0W’1 Production & Consumption And of the nation depend on the And of the nation depend on the consumption 60C = 0C1 people’s tastes ,or demand consumption 60C’1 = 0C’1 people’s tastes ,or demand considerations considerations (The Nation chooses point A) (The Nation chooses point A’) If trade possible for 1 W = 1 C internationally Similarly, if trade possible for 1W=1C internationally The U.S. might choose point E ( might want to exchange 70 W for 70 C ; The U.K. might choose point E` chooses E ) (might want to exchange 70 W for 70 C ); Then, Production ; 180 W = 0B ; 0C (no cloth production ) Production ; 120 C =0B`; 0W (no wheat production) Consumption ; 110 W = 0W2 >0W1 (110 – 90 = 20 W ) Consumption; 50C=0C2`>0C1` (50-40 = 10C) Export ; 70 W (180 – 110 ) Export ; 120-50 =70C Import = consumption of cloth; Import = consumption wheat; 70C = 0C2>0C1 (70-60 =10C) 70W= 0W2`>0W1` (70-40=30W) “With trade, The U.S. gained 20 W and 10 C”. “With trade The U.K. gained 10C and 30W.” EW2B is called ‘foreign trade triangle.’ E`C2`B` is the foreign trade triangle of The U.K. Vertical axis shows import, Horizontal axis shows export, 23 Hypotenuse shows “rate of exchange.” / ‘relative prices’ / ‘terms of trade’
  • 24. Table 2.5 Increases in the World Production and Consumption after Trade World Production Before Trade After Trade U.S U.K Total U.S U.K Total Wheat 90 40 130 180 0 180 Cloth 60 40 100 0 120 120 World Consumption Before Trade After Trade U.S U.K Total U.S U.K Total Wheat 90 40 130 110 70 180 Cloth 60 40 100 70 50 120 2.8 Empirical Tests of the Ricardian Model → Various tests were conducted for the validity of Ricardian simple model. G.D.A. Mac Dougall (in1951, 1952), Bela Balassa (in 1963), R.M. Stern (in 1962), S.S. Golub (in1995), S.S. Golub and C.T. Hsieh (in 2000) studied the theory empirically. → The Ricardian trade model has to a large extent been empirically verified. → Despite this, it has a serious shortcoming in that it “assumes” rather than “explains” comparative advantage. → The model explains NEITHER the reason for the differences in labor productivity across nations NOR the effect of international trade on the earnings of factors. → By providing answers to both of these important questions, The Hecksher-Ohlin model theoretically improves upon Ricardian Model. 24
  • 25. Chapter Three THE STANDARD THEORY of INTERNATIONAL TRADE 3.1 Introduction → By ‘The Standard Theory’ we mean the extension of the model with the more realistic case of ‘increasing opportunity costs.’ → We consider ‘tastes or demand preferences’, represented by ‘community indifference curves’ → So, together with production possibility curve (supply force) and community preferences (demand force), we will drive the equilibrium relative price in each nation in the absence of trade under increasing costs. (This will also indicate the commodity of comparative advantage for each nation) → Subsequently, we examine how, with trade, each nation gains by specializing in the production of the commodity of its comparative advantage. → Also, we’ll see a special case; how mutually beneficial trade is possible even when two nations are exactly alike except for tastes under increasing costs. 3.2 The Production Frontier with Increasing Costs It is more realistic for a nation to face increasing rather than constant opportunity costs. Increasing opportunity costs mean that the nation must give up more and more of one commodity to release just enough resources to produce each additional unit of another commodity. Increasing opportunity costs result in a production frontier (production Figure 3.1 a possibility curve) that is concave from the origin (Figure 3.1a). Nation 1 Y Nation 1 incurs increasing opportunity costs in the A production of both commodities. Y1 B Y2 C For each additional unit of X commodity, Nation 1 must Y3 D give up more and more Y. ( Y1< Y2< Y3 ) X 25 0 1 2 3 4
  • 26. This is also valid when each additional unit of Y is increased. Figure 3.1 b Y Nation 2 Nation 2 incurs increasing costs in the production of Y. 5 4 X3 For each additional unit of Y commodity, Nation 2 must 3 give up more and more X. X2 ( X1< X2< X3 ) 2 X1 1 0 X 3.2a The Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT) → The marginal rate of transformation of X for Y refers to the amount of Y that a nation must give up to produce each additional unit of X. → Thus, MRT is another name for the opportunity cost of X, and is given by the (absolute) slope of the production frontier at the point of production. In Figure 3.1a, if the slope of the production frontier (MRT) of Nation 1 at point A is 1/4, this means that Nation 1 must give up 1/4 of a unit of Y to release just enough resources to produce one additional unit of X at this point. Similarly, if the slope, or MRT, equals 1 at point B, this means that Nation 1 must give up one unit of Y to produce one additional unit of X at this point. → Thus, a movement from point A down to point B along the production frontier of Nation1 involves an increase in the slope and reflects the increasing opportunity costs in producing more X. → In contrast, in the case of constant opportunity costs the MRT is constant, as seen in Figure 2.1. 26
  • 27. 3.2b Reasons for Increasing Opportunity Costs and Different Production Frontiers → How do increasing costs arise? → Why are they more realistic than constant opportunity costs? Because; 1) Resources or factors of production are not homogenous. That is, all units of the same factor are not identical or of the same equality (no perfect substitution) 2) Resources or factors of production are not used in the same fixed proportion or intensity in the production of all commodities. This means that as the nation produces more of a commodity, it must utilize resources that become progressively ‘less efficient’ or ‘less suited’ for the production of that commodity. For instance, suppose some of a nation’s land is flat and suited for growing wheat, and some is hilly and better suited for grazing and milk production. The nation originally specialized in wheat but now wants to concentrate on producing milk. By transferring its hilly areas from wheat growing to grazing, the nation gives up very little wheat and obtains a great deal of milk. Thus, the opportunity cost of milk in terms of the amount of wheat given up is initially small. But if this transfer process continues, eventually flat land, which is better suited for wheat growing, will have to be used for grazing. As a result, the opportunity cost of milk will rise and the production frontier will be concave from the origin. Note that the production frontiers of Nation 1 and Nation 2 in figure 3.1 have different factor endowments and / or use different technologies in production. In the real world, the production frontiers of different nations will usually differ, since practically no two nations have identical factor endowments (even if they could have access to the same technology). 27
  • 28. 3.2c Community Indifference Curves So far, we have discussed production, or supply, considerations in a nation. Now, we introduce the demand considerations (or tastes) in a nation. These are given by community indifference curves (or social indifference curves). Definition: ‘A community indifference curve shows the various combinations of two commodities that yield equal satisfaction to the community or nation.’ → Higher curves refer to greater satisfaction, lower curves refer to less satisfaction. → Community indifference curves are negatively sloped and convex from the origin. → To be useful, they must not cross. Illustration of Indifference Curves Figure 3.2a Figure 3.2b 28
  • 29. Y T E N H III A II I X 0 Nation 1 Y H’ E’ A’ III’ II’ R’ I’ X 0 Nation 2 Here, tastes (or demand preferences) are different in the two nations. Points N and A give equal satisfaction to Nation 1, since they are both on the same indifference curve (I). Points T and H refer to a higher level of satisfaction, since they are on a higher indifference curve (II). Even though T involves more of Y but less of X than A, satisfaction is greater at T because it is on Indifference Curve II. Point E refers to still greater satisfaction, since it is on indifference curve III. 29
  • 30. Then, N=A<T=H<E; and for Nation 2, A`=R`<H`<E` → The community indifference curves are negatively sloped. It implies that if the nation wants to consume more of X, it must consume less of Y, remaining on the same level of satisfaction. The Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)  The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of X for Y in consumption refers to the amount of Y that a nation could give up for one extra unit of X and still remains on the same indifference curve.  This is given by the (absolute) slope of the community indifference curve at the point of consumption and declines as the nation moves down the curve. Because, the marginal utility of commodity X decreses more and more as the commodity is used more and more. Figure 3.2 c Y tan A> tan B means that the slope at point N is higher than the slope at point A. N opposite rise A (Tangent is measured as ˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗ = ˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗˗ ) adjacent run tan A tan B (The position of an indifference curve represents X for what commodity the society demands more. The slope represents the degree of substitution.)  Declining MRS means that community indifference curves are convex from the origin.  Thus, while increasing opportunity cost in production is reflected in concave production frontiers; a declining marginal rate of substitution in consumption is reflected in convex indifference curves. 30
  • 31. This convexity property of indifference curves is necessary to reach a unique equilibrium consumption point for the nation 3.3 Equilibrium in Isolation with Increasing Costs (In a Closed Economy) Figure 3.3 a Figure 3.3 b Y Nation 1 Nation 1 A I I 60 PA=1/4 PA=1/4 X 50 130 X 50 130 Y PA’=4 Nation 2 40 A’ I’ X 80 → Nation 1 is in equilibrium, or maximizes its welfare, in isolation by producing and consuming at point A, where its production frontier reaches, or is tangent to, indifference curve I (the highest possible). 31
  • 32. → Similarly, Nation 2 is in equilibrium at point A’, where its production frontier is tangent to indifference curve I’. → The equilibrium relative price of X in Nation 1 is given by the slope of the common tangent to its production frontier and indifference curve I at point A. This is PA=1/4 for Nation 1, PA’= 4 for Nation 2  Since the relative price of X is lower in Nation 1 than in Nation 2, Nation 1 has a comparative advantage in commodity X, and Nation 2 has a comparative advantage in commodity Y. 3.4 The Basis For and the Gains from Trade with Increasing Costs Now, suppose that the world (equilibrium) relative price is 1Y=1X We know that, in Nation 1, 1/4 Y=1X → If Nation 1 can exchange 1X for more than 1/4 Y, it wants to specialize in X production. → But as long as Nation 1 specialize in X production, the opportunity cost of X will rise. → Nation 1 will specialize in X production up to the point where 1X is exchanged for 1Y. This point is B in figure 3.4 a. Figure 3.4 a 32
  • 33. 1) Point A Nation 1 represents Y the E (80) Y3 III A I Y1 C B (20) Y2 PB=1 X1 X3 X2 0 (70) (130) equilibrium in isolation. In this case, Nation 1 consumes the amount of X and Y that it produces (that is, X1 and Y1). 2) With trade, Nation 1 moves from point A to point B in production. By then exchanging 60X for 60Y with Nation 2, Nation 1 ends up consuming at point E (on indifference curve III). It represents a higher welfare level. (After trade, Nation 1 changed its production and consumption combinations.) 3) The trade triangle is ECB. X 4) The key point here is that the specialization is incomplete. Nation 1 still produces the two goods, but it produces more commodity X (X2) than commodity Y (Y2). It consumes some X (X3), and sell the amount not used (X3- X2=CB); in return, it buys commodity Y (Y2-Y3=EC). Similarly, we can analyze the case of Nation 2, as illustrated in Figure 3.4 b. Figure 3.4 b Nation 2 33
  • 34. Y 1) A’ is the point where production B' and consumption of Nation 2 are in C' isolation. E' III' A' 2) With trade, PB=1 I' production 120 moves from X point A’ to X2 X1 X3 point B’. (40) (80) (100) 60 3) Consumptio Y1 0 n moves from point A’ to point E’, which represents a higher welfare level. 4) The trade triangle is C’E’B’. 5) B’C’ is the export of Nation 2. 6) C’E’ is the import of Nation 2, 7) The hypotenuse of the trade triangle (B’E’) represents the world relative commodity price. 8) PB is the ‘equilibrium-relative commodity price with trade’. 9) Also note that specialization is ‘incomplete’.  As the result of these analyses, these two nations want to trade at an equilibrium- relative commodity world price that is higher than domestic relative commodity prices of these two nations. 34
  • 35. 3.5 The Gains from Exchange and From Specialization Figure 3.5 Nation 1 A nation’s gains from trade can be broken into two components: Y3 E T U10 Y2 U7 Y1 C A U5 PD=1/4 B Y4 F P*W=1 PW=1 0 X2 X1 X3 X4 1) The gains from ‘exchange’, and 2) The gains from ‘specialization’. This breakdown is illustrated in Figure 3.5. From A to T (Gains from exchange) From A to E (Gains from specialization) → Suppose that, for whatever reason, Nation 1 could not specialize in the production of X with the opening of trade but continued to produce at point A. - Point A shows both producing and consuming combinations (in isolation) - Pd (=1/4) is the relative domestic price. → Let us assume that Pw (=1) represents the world relative price. Accordingly, Pw* also represents the world relative price. → Because Pw (=Pw*=1) is higher than PD (=1/4), Nation 1 can produce at PD and sell at Pw. That is, Nation 1 can exchange X 2X1 (CA) amount of X for Y1Y2 (CT) amount of Y. (Note that preferences do not change, therefore T is the new consuming point) 35
  • 36. ∆ TCA is the trade triangle in the case of without specialization.  Now, after trade, Nation 1 reduced consumption of X, but increased consumption of Y. Even though Nation 1 consumes less of X and more of Y at point T in relation to point A, ‘it is better off than it was autarchy because T is on higher indifference curve U7’. The movement from point A to point T in consumption measures the gains from exchange. → If subsequently Nation 1 also specialized in production of X and produced at Point B (at the prevailing relative world price Pw (=1)), then it could exchange X3X4 amount of X for Y4Y3 amount of Y and ends up in consuming at point E on indifference curve U 10 which represents a higher consumption combination (a higher welfare level). → Production and consumption points in the case of specialization: B: equilibrium production point. E: equilibrium consumption point. Nation 1 produces X4 units of X, consumes X3 units of X, (X3>X1) exports X3X4 amount of X, imports Y4Y3 amount of Y in exchange of X3X4. Total consumption of Y is OY3, which is the sum of OY4 (its own production) and Y3Y4 (its import). → Recall that EFB is the trade triangle in the case of specialization. The movement from T to E in consumption measures ‘the gains from specialization in production.’ 3.6 Trade Based on Differences in Tastes Figure 3.6 36
  • 37. Nation 1 and Nation 2 have identical production frontiers (shown by a single curve) Y E U8 U5 PA = 1/4 A IMA Y'2 B’ C EXA B PA’= 4 PW = 1 EXA’ IMA’ E’ C’ U’8 Y'1 A’ U’5 X 0 X'2 X'1  In the analysis before (in Figure 3.4 a and Figure 3.4 b), we supposed that the ‘difference in pretrade relative commodity prices’ was based on the ‘differences in the production frontiers and indifference curves’ in two nations.  Whereas, even if two nations have identical production possibility frontiers, there will still be a basis for mutually beneficial trade if tastes (i.e. demand preferences) in two nations differ.  The nation with the relatively smaller demand (or preference for a commodity) will have a lower relative price for that commodity. 37
  • 38.  The process of specialization in production and trade would then follow, as described in previous cases (for previous cases see pages 28/ Figure 3.4a and 29/ Figure 3.4b).  In figure 3.6, the two nations have the same production possibility curve (DD). → A is the point where Nation 1 is in equilibrium in autarky. → PA represents the autarky price of Nation 1. → In this case, Nation 1 has a comparative advantage in commodity X. On the other hand, → A’ is the point where Nation 2 is in equilibrium in autarky. → PA’ represents the autarky price of Nation 2. → In this case, Nation 2 has a comparative advantage in commodity Y.  Note that the two nations have different relative domestic (autarky) prices because of different tastes (demand preferences) even though they have the same production possibility frontier.  PW is the world relative commodity price, which is higher than PA (when the price of X is measured in terms of Y) and higher than PA’ (when the price of Y is measured in terms of X).  Now, there is a basis for mutually beneficial trade between the two nations at world price PW.  With trade, Nation 1 will move from A to B in production and it will move from A to E for consumption. → Nation 1 will consume more X and more Y than the pretrade case (it will export EXA’ amount of X commodity, and import IMA’ amount of Y commodity).  Also with trade, Nation 2 will move from A’ to B’ in production and it will move from A’ to E’ for consumption. 38
  • 39. → Nation 2 will consume more Y and more X than the pretrade (it will export EXA amount of Y commodity, import IMA amount of X commodity). Consequently, mutually beneficial trade became possible though the same production frontiers, depending on the difference in tastes. Chapter Four OFFER CURVES, DEMAND and SUPPLY (Reciprocal Demands), and the TERMS OF TRADE 4.1 Introduction • So far, while analyzing trade between two countries we have assumed a hypothetical relative equilibrium (world) price which is higher than domestic relative commodity prices. • Then, the question is that how this equilibrium-relative commodity price (P W) is determined. • We will make use of ‘offer curves’ (sometimes referred to as ‘reciprocal demand curves’). • Offer curves (or reciprocal demand curves) were devised and introduced into international economics by Alfred Marshall and Ysidro Edgeword, two British economists. Offer curves have been used extensively in international economics, especially for pedagogical purposes. • The offer curve of a nation shows how much of its import commodity the nation demands for it to be willing to supply various amounts of its export commodity. (In other words, how much of its export commodity Nation 1 offers for 1 unit of import commodity of Nation 2). • As the definitions indicate, offer curves incorporate elements of both demand and supply. • Alternatively, we can say that the offer curve of a nation shows the nation’s willingness to import and export at various relative commodity prices. 39
  • 40. 4.2 Illustration of Offer Curves • Suppose that U.S. and Turkey will trade. U.S. has a comparative advantage in machine (M), Turkey has a comparative advantage in wheat (W) → In Turkey; 1W=1/2M → In U.S. ; 1W=2M (or 1/2W=1M) Figure 4.1 Machine • Considering Figure 4.1, Turkey would be neutral if the world price U.S’s relative was equal to Turkey’s domestic commodity price price. PUS 5 Area for mutually benefical trade But, if Turkey can exchange 1W 4 for more than 1/2M, it wants to PT 3 trade. B Turkey’s relative 2 commodity price (Domestic • Similarly, the U.S. would be neutral price ) 1 if the world price was equal to its 1/2 A domestic price. 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Wheat But if U.S. can Exchange 1M for more than 1/2W, it wants to trade. • Then, the area between lines showing domestic relative prices of Turkey and U.S. takes place for mutually beneficial trade. • Depending on figure 4.2, we derive the offer curve D (10M=5W) of Turkey. C (10M=10W) Figure 4.2 4 Machine B (10M=15W) C A (10M=20W) 2 B (1/2M=1W) 1 40 1/2 A 0,5 1 1.5 2 3 4 5 Wheat
  • 41. (The offer curve of Turkey bulges toward X axis).  According to figure 4.2, Turkey is neutral to trade up to point A, because point A is on its domestic (relative) price.  But, for example, at point B, which is on the world relative commodity price of B, Turkey wants to exchange 3W for 2M. → That is, Turkey offers (or exports/supplies) 3 units of wheat and demands (or imports) 2 units of machine in return. At point C, which is on the world relative-commodity price of C, Turkey wants to Exchange 4W for 4M → That is, for Turkey to import 2 more units of machine it offers less amount of wheat. → As Turkey consumes more and more units of machine, for one additional unit of machine it offers less amount of wheat (because of diminishing marginal utility law). → If we joint the points A, B, C, D from the origin, we obtain the offer curve of Turkey.  Following the same method, the U.S.’s offer curve can be derived (This is left for the students). Let us suppose that the offer curve of U.S. is as follows. Figure 4.3 D (10M=5W) Machine C(10M=10W) 4 B(10M=15W) 3 The offer curve of U.S. bulges toward Y axis. 2 1 41 0 1 2 3 4 Wheat
  • 42.  The world equilibrium relative commodity price is determined at the point where the offer curves of the two nations intersect. Figure 4.4 Machine Turkey Pw (M) 4 US E Keep in mind that prices 1 are relative-commodity prices Wheat 0 1 4 (L) → At price PW, Turkey exports 4 units of wheat (OL) At price PW, Turkey imports 4 units of machine (EL) → At the same price, U.S. exports 4 units of machine (OM=EL) At the same price, U.S. imports 4 units of wheat (EM=OL) The hypotenuse represents the world OLE is the Turkey’s trade triangle price OME is the U.S.’s trade triangle (Equilibrium relative commodity price) 42
  • 43.  How does the equilibrium relative commodity price change? → For various reasons, when the offer curves of the nations shift, the equilibrium price changes. → The variables which cause supply and demand curves to shift cause the offer curves to shift as well. (Recall that consumer’s income, the price of related goods, tastes, expectations, technology, and input prices cause the forces of demand and supply to shift). Figure 4.5 Illustration of a change in equilibrium world price) T’ Machine T • Let Turkey demands more P’ US of U.S. import good. P • The offer curve of Turkey shifts to the right. • The world price rises from Wheat OP to OP’ (If the United States does not change its demand preference). • The world price changes; it moves toward the relative price of Turkey.  How does the welfare effect of this change take place? → The welfare effect takes place with the comparison of two opposite changes: The first is the change in the terms of trade ( P) The second is the change in trade volume ( TV) 43
  • 44. Figure 4.6 Machine T If TV> P , the welfare effect is (+) P’ If TV< P, the welfare effect is (-) A P OPL is the trade voşume in the first case. 0 L OP’L’ is the trade volume in the second case. L’ 0 L L’ Wheat 4.3 A Special Case: The Importance of Being Unimportant Let’s take two nations. The first is large (U.S.), and the second is small (Luxembourg). → The U.S.’s offer curve bulges more toward Y axis because its demand for the good (say, butter) of Luxembourg is high. On the other hand, Luxembourg’s offer curve bulges less toward X axis because its demand for the good (say, engine) of U.S. is small. Figure 4.7 Engine L A Pus P U.S.’s gains from trade Luxembourg’s gains from trade O Butter  OPUS = The U.S.’s domestic price OP = World relative price 44
  • 45. OA = the U.S.’s offer curve OL = Luxembourg’s offer curve  The area between OA and OP represents the U.S.’s gains from trade.  The area between OL and OP represents the Luxembourg’s gains from trade.  Because the world price is very high from Luxembourg’s domestic price, Luxembourg gains more from trade than U.S.  This case is called the importance of being unimportant (Marshall’s contribution to the theory of trade). Chapter Four FACTOR ENDOWMENTS and the HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY 5.1 Introduction • We have seen in previous chapters that the difference in relative commodity prices between two nations is evidence of their comparative advantage and forms the basis for mutually beneficial trade. • We now go one step further and explain the reason, or cause for the difference in relative commodity prices and comparative advantage between the two nations. • According to classical economists (Smith, Ricardo, Mill), comparative advantage was based on the difference in the productivity of labor among nations, but they provided no explanation for such a difference in productivity. • The Heckscher-Ohlin theory extends the trade theory and examines the basis for comparative advantage. • The H-O theory is based on the following assumptions (see Salvatore, pp.123-124): 45
  • 46. 1. There are two nations, two commodities, and two factors of production (labor and capital). Considering more than two nations, more than two commodities, and more than two factors will leave the conclusions of the theory basically unchanged. 2. Both nations use the same technology in production. 3. Commodity X is labor intensive and commodity Y is capital intensive in both nations. 4. Both commodities are produced under constant returns to scale in both nations. 5. There is incomplete specialization in production in both countries. 6. Tastes are equal in both nations. 7. There is perfect competition in both commodities and factor markets in both nations. 8. There is perfect factor mobility within each nation but no international factor mobility. 9. There are no transportation costs, tariffs, or other obstructions to the free flow of international trade. 10. All recourses are fully employed in both nations. 11. International trade between the two nations is balanced. • The main idea of the H-O is that; “Each nation has comparative advantage in the commodity that it can produce in accordance with its factor intensity.” 5.2 Illustration of the H-O Theory • According to the Figure 5.1., the U.S. has a comparative advantage in machine because machine is a capital intensive good and the U.S. has more capital than labor. So, capital is the cheap factor with respect to labor in the U.S. Figure 5.1 a Figure 5.1 b Machine (Y) Machine (Y) Before Trade PW After Trade A A’ EXUS A E T IMUS T U10 U5 IMT PT PA T’ EXT 0 A T Wheat Wheat (X) (X) ( 46
  • 47. • On the other hand, Turkey has a comparative advantage in wheat because wheat is a labor intensive good and Turkey has more labor than capital. So, labor is the cheap factor with respect to capital in Turkey. • In this case, according to the H-O theory, the U.S. will specialize in the machine production and export machine but import wheat. On the other hand, Turkey will specialize in wheat production and export wheat but import capital. • The analysis is very similar as we did for the cases in this chapter. It is left for you! (Proceed the analysis) • In sum, according to H-O theory, “a nation will export the commodity whose production requires the intensive use of the nation’s relatively abundant and cheap factor and import the commodity whose production requires the intensive use of the nation’s relatively scarce and expensive factor.” 5.3 Corollaries of the H-O Theory Depending on the H-O Theory, various theorems have been developed. We will examine them briefly in the following. 1. The factor-price equalization theorem → Paul Samuelson (1976 Nobel Prize in economics) rigorously proved the factor-price equalization theorem, which is really a corollary since it follows directly from the H-O theory. → For this reason, it is sometimes referred to as the Hecksher-Ohlin-Samouelson theorem (H-O-S theorem, for short) → According to the H-O-S theorem, “International trade will bring about equalization in the relative and absolute returns to homogenous factors across nations.” 47
  • 48.  What this means is that international trade will cause the wages of homogenous labor to be same in all trading nations.  Similarly, international trade will cause the return to homogenous capital (i.e. capital of the same productivity and risk) to be the same in all trading nations.  In this respect, it brings about the same results of international factor mobility. → How this process works? → Turkey has abundant labor; therefore, the price of labor is relatively cheap. With the opening of trade, as it specializes in wheat production, the demand for labor will increase.  The price of labor (wage) will tend to rise. → The U.S.A. has abundant capital factor. For this reason, the price of capital (i.e., interest rate) is relatively cheap.  With the opening of trade, as it specializes in machine production, the demand for capital will increase in the U.S.  The price of capital (interests) will tend to rise. → As a result of the movements of factors, the wages in Turkey will tend to be equal to the wages in the U.S. and the interest rates in the U.S. will tend to be equal to the rates in Turkey. → The best example of this theorem is the real hourly wages in manufacturing in leading Industrial Countries as a percentage of the U.S. wage (see p. 144 of your textbook, Salvatore, Table 5.6 in the 9th edition). → Depending on H-O-S theorem, it is expected that, with the increasing of factor mobility and trade in European Union, the wages will rise and the interest rates will fall in the developing nations who will be integrated with the European Union. 48
  • 49. 2. Stolper- Samuelson Theorem of Income Distribution This theorem is the corollary of the H-O-S theorem. → According to this theorem, free trade will raise the real income of the factor that is abundant in the nation, and reduce the real income of the factor that is scarce in the nation. → The protectionist policies of the European Union for the agricultural sector can be explained by this theorem. 3. The Rybczynski Theorem This theorem postulates that at constant commodity prices, an increase in the endowment of one factor will increase by a greater proportion the output of the commodity which is intensive in that factor and will reduce the output of the other commodity. Figure 5.2 Machine Pw=1 Pw=1 M1 A M2 A’ Wheat 0 W1 W2 → The nation experienced economic growth with the increase in the endowment of labor. 49
  • 50. → The world relative price remained the same. → The output of the commodity (wheat) which is labor-intensive increased by a greater proportion. → The Output of the other good decreased. 5.4 Empirical Tests of the Heckscher-Ohlin Model →The first empirical test of the H-O model was conducted by Wassily Leontief in 1951 using U.S. data for the year 1947. →Since the U.S was the most capital-abundant nation in the world, Leontief expected to find that it exported capital-intensive commodities and imported labor-intensive commodities. →According to the results, the United States seemed to export labor intensive commodities and import capital intensive commodities. This was the opposite of what the H-O Model predicted and became known as the “Leontief Paradox”. → Hereupon, some explanations were made for this paradox. → Many empirical studies were conducted with data from other countries. → But, the empirical studies give conflicting results. ∴ In consequent, such an explanation has been made: The H-O Model is adequate for the explanation of the trade between the developed and developing nations but not enough to explain the trade between industrial nations. ∴ New theories have been developed... 5.5 The New Trade Theories →Heckscher and Ohlin based comparative advantage on the difference in factor endowments (labor & capital) among nations. This theory, however, leaves a great 50
  • 51. deal of today’s international trade unexplained. Because trade among 200 nations and trade of thousands of goods are difficult to explain with one model. →To fill this gap, after 1960s, new international trade theories have been developed. →In fact, some of these new theories try to explain the source of comparative advantage and the difference between factor endowments. The new theories are explained briefly in the following. 1. Skilled Labor Hypothesis:  The skilled labor-intensive goods are almost the same as capital-intensive goods. In general, these two kinds of goods are treated together as “man- made”.  This revision of H-O Model is called “New-factor Endowment Theory”.  Empirical studies show that the developed nations having skilled labor export industrial goods and the developing nations having unskilled labor and abundant land export primary agricultural goods. 2. Technological Gap Model  According to this model, a great deal of the trade among industrialized countries is based on the introduction of new products and new production processes.  These give the innovating firm or nation a “temporary” monopoly in the world market. Protected by laws such as patents and copyrights.  In time, the new technology becomes widespread. The exporting nation becomes importing one and vice-versa.  The industries of textile, electronic equipment, chemistry, steel and iron and cement are typical examples. 51
  • 52.  The model is tested for various countries. According to the empirical results, there is a high correlation between the net exports of industries and their research and development investments.  For instance, more than 50 percent of R& D personnel in the world work in the United States. This fact can be interpreted that the United States has comparative advantages especially in high-tech products. 3. Product Cycle Model  This model is a generalization and extension of the technological gap model.  The process is from the innovating to imitating nation: Step 1: Innovation and to meet the domestic consumption. Step 2: The product matures. The amount of production becomes greater than the domestic consumption. The nation exports. Step 3: * Gradually, the technology and the product become standardized. The innovative firm starts to give licenses to the firms of other nations. * The production becomes more advantageous in previously importing countries with the contribution of other factors. * The production in the innovating nation starts to decrease. Step 4: * Anyway, the technology and production methods are fully standardized and the legal limitations such as patents and copyrights are removed. * The innovating nation is eventually in the position of an importing nation. * The product cycle is completed. And the innovating nation, in the meantime, is up to new products. In the world of today, the time period of product cycles becomes considerably shorten. This fact implies that the innovating nations such 52
  • 53. as U.S. and Japan have to provide technological improvements to keep their competitiveness. As a matter fact, they do so! 4) Preference Similarity Hypothesis  This hypothesis, different from others, views the demand side of the international trade.  Therefore, it is also named “overlapping demands” hypothesis.  According to this model, a nation exports those manufactured products for which a large domestic market exists.  These are products that appeal to the majority of the population.  In the process of satisfying such a market, the nation acquires the necessary experience and efficiency to be able subsequently to export these commodities to other nations with similar tastes and income levels.  On the other hand, the nation will import those products that appeal to its low- and high-income minorities.  According to this hypothesis, trade in manufactures is likely to be largest among countries with similar tastes and income levels.  While confirmed for Sweden, this hypothesis has not been confirmed for other nations. It cannot explain the goods that a nation produces only for exports. For example, why such non-Christian nations as Japan and Korea export artificial christmas trees and christmas cards in the absence of a domestic market for these products? 5) Economies of Scale and Monopolistic Competition  These two theories are related to one another. The factor endowment theory (H-O Model) makes explanations under “constant returns to scale”. 53
  • 54. “Constant returns to scale” refers to the production situation where output grows at the same rate with the increase in inputs or factors of production. That is, if all inputs are doubled, output is doubled.  On the other hand, “increasing returns to scale” refers to the situation where output grows proportionately more than the increase in intputs or factors of production. That is, if all inputs are doubled, output is more than doubled.  Increasing returns to scale may occur because at a larger scale of operation a greater division of labor and specialization becomes possible.  Therefore, even if two nations are identical in every respect, there is still a basis for mutually beneficial trade based on economies of scale.  Because of “external” and “internal” economies, nations specialize in different goods in the same industry. Thus, trade in the same industry becomes possible. This is called “intra-industry trade”.  In addition, the economies of scale stimulate the “differentiated products” under the situation of monopolistic competition. The consumers are presented a wide range of differentiated products of the same good.  The automobile industry is the best example of economies of scale, differentiated products and intra-industry trade.  The importance of intra-industry trade became apparent when tariffs and other obstructions to the flow of trade among members of the European Union were removed in 1958.  The study made by B. Balassa (in 1967) showed that “The trade volume increased very speed among member nations of the E.U., but most of this trade was different goods within the same industries. 5.6 Synthesis of Trade Theories 54
  • 55. The overall conclusions that we can reach regarding the empirical relevance of the trade theories examined thus far are: (1) Most of the trade between developed and developing countries are “inter- industry trade” based on differences in factor endowments, as postulated by Heckscher- Ohlin. (2) An increasing proportion of the trade among industrialized countries is “intra-industry trade” based on economies of scale in differentiated products, as postulated by the new trade theories. 5.7 Transportation Costs and International Trade → So far we have assumed that costs of transportation are zero. We can relax this assumption. → Costs of transportation affect international trade directly by affecting the price of the traded commodity in the exporting and importing countries. → Furthermore, costs of transportation affect international trade indirectly by affecting the international location of production and industry. → Costs of transportation include • Freight charges • Warehouse costs • Costs of loading and unloading • Insurance premiums • Interest charges while goods are in transit In sum, the term transport or logistics costs include all the costs of transferring goods from one location (country) to another. → Logistic costs are affected by the country’s geography, the quality of its infrastructures, and the management techniques of the firms. 55